Skip to main content
Log in

Decentralization as a constraint to Leviathan: a panel cointegration analysis

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper extends the empirical literature about the effects of fiscal decentralization on the growth of government along three dimensions. It distinguishes between the effects of the level of decentralization from the way local governments finance their expenditures (common pool versus own resources); it uses a panel cointegration approach to separate the long run effects of decentralization from the short run dynamics; and it extends and revises the datasets generally used in these empirical analyses. The results show that the amount of revenue raised by sub-national governments leads to a long-term fall in the size of government but grants have the opposite effect. In addition, a greater decentralization of expenditure leads to greater overall spending. When the short-term is considered these influences work slowly, as the speed of adjustment towards the desired government size is relatively sluggish. In addition, in the short run, there is also a clear effect from the role of local revenue raising powers that stimulates the growth of government. These results appear robust to changes in the composition of the variables, countries and periods included the sample.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The countries considered in the present study are Argentina, Australia, Austria. Belgium, Bolivia, Brazil, Canada, Chile, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, India, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Luxemburg, Mexico, Netherlands, Norway, Romania, South Africa, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Thailand, United Kingdom and United States. The availability of a balanced panel of data, characterized by series definitions and sources that remain consistent across time and countries, determines the choice of the sample.

  2. Blume and Voigt (2011a, 2011b) provide evidence showing the importance of institutional details in this type of analysis.

  3. An example is provided by the financing of health care services in Italy, which constitutes the main responsibility of regional governments. Until the early 1990s, these expenditures were mainly funded by central government grants, ensuing their rapid growth in all regions, as each region could partly export the additional costs of greater spending. In 1996, the introduction of a regional tax, the IRAP, initially earmarked to finance health care, and the simultaneous reduction of central government transfers, contributed to the reduction in these expenditures (Bordignon and Turati 2009). Eskeland et al. (2003) provide many more examples of this kind.

  4. In particular this covariate is defined as younger than 15 years of age and older than 65 and thus provides a consistent definition of the variable, though it is clearly only an approximation to the reality in each country of the actual dependency ratio, given the different ages for compulsory education across the sample.

  5. The correlation between veto players and proportional representation is 0.521; this is more severe than the correlation with the parliamentary variables, where the correlation is 0.337.

  6. For some countries data are available up to 2006. Extending the time series, however, severely limits the cross section dimension of the sample and its economic, institutional and geographic variety. Estimates on this other sample, available upon request, are not qualitatively different from those reported in the paper. This is reassuring from an econometric point of view, since Örsal (2008) shows that, with the available time series and number of countries, cointegration is likely to be found. Clearly, the power of the tests depends on the span of the data and not only on the number of observations, so the robustness of the results when the sample is extended by six years is supportive of our findings.

  7. There is a debate as to the precision of these tests (Harris and Sollis 2003), in particular about how cross section independence is treated. To accommodate this, we checked the results using the tests proposed by Hadri (2000). The Hadri test is a sensible check, as it assumes a null hypothesis of stationarity, whereas the others assume a null hypothesis of nonstationarity. No change in inference with respect to the levels of integration of the variables was observed, confirming the outcome of the Im et al. (2003) tests. The results of this alternative testing procedure are available upon request.

  8. We entered (see the Appendix) the EXCHANGE dummy which must be I(0), just like the political dummies, but its omission in the cointegrating relationship does not destroy the relationship. We thus infer that the breaks are not crucial to the estimation.

  9. Other researchers examine various cross product terms too. It is not obvious that these should be introduced in the first, baseline estimates. Moreover, when explored, we found that various combinations were all dominated by the results presented.

  10. Evidence of cointegration means that there is a minimum of one long run relationship. The negative sign on the ECM indicates that expenditure is at the very least one of the endogenous variables, if not necessarily the only one and we are then following other researchers in treating the regressors as exogenous. As a check on the reasonableness of this approach, IV estimation of the preferred equation ECM using lags 2 and 3 of the variables as instruments was undertaken with the coefficients from such a regression little changed from those presented; the results of one of these estimations are presented in model 13 (column 4) of Table 3.

  11. Dynamic OLS (DOLS) estimations also were performed. Given annual data, the lags on the DOLS were taken to be first order. The difference between the FMOLS and DOLS estimation techniques is in their approach to dealing with potential non-exogeneity of the regressors and serial correlation (Harris and Sollis 2003). The FMOLS results take a non-parametric approach, while the DOLS adopt a parametric approach where lagged first differences are estimated. The preference for either technique rests on judgments with respect to the data (see Harris and Sollis 2003, for more). In this case, given the differential sizes of the countries, the FMOLS is probably to be preferred. The results from both estimation techniques are, however, consistent, which indicates a degree of robustness. DOLS estimates are available upon request.

  12. Table A.2 in the Appendix provides estimations to show the effect of the alternative EXCHANGE variable, with specifications close to those of previous research. The main results are not changed unduly.

  13. The DEMOCRACY variable is omitted from later columns using only OECD countries, where its variability is very slight, causing difficulties in the estimation. Table A.1 in the Appendix provides results if the SYSTEM of government (however defined) is omitted. It can be seen that DEMOCRACY picks up the effect of SYSTEM, showing the degree of collinearity between the two variables. It is also clear that the SYSTEM of government, even simply defined as PARLIAMENTARY (or other), is more consistently significant; hence it is preferred and reported in Table 2 of the main text.

  14. Some indicative results are placed in Table A.2. The full set of results relative to the preferred model are available from the authors upon request.

  15. The plots of the residuals are available upon request.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2005). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Drazen, A. (1991). Why are stabilization delayed? American Economic Journal, 81, 1170–1188.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arzaghi, M., & Henderson, J. V. (2005). Why countries are fiscally decentralizing. Journal of Public Economics, 89, 1157–1189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashworth, J., Geys, B., & Heyndels, B. (2005). Government weakness and local public debt development in Flemish municipalities. International Tax and Public Finance, 12, 395–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashworth, J., Geys, B., & Heyndels, B. (2006). Determinants of tax innovation: the case of environmental taxes in Flemish municipalities. European Journal of Political Economy, 22, 223–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashworth, J., Galli, E., & Padovano, F. (2012). The effects of decentralization on the dynamics of public spending programs (CREM-CNRS Working Paper 2012/5).

  • Bardhan, P., & Mookherjee, D. (2000). Capture and governance at local and national levels. American Economic Review, 90, 135–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blume, L., & Voigt, S. (2011a). Federalism and decentralization—a critical survey of frequently used indicators. Constitutional Political Economy, 22, 238–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blume, L., & Voigt, S. (2011b). The economic effects of federalism and decentralization: a cross-country assessment. Public Choice, 151, 229–254.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & Case, A. C. (1995). Incumbent behavior: vote-seeking, tax setting, and yardstick competition. American Economic Review, 85, 25–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bordignon, M., & Piazza, S. (2010). Who do you blame in local finance? An analysis of municipal financing in Italy (CESifo Working Paper Series No. 3100).

  • Bordignon, M., & Turati, G. (2009). Bailing out expectations and health expenditure. Journal of Health Economics, 28, 305–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. M. (1980). The power to tax. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crowley, G. R., & Sobel, R. S. (2011). Does fiscal decentralization constrain Leviathan? New evidence from local property tax competition. Public Choice, 149, 5–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Haan, J., Sturm, I. E., & De Groot, O. (2008). Policy adjustments and sustainability of public finances in the Netherlands. In R. Neck & I. E. Sturm (Eds.), Sustainability of public debt (pp. 85–106). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Devarajan, S., Khemani, S., & Shah, S. (2009). The politics of partial decentralization. In E. Ahmad & G. Brosio (Eds.), Does decentralization enhance service delivery and poverty reduction? (pp. 102–123). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehdaie, J. (1994). Fiscal decentralization and the size of government (Policy Research Working Paper No. 1387). World Bank.

  • Enikolopov, R., & Zhuravskaya, E. (2007). Decentralization and political institutions. Journal of Public Economics, 91, 2261–2290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eskeland, G., Litvack, J., & Rodden, J. (2003). Fiscal decentralization and the challenge of hard budget constraints. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fan, C. S., Lin, C., & Treisman, D. (2009). Political decentralization and corruption: evidence from around the world. Journal of Public Economics, 93, 14–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feld, L. P., & Dede, T. (2005). Fiscal federalism and economic growth: cross country evidence for OECD countries. Paper presented at EPCS2005 Conference.

  • Fiva, J. H. (2006). New evidence on fiscal decentralization and the size of government. FinanzArchiv: Public Finance Analysis, 62, 250–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franzese, R. (2001). The positive political economy of public debt: an empirical examination of the postwar OECD experience. Unpublished paper, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor.

  • Garrett, G., & Rodden, J. (2003). Globalization and fiscal decentralization? In M. Kahler & D. Lake (Eds.), Governance in a global economy: political authority in transition. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, P. J. (1989). Fiscal decentralization and government size: an extension. Public Choice, 62, 63–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hadri, K. (2000). Testing for stationarity in heterogeneous panel data. Econometrics Journal, 3, 148–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, R., & Sollis, R. (2003). Applied time series modelling and forecasting. Chichester: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Im, K. S., Pesaran, M. H., & Shin, Y. (2003). Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. Journal of Econometrics, 115, 53–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inman, R. P. (1979). The fiscal performance of local governments: an interpretative review. In P. Mieszkowski & M. Straszheim (Eds.), Current issues in urban economics (pp. 270–321). Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Inman, R. P., & Rubinfeld, D. L. (1997). Rethinking federalism. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11, 43–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jin, J., & Zou, H. (2002). How does fiscal decentralization affect aggregate, national and subnational government size. Journal of Urban Economics, 52, 270–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Josselin, J.-M., Padovano, F., & Rocaboy, Y. (2012). Fiscal rules vs. political culture as determinants of soft budget spending behavior. Evidence from Italian and French regions (IREF Working Paper 2012/1).

  • Joulfaian, D., & Marlow, M. (1990). Government size and decentralization: evidence from disaggregated data. Southern Economic Journal, 56, 1094–1102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kao, C. H. (1999). Spurious regression and residual based tests of cointegration in panel data. Journal of Econometrics, 90, 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keen, M., & Marchand, M. (1997). Fiscal competition and the pattern of public spending. Journal of Public Economics, 66, 33–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khemani, S. (2010). Decentralization by politicians: creation of grants-financed local jurisdictions. In N. Bosch, M. Espasa & A. Sole-Ollé (Eds.), The political economy of regional fiscal flows. Measurement, determinants and effects on country stability (pp. 227–248). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Khemani, S. (2001). Decentralization and accountability: are voters more vigilant in local than in national elections? (Working Paper No. 2557). The World Bank.

  • McCoskey, S., & Kao, C. H. (1999). Testing for the stability of a production function with urbanisation as a shift factor. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 61, 671–690.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milesi-Ferretti, G. M., Perotti, R., & Rostagno, M. (2001). Electoral systems and public spending (Working Paper 01022). Washington, D. C. International Monetary Fund.

  • Moesen, W., & Van Cauwenberge, P. (2000). The status of the budget constraint, federalism and the relative size of government: a bureaucracy approach. Public Choice, 104, 207–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave, R. (1959). The theory of public finance. New York: McGraw.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates, W. E. (1972). Fiscal federalism. New York: Harcourt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates, W. E. (1985). Searching for Leviathan: an empirical study. American Economic Review, 75, 748–757.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (1999). Taxing powers of state and local governments. OECD Tax Policy Studies, No. 1, Paris.

  • OECD (2002). Fiscal design surveys across levels of government. OECD Tax Policy Studies No. 7, Paris.

  • Örsal, K. D. D. (2008). Comparison of panel cointegration tests. Economics Bulletin, 3, 1–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Padovano, F. (2007). The politics and economics of regional transfers. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Padovano, F., & Venturi, L. (2001). Wars of attrition in government coalitions and fiscal performance: a test on Italian 1948–1994 data. Public Choice, 109, 15–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panizza, U. (1999). On the determinants of fiscal centralization: theory and evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 74, 97–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pedroni, P. (1995). Panel cointegration: asymptotic and finite sample properties in pooled time series tests with an application to the PPP hypothesis (Indiana University Working Papers in Economics No. 95-013).

  • Pedroni, P. (1999). Critical values for cointegration tests in heterogeneous panels with multiple regressors. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 61, 653–670.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perron, P. (1988). Trends and random walks in macroeconomic time series: further evidence from a new approach. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control, 12, 297–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1994). Does centralization increase the size of government? European Economic Review, 38, 765–773.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political economics: explaining economic policy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2002). Do constitutions cause large governments? Quasi-experimental evidence. European Economic Review, 46, 908–918.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rattsø, J., & Tovmo, P. (2002). Fiscal discipline and asymmetric adjustment of revenues and expenditures: local government responses to shocks in Denmark. Public Finance Review, 30, 208–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. (1964). Federalism: origins, operation, significance. Boston: Little, Brown & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodden, J. (2003). Reviving Leviathan: fiscal federalism and the growth of government. International Organization, 57, 695–729.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodden, J., & Rose-Ackerman, S. (1997). Does federalism preserve markets? Virginia Law Review, 83, 1521–1572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (1998). Why do more open economics have bogger goverments? Journal of Political Economy, 106, 997–1032.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salmon, P. (1987). Decentralization as an incentive scheme. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 3, 24–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scharpf, F. W. (1988). The joint-decision trap: lessons from German federalism and European integration. Public Administration, 66, 239–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spolaroe, E. (2004). Adjustments in different government systems. Economics & Politics, 16, 117–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stegarescu, D. (2005). Public sector decentralization: measurement concepts and recent international trends. Fiscal Studies, 26, 301–333.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stein, E. (1999). Fiscal decentralization and government size in Latin America. Journal of Applied Economics, 2, 357–391.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strumpf, K. S. (2002). Does government decentralization increase policy innovation? Journal of Public Economic Theory, 4, 207–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanzi, V. (2002). Globalization and the future of social protection. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 49, 116–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R. (1995). The economic role of political institutions: market-preserving federalism and economic development. Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 11, 1–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, J. D. (1986). A theory of interregional tax competition. Journal of Urban Economics, 19, 296–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zodrow, G. R., & Mieszkowski, P. M. (1986). Pigou, Tiebout, property taxation, and the underprovision of local public goods. Journal of Urban Economics, 19, 356–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Paper presented at the University of Florence, at the University of Roma Tre, at the INFER conference, at the EPCS conference and at the PEARLE seminar. We thank the participants to these conferences and particularly Giampaolo Arachi, Geoffrey Brennan, Arthur Charpentier, Wallace Oates, Federico Revelli and three anonymous referees for helpful comments on previous drafts of this paper. Ilaria Petrarca provided excellent research assistance. The usual caveat applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Fabio Padovano.

Appendix: Alternative estimates

Appendix: Alternative estimates

Table A.1 Test for the panel cointegration and panel estimates of the cointegration vectors omitting SYSTEM and PARLIAMENTARY
Table A.2 Test for panel cointegration and panel estimates of the cointegration vectors: further evidence on EXCHANGE, SYSTEM and PR

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ashworth, J., Galli, E. & Padovano, F. Decentralization as a constraint to Leviathan: a panel cointegration analysis. Public Choice 156, 491–516 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-012-9962-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-012-9962-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation