Skip to main content
Log in

Marriage: for love, for money…and for time?

  • Published:
Review of Economics of the Household Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Married couples enjoy meaningful economies in time, often choosing to specialize where one spouse focuses on market work and the other on household production and childcare. Using data from the American Time Use Survey 2003–2008, I estimate significant marriage effects upon time use. Most married women gain 33–34 min of leisure each weekday when compared to single women. While marriage does not lead to more leisure for husbands, it allows them to allocate time away from home and towards market work. Lower-income couples work more at home and for pay, and spend less time in leisure than their single counterparts. The temporal and financial gains from marriage for most people are inconsistent with its declining prevalence.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. According to the Census Bureau, the proportion of married couples decreased from 84% in 1930 to 56% in 1990, and to under 50% in 2006.

  2. 34.5 h*$15 $/h =  $517.5.

  3. According to the Consumer Expenditure Survey 2006, an average two-person household spent over 12% of its total expenditures on food at home and away from home, not including alcohol. Average total annual expenditures was $50,652, including $6,203 on food whereas single adults spent on average $3,249 on food. Source: ftp://ftp.bls.gov/pub/special.requests/ce/standard/2006/cusize.txt.

  4. ATUS is an ongoing annual survey with over 85,000 interviews over 6 years. Its respondents are a subset of households which have finished their last rotation in the Current Population Survey. For a complete description of the survey see http://www.bls.gov/tus/. See Hamermesh et al. (2005) for a overview and discussion of ATUS.

  5. Grossbard-Shechtman and Jepsen (2008) suggest that non-traditional households may require a separate analysis.

  6. A famous saying goes “Nobody ever washed a rental car.”

  7. Wages, earnings and incomes are converted to 2008 dollars using the CPI from www.bls.gov.

  8. Poverty thresholds can be found at http://www.census.gov/hhes/www/poverty/threshld.html.

  9. A similar technique, with variations, is used by Kalenkoski et al. (2005), Kimmel and Connelly (2006), Bloemen and Stancanelli (2009).

  10. The Heckman participation and log wage equations are estimated over all employed individuals from the CPS-ATUS sample, which is a much larger sample that includes observations on over 160,000 individuals over 7 survey years. Log wage and participation regressions include the following controls: age, age-squared, indicators for black, Hispanic, 4 education dummies, married and never married status, indicators for a non-US citizen, a naturalized citizen (to account for difference in English language skills that might impact employment and wages), metropolitan residence, region dummies, year of the survey dummies, local monthly unemployment rate. The employment participation equation is identified by the inclusion of the presence and number of children by age groups, and the student status. According to these estimates, married men are 32% more likely to be employed, with marriage wage premium of 10%. Marriage decreases women’s probability to be employed by 23%, but women’s marriage wage premium is also positive, 6%.

  11. This result is consistent with Kalenkoski et al. (2005), who find single fathers spend more time in primary childcare than married fathers.

  12. These data and description are available at: http://www.nber.org/data/ces_cbo.html Sample characteristics and methodology are described in “Appendix”.

References

  • Aguiar, M., & Hurst, E. (2004). Consumption vs. expenditure. NBER Working Paper No. 10307.

  • Becker, G. (1965). A theory of the allocation of time. Economic Journal, 75, 493–517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1973). A theory of marriage: Part I. Journal of Political Economy, 8i, 813–846.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1991). Treatise on the family. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. (1981, Enlarged edition).

    Google Scholar 

  • Bloemen, H., & Stancanelli, E. (2009). How do parents allocate time? The effects of wages and income, IZA DP No. 3679.

  • Briant, W. K., & Zick, C. (2006). The economic organization of the household (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burda, M., Hamermesh, D. S., & Weil, P. (2007). Total work, gender and social norms, NBER Working Paper No. 13000, March 2007.

  • Chiappori, P. -A. (1997). Introducing household production in collective models of labor supply. Journal of Political Economy, 105(1), 191–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connelly, R., & Kimmel, J. (2009). Spousal influences on parents’ non-market time choices. Review of the Economics of the Household, 7, 361–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connolly, M. (2008). Here comes the rain again: Weather and the intertemporal substitution of leisure. Journal of Labor Economics, 26(1).

  • Crossley, T., & Lu, Y. (2003). Exploring the returns to scale in food preparation (Baking Penny Buns at Home), Institute for Fiscal Studies Working Paper 05/03.

  • Datta Gupta, N., & Stratton, L. (2009). Examining the impact of alternative power measures on individual time use in American and Danish couple households, forthcoming in Review of the Economics of the Household.

  • Deaton, A., & Paxson, C. (1998). Economies of scale, household size and the demand for food. Journal of Political Economy, 106, 897–930.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • El Lahga, A. R., & Moreau, N. (2007). The effects of marriage on couples allocation of time between market and non-market hours. IZA DPf 2619, February 2007.

  • Gronau, R. (1977). Leisure, home production, and work—The theory of the allocation of time revisited. The Journal of Political Economy, 85(6).

  • Gronau, R., & Hamermesh, D. (2006). Time vs. goods: The value of measuring household technologies. Review of Income and Wealth, 52, 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossbard-Shechtman, A. S. (1984). A theory of allocation of time in markets for labor and marriage. Economic Journal, 94, 863–882.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossbard-Shechtman, S. (1993). On the economics of marriage: A theory of marriage, labor and divorce. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossbard-Shechtman, S., & Jepsen, L. (2008). The economics of gay and lesbian couples: Introduction to a special issue on gay and lesbian households. Review of Economics of the Household, 6.

  • Grossbard-Shechtman, S., & Neuman, S. (1998). The extra burden of moslem wives: Clues from Israeli women’s labor supply. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 46(3).

  • Hamermesh, D. (2002). Timing, togetherness and time windfalls. Journal of Population Economics, 15(2002), 601–623.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamermesh, D. S., Harley, F., & Stewart, J. (2005). Data watch: The American time use survey. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(1), 221–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hersch, J. (2009). Home production and wages: Evidence from the American time use survey. Review of the Economics of the Household, 7, 159–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hersch, J., & Stratton, L. S. (2002). Housework and wages. Journal of Human Resources, 37(1), 217–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalenkoski, C., Ribar, D., & Stratton, L. S. (2005). Parental child care in single parent, cohabiting, and married couple families: Time diary evidence from the United Kingdom. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 95(2), 194–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimmel, J., & Connelly, R. (2006). Is mothers’ time with their children home production or leisure? IZA DP 2058, March 2006.

  • Lam, D. (1988). Marriage markets and assortative mating with household public goods. Journal of Human Resources, 23, 462–487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear, E., & Michael, R. (1980). Family size and the distribution of real per capita income. American Economic Review, 1, 91–107.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solaz, A. (2005). Division of domestic work: Is there adjustment between partners when one is unemployed? Evidence from French Couples. Review of Economics of the Household, 3, 387–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson, B., & Wolfers, J. (2007). Marriage and divorce: Changes and their driving forces. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(2), 27–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Victoria Vernon.

Appendix: Calculations based on NBER Consumer Expenditure Survey Family-Level Extracts 2002–03

Appendix: Calculations based on NBER Consumer Expenditure Survey Family-Level Extracts 2002–03

NBER Consumer Expenditure Survey Family-Level Extracts are annual household-level data derived by linking the four quarterly interviews for each Consumer Expenditure Survey respondent family. The extract contains information on annual expenditures, incomes, household composition and demographics. I select one and two adult families with and without children, so that the final sample contains 6640 households. Mean values are listed in Appendix Table 4. Single headed households account for 36% of the sample. Children live in 42% of the households. Overall the racial and educational composition of the sample is similar to the one found in the time use data and is representative of the US population.

Table 4 Sample means and OLS estimates of the expenditure equations

Total expenditure includes food, nonfood, clothing, personal care, shelter, recreation, education, personal insurance, transportation, charity. I also separately examine three major expenditure categories—food, shelter and transportation—in order to compare relative economies in these items. Food expenditure includes food eaten at home and away from home, excluding alcohol. Shelter includes rent or value of owner occupied housing, utilities, household help and 10% of the value of purchased furnishings and appliances. Transportation includes 10% of the cost of new vehicles, gasoline, vehicle maintenance, auto insurance, public and other transportation. While these measurements of expenditures are far from being perfect, for example, they do not include service value of durable goods purchased in previous years, they will still give us a rough idea on how much money an average couple saves by living together.

The following relationship between per adult household expenditure and family composition is estimated:

$$ {\text{Per}}\;{\text{Adult}}\;{\text{Expenditure}} = \alpha {\text{SingleMan}} + \beta {\text{SingleWoman}} + \gamma {\text{X}} + \varepsilon . $$

Vector X includes presence and number of children, employment status of the household head, race, education and age of the household head, annual income per adult, and, to refine the income variable further, indicators for low income food stamp recipients and housing ownership status.

The sum of the coefficients on SingleMan and SingleWoman shows how much more a single man and a single woman living apart spend compared to an otherwise similar married couple.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Vernon, V. Marriage: for love, for money…and for time?. Rev Econ Household 8, 433–457 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-009-9086-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-009-9086-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation