Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Litigation and legal evolution: does procedure matter?

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Gordon Tullock’s critique of the common law runs against much of the conventional wisdom in the law and economics literature. In this paper we revisit one of the most controversial aspects of Tullock’s critique. By applying Tullock’s own model of rent-seeking to litigation, we study the effect of alternative procedural rules on civil litigation. Our results provide support for Tullock’s controversial critique of the common law, revealing an evolutionary bias in the production of legal rules by courts. We extend the standard litigation model to study the effects of alternative procedural systems on the evolution of the common law.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aranson, P. H. (1992). The common law as central economic planning. Constitutional Political Economy, 3, 289–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barzel, Y. (2000). Dispute and its resolution: delineating the economic role of the common law. American Law and Economics Review, 2(2), 238–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. L. (1989). The spontaneous evolution of commercial law. Southern Economic Journal, 55(3), 644–661.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cenini, M., & Parisi, F. (2010). Punitive damages and class actions. In J. G. Backhaus, A. Cassone & G. Ramello (Eds.), Class actions for Europe: perspectives from law and economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooter, R., & Kornhauser, L. (1980). Can litigation improve the law without the help of judges? Journal of Legal Studies, 9(1), 139–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooter, R. D., & Rubinfeld, D. L. (1989). Economic analysis of legal disputes and their resolution. Journal of Economic Literature, 27, 1067–1097.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dari-Mattiacci, G., & Parisi, F. (2005). Rents, dissipation, and lost treasures: rethinking Tullock’s paradox. Public Choice, 124, 411–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erlich, I., & Posner, R. A. (1974). An economic analysis of legal rulemaking. Journal of Legal Studies, 3, 257–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eisenberg, M. A. (1988). The nature of the common law. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fon, V., & Parisi, F. (2003). Litigation and the evolution of legal remedies: a dynamic model. Public Choice, 116, 419–433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fon, V., Parisi, F., & Depoorter, B. (2005). Litigation, judicial path-dependence, and legal change. European Journal of Law and Economics, 20, 43–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodman, J. C. (1978). An economic theory of the evolution of common law. Journal of Legal Studies, 7(2), 393–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gould, J. P. (1973). The economics of legal conflicts. Journal of Legal Studies, 2, 279–300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hadfield, G. K. (1992). Biases in the evolution of legal rules. Georgetown Law Journal, 80, 583–616.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. (1973). Law, legislation and liberty. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hathaway, O. A. (2001). Path dependence in the law: the course and pattern of legal change in a common law system. Iowa Law Review, 86, 601–661.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J. (1982). Evolutionary models in economics and law. In R. Zerbe (Ed.), Research in law and economics (Vol. 4, pp. 1–60). New York: JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hylton, K. N. (2006). Information, litigation and common law evolution. American Law and Economics Review, 8(1), 33–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplow, L. (1986). Private versus social costs in bringing suits. Journal of Legal Studies, 15, 371–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1998). Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106(6), 1113–1155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landes, W. M. (1971). An economic analysis of the courts. Journal of Law and Economics, 14, 61–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landes, W. M., & Posner, R. A. (1975). The independent judiciary in an interest-group perspective. Journal of Law and Economics, 18, 875–901.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landes, W. M., & Posner, R. A. (1979). Adjudication as a private good. Journal of Legal Studies, 8(2, Special Issue), 235–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahoney, P. G. (2001). The common law and economic growth: Hayek might be right. Journal of Legal Studies, 30, 503–525.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menell, P. (1983). A note on private versus social incentives to sue in a costly legal system. Journal of Legal Studies, 15, 41–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parisi, F. (2002). Rent-seeking through litigation: adversarial and inquisitorial systems compared. International Review of Law and Economics, 22, 193–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parisi, F., & Fon, V. (2009). The economics of lawmaking. London: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. A. (1975). The economic approach to law. Texas Law Review, 53, 757–782.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. A. (1994). What do judges and justices maximize? (The same thing everybody else does). Supreme Court Economic Review, 3, 1–41.

    Google Scholar 

  • Priest, G. L. (1977). The common law process and the selection of efficient rules. Journal of Legal Studies, 6, 65–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Priest, G. L., & Klein, B. (1984). The selection of disputes for Litigation. Journal of Legal Studies, 13, 1–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose-Ackerman, S., & Geistfeld, M. (1987). The divergence between social and private incentives to sue: a comment on Shavell, Menell, and Kaplow. Journal of Legal Studies, 16, 483–491.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roe, M. J. (1996). Chaos and evolution in law and economics. Harvard Law Review, 109(3), 641–668.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rowley, C. K. (1989). The common law in public choice perspective: a theoretical and institutional critique. Hamline Law Review, 12, 355–383.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, P. H. (1977). Why is the common law efficient? Journal of Legal Studies, 6, 51–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, P. H. (1982). Common law and statute law. Journal of Legal Studies, 11, 205–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, P. H. (2005). Micro and macro legal efficiency: supply and demand. Supreme Court Economic Review, 13, 19–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, P. H. (2007). The evolution of efficient common law. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, P. H., & Bailey, M. (1994). The role of lawyers in changing the law. Journal of Legal Studies, 23, 807–831.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shavell, S. (1982). The social versus the private incentive to bring suit in a costly legal system. Journal of Legal Studies, 11, 333–339.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shavell, S. (1997). The fundamental divergence between the private and the social motive to use the legal system. Journal of Legal Studies, 26, 575–612.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shavell, S. (1999). The level of litigation: private versus social optimality of suit and of settlement. International Review of Law and Economics, 19, 99–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stake, J. E. (2005). Evolution of rules in a common law system: differential litigation of the fee tail and other perpetuities. Florida State Law Review, 32(2), 401.

    Google Scholar 

  • Terrebonne, R. P. (1981). A strictly evolutionary model of common law. Journal of Legal Studies, 10(2), 397–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare cost of tariffs, monopolies and theft. Western Economic Journal, 5, 224–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1971). The logic of law. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent-seeking. In J. M. Buchanan, G. Tollison & G. Tullock (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society (pp. 97–112). College Station: Texas A&M University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1997). The case against the common law. Durham: Carolina Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (2004). On the efficient organization of trials. In C. K. Rowley (Ed.), The selected works of Gordon Tullock (Vol. 1). Indianapolis: Liberty Funds.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (2005a). Rent seeking and the law. In C. K. Rowley (Ed.), The selected works of Gordon Tullock (Vol. 5). Indianapolis: Liberty Funds.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (2005b). Technology: the anglo-saxons versus the rest of the world. In Trials on trial: the pure theory of legal procedure (New York: Columbia University Press, 1980). Reprinted: In C. K. Rowley (Ed.), The selected works of Gordon Tullock (Vol. 9). Indianapolis: Liberty Funds.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (2005c). The case against the common law (1997, Carolina Academic Press). In C. K. Rowley (Ed.), The selected works of Gordon Tullock (Vol. 9). Indianapolis: Liberty Funds.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zywicki, T. J. (2003). The rise and fall of efficiency in the common law. Northwestern University Law Review, 97, 1551.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zywicki, T. J. (2008). Spontaneous order and the common law: Gordon Tullock’s critique. Public Choice, 135, 35–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Francesco Parisi.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Luppi, B., Parisi, F. Litigation and legal evolution: does procedure matter?. Public Choice 152, 181–201 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9860-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9860-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation