Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

On structural and average technical efficiency

  • Published:
Journal of Productivity Analysis Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we explain the discrepancy between the efficiency of the average production unit and average efficiency by means of a covariance term relating size and technical efficiency and the extent of reallocation inefficiency. We show that, regardless of the degree of reallocation efficiency, the efficiency of the average production unit is lower than average efficiency when either size and efficiency are uncorrelated or larger units are more efficient than smaller ones. If however larger units are less efficient than smaller ones, the efficiency of the average production unit is higher than average efficiency as long as reallocation efficiency prevails. In addition, reallocation efficiency and a zero covariance term are sufficient conditions for the efficiency of the average production unit to be equal to average efficiency.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Li and Ng (1995) shown that structural and aggregate efficiency are related to one another by means of reallocation efficiency; for more details see Sect. 2 below.

  2. In this it is implicitly assumed that the reallocation process involves changes in the internal margin only (i.e., input movements across and mergers/splits of constituent firms), excluding entry and exit of firms. Another approach for aggregating across firms that follows points (a) and (b) is Johansen (1972) vintage approach; for more see Färe and Grosskopf (2004, pp. 109–115).

  3. We use Li and Cheng (2007) terminology for structural and aggregate efficiency, which follows closer Farrell’s (1957) spirit. His notion of structural efficiency clearly reflects reallocation of inputs available to the industry as well as restructuring of firms (see p. 262) while aggregate efficiency, which he called it ‘efficiency of an industry’, takes industry structure as given (see p. 261). Some authors (i.e., Bjurek et al. 1992; Ylvinger 2000; Nesterenko and Zelenyuk 2007) used the term structural efficiency to mean what we refer to as aggregate efficiency. One should keep that in mind when reading Ylvinger’s (2000) criticism on using the average unit to measure industry efficiency. On the other hand, Färe et al. (1992) estimated structural and aggregate efficiency by using what they referred respectively to as the industry and the firm linear programming models.

  4. See Nesterenko and Zelenyuk (2007), Pachkova (2009), ten Raa (2011), Fang and Li (2013) and Peyrache (2013).

  5. See for example Kittelsen and Førsund (1992) Hjalmarsson and Veiderpass (1992), Torgersen et al. (1996), Halsteinli et al. (2001), Arocena and Waddams Price (2002) and Odeck and Alkadi (2004).

  6. In a multi-output setting, allocation inefficiency does not matter in the aggregation of technical inefficiency scores as long as each firm is as allocatively inefficient as the industry (Färe and Grosskopf 2004, p. 116). Even in this case though we cannot avoid using price dependent weights.

  7. The same is true in the case of input orientation as long as production technology employs a single input and thus can be represented by an input requirement function.

  8. Throughout the paper when a quotation is used, words or phrases in brackets are our own additions.

  9. Here we follow Färe et al. (1985) tradition and we define output-oriented technical efficiency to be equal or greater than one. Notice however that Farrell (1957) defined all his efficiency measures to be between zero and one, i.e., the inverse of (1). Our main results hold for Farrell (1957) efficiency measures as well after the appropriate adjustments to aggregation weights in (5) are made by means of the denominator rule, which requires (see Färe and Karagiannis 2013) the weighting shares to be defined in terms of denominator variable of the relevant index in order to ensure consistent aggregation of ratio-type performance measures.

  10. Färe et al. (1992) used a single output, constant-returns-to-scale model and thus can aggregate firms’ output just by inserting the total amount of factors. This cannot be done without the assumption of constant returns to scale as mentioned by a referee. No such an assumption is made in (2) below or in Eq. (4) of Li and Ng (1995) that provides the efficiency measurement counterpart of Eq. (3) in (Färe et al. 1992).

  11. Notice that (2) differs from Eq. (4) in Li and Ng (1995) where there is an error in the sum of the intensity variables that should be equal to the number of constituent firms and not equal to one.

  12. That the centralized resource allocation DEA model is equivalent to Färe et al. (1992) structural efficiency model becomes apparent after the simplification introduced by Mar-Molinero et al. (2014); see in particular their Eq. (3) that is the input-oriented counterpart of (2) above.

  13. Nesterenko and Zelenyuk (2007, lemma 3) have extended this result to measures of allocative and revenue efficiency. On the other hand, Lozano and Villa (2004), Du et al. (2010) and Fang (2013) have shown a similar result for the centralized resource allocation DEA model.

  14. This proof was suggested by one of the referees to who I am indebted. Notice that (1) and (2) results in the same efficiency score but in different intensity variables, which are however related to one another.

  15. Notice that Farrell (1957) considered a single-output technology, an input-oriented measure of efficiency and implicit in his definition are the assumptions of identical firm technology and constant returns to scale. Färe and Karagiannis (2014) show that his suggestion for the aggregation weights could have been correct if he had referred to potential (instead of observed) output shares. In that case the aggregate efficiency measure would reflect potential input savings.

  16. In the case of multi-output technologies and allocative inefficiency, price dependent weights (i.e., revenue shares) should be used for consistent aggregation of technical efficiency scores.

  17. Since the following aggregation scheme uses observed output shares as weights, which is the denominator of the \( F_{O}^{k} \left( {x^{k} ,y^{k} } \right) \) index, it does not violate. monotonicity and moreover, it is consistent with an intuitive interpretation of industry output as the one that can be produced by making all firms work with average technical efficiency (Färe and Karagiannis 2013). For similar concerns on productivity measures see van Biesebroeck (2008).

  18. Bjurek et al. (1992), using the inverse of \( F_{O}^{k} \left( {x^{k} ,y^{k} } \right) \) as their efficiency index, proposed the ratio of industry total observed (actual) to potential output as a measure of aggregate technical efficiency.

  19. Li and Cheng (2007, proposition 2) shown that aggregate technical efficiency for a group or industry with constant-returns-to-scale technology is equal to Ylvinger’s (2000) “structural efficiency” measure with restricted (i.e., common to all firms) weights in aggregating potential and observed (actual) outputs.

  20. ten Raa (2011) referred to reallocation efficiency as industrial organization efficiency.

  21. Nesterenko and Zelenyuk (2007, proposition 2) decomposed reallocation efficiency into a technical and an allocative component, as has been done with other radial economic efficiency measures (i.e., revenue or cost). However their assertion that the allocative component can take values greater or less than one is incompatible with the output-oriented nature of reallocation efficiency.

  22. To prove this for the single-output case, divide both sides of Eq. (11) in Färe et al. (1992) by the observed industry output to obtain the corresponding output-oriented technical efficiency measures.

  23. Li and Cheng (2007, corollary 1) shown that the average of all individual technical efficiency scores is equal to Ylvinger’s (2000) “structural efficiency” measure with flexible (i.e., firm-specific) weights in aggregating potential and observed (actual) outputs.

References

  • Aigner DJ, Chu SF (1968) On estimating the industry production function. Am Econ Rev 58:826–839

    Google Scholar 

  • Arocena P, Waddams Price C (2002) Generating efficiency: economic and environmental regulation of public and private electricity generators in spain. Int J Ind Organ 20:41–69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjurek H, Kjulin U, Gustavsson B (1992) Efficiency, productivity and determinants of inefficiency at public day care centers in Sweden. Scand J Econ 94(supplement):173–187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bogetoft P, Otto L (2011) Benchmarking with DEA, SFA, and R. Springer, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Briec W, Dervaux B, Leleu H (2003) Aggregation of directional distance functions and industrial efficiency. J Econ 79:237–261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charnes A, Cooper WW, Rhodes E (1981) Evaluating program and managerial efficiency: an application of data envelopment analysis to program follow through. Manage Sci 27:668–697

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Du J, Liang L, Chen Y, Bi GB (2010) DEA-based production planning. Omega 38:105–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fang L (2013) A generalized DEA model of centralized resource allocation. Eur J Oper Res 228:405–412

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fang L, Li H (2013) A comment on solving the puzzles of structural efficiency. Eur J Oper Res 230:444–446

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S (2004) New directions: efficiency and productivity. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht

    Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Karagiannis G (2013) The denominator rule for share-weighting aggregation, unpublished manuscript

  • Färe R, Karagiannis G (2014) A postscript on aggregate Farrell efficiencies. Eur J Oper Res 233:784–786

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Zelenyuk V (2003) On aggregate Farrell efficiencies. Eur J Oper Res 146:615–620

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Lovell CAK (1985) The measurement of efficiency of production. Kluwer Academic Press, Dordrecht

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Li SK (1992) Linear programming models for firm and industry performance. Scand J Econ 94:599–608

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell MJ (1957) The measurement of productive efficiency. J R Stat S Ser A 120:253–290

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Førsund FR, Hjalmarsson L (1974) On the measurement of productive efficiency. Swed J Econ 76:141–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Førsund FR, Hjalmarsson L (1979) Generalised Farrell measures of efficiency: an application to milk processing in Swedish dairy plants. Econ J 89:294–315

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Førsund FR, Kittelsen SAC (1998) Productivity development of Norwegian electricity distribution utilities. Resour Energy Econ 20:207–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halsteinli V, Kittelsen SAC, Magnussen J (2001) Scale, Efficiency and organization of norwegian psychiatric outpatient clinics for children. J Ment Health Policy Econ 4:79–90

    Google Scholar 

  • Hjalmarsson L, Veiderpass A (1992) Efficiency and ownership in Swedish electricity retail distribution. J Prod Anal 3:7–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansen L (1972) Production functions, North-Holland

  • Kittelsen SAC, Førsund FR (1992) Efficiency analysis of Norwegian district courts. J Prod Anal 3:277–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li SK, Cheng YS (2007) Solving the puzzles of structural efficiency. Eur J Oper J 180:713–722

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li SK, Ng YC (1995) Measuring the productive efficiency of a group of firms. Int Adv Econ Res 1:377–390

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lozano S, Villa G (2004) Centralized resource allocation using data envelopment analysis. J Prod Anal 22:143–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mar-Molinero C, Prior D, Segovia MM, Portillo F (2014) On centralized resource utilization and its reallocation using DEA. Ann Oper Res 221:273–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nesterenko V, Zelenyuk V (2007) Measuring potential gains form reallocation of resources. J Prod Anal 28:107–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ng YC, Li SK (2000) Measuring the research performance of Chinese Higher Education Institutions: an application of data envelopment analysis. Educ Econ 8:139–156

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Odeck J, Alkadi A (2004) The perfromance of subsidized urban and rural public bus operators: empirical evidence from Norway. Ann Reg Sci 38:413–431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olley GS, Pakes A (1996) The dynamics of productivity in the telecommunication equipment industry. Econometrica 64:1263–1297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pachkova EV (2009) Restricted reallocation of resources. Eur J Oper Res 196:1049–1057

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peyrache A (2013) Industry structural inefficiency and potential gains from mergers and break-ups: a comprehensive approach. Eur J Oper Res 230:422–430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ten Raa T (2011) Benchmarking and industry performance. J Prod Anal 36:285–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Torgersen AM, Førsund FR, Kittelsen SAC (1996) Slack-adjusted efficiency measures and ranking of efficient units. J Prod Anal 7:379–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Biesebroeck J (2008) Aggregating and decomposing productivity. Rev Bus Econ 2:122–146

    Google Scholar 

  • Ylvinger S (2000) Industry performance and structural efficiency measures: solutions to problems in firm models. Eur J Oper Res 121:164–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This paper was presented at the Conference in Memory of Professor Lennart Hjalmarsson, hold at Gothenburg, Sweden, Dec. 7–8, 2012. I would like to thank session participants for a constructive and stimulating discussion. Rolf Färe as always provided inspired comments and suggestions. Svante Ylvinger supplied several related materials and Finn Førsund gave useful guidelines that both help me in revising the paper. Last but not least, the paper has benefited of valuable comments from two anonymous referees of this journal.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Giannis Karagiannis.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Karagiannis, G. On structural and average technical efficiency. J Prod Anal 43, 259–267 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-015-0439-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-015-0439-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation