Skip to main content
Log in

Licensing versus selling in transactions for exploiting patented technological knowledge assets in the markets for technology

  • Published:
The Journal of Technology Transfer Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the determinants of the types of technology transactions in the markets for technology. On the basis of the relationship between the characteristics of a firm’s patents and the firm’s decision on whether to license out or sell these patented technologies, we empirically analyze the determinants of the decision. We employ interlocked patent data from the representative Korean market for technology, the National Technology Bank, using a bivariate probit regression model in a theoretical framework that includes the option and transaction cost perspectives. Overall, the results show that the relationship between licensing and selling, the major alternatives in technology transactions, is strongly substitutive. The major finding of this study is that firms in markets for technology tend to prefer licensing their patents when uncertainty is low or transaction cost is high, whereas they tend to prefer selling their patents under opposite conditions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Elton et al. (2002) show that 10 % of patents from research-oriented firms have never been used, even for a protective purpose, and that if the unused patents were to be licensed, the annual profits of patent-owning firms would increase by 5 %.

  2. In reality, mixed licensing (i.e., lump sum plus running royalties) is a commonly chosen form of transaction (Chiesa et al. 2008). According to Thomson Financial’s Securities Data Company (SDC) Database, 66 % of all licensing contracts from 1997 to 2004 included royalties.

  3. Regardless of uncertainty, the cost of maintaining the ownership of patents increases every year, as does the financial burden of ownership (Bessen 2008). Therefore, firms are motivated to sell obsolete technologies for financial reasons as well.

  4. The Department of Defense (DoD) and the National Aeronautics and Space Administration (NASA) in the United States also use a similar definition of technology readiness level.

  5. Gambardella et al. (2007) have a different concept of importance. They consider a patent whose owner’s share in the technological field is high to be important.

  6. Palomeras (2007) defines core patent differently from our study by judging a patent in the technological field that accounts for more than 5 % of the patent holder’s entire patent portfolio to be a core patent.

References

  • Andrews, F. M. (1979). Scientific productivity: The effectiveness of research groups in six countries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arora, A. (1996). Contracting for tacit knowledge: The provision of technical service in technology licensing contracts. Journal of Development Economics, 50, 233–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arora, A., & Forfuri, A. (2003). Licensing the market for technology. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 52, 277–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arora, A., Forfuri, A., & Gambardella, A. (2001). Markets for technology and their implications for corporate strategy. Industrial and Corporate Change, 10, 419–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bessen, J. (2008). The value of U.S. patents by owner and patent characteristics. Research Policy, 37, 932–945.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyens, K. (1998). Externe Verwertung von Technologischem Wissen. Wiesbaden: DUV, Dt. Univ.-Verl.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Brorsen, B. W., Dicks, M. R., & Just, W. B. (1996) Regional and farm structure effects of planting flexibility. Review of Agricultural Economics, 18, 467–475.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chakravarthy, B. S. (1985). Business-government partnership in emerging industries: Lessons from the American synfuels experience. Advances in Strategic Management, 3, 257–275.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chesbrough, H. W. (2003). Open innovation: The new imperative for creating and profiting from technology. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiesa, V., Manzini, R., & Pizzurno, E. (2008). The market for technological intangibles: A conceptual framework for commercial transactions. International Journal of Learning and Intellectual Capital, 5(2), 186–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chung, K., & Park, S. (2005). A study of local large corporations technology marketing activating programs. Journal of Korea Technology Innovation Society, 8(1), 1–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clemons, E., & Row, M. (1992). Information technology and industrial cooperation: The changing economics of coordination and ownership. Journal of Management Information Systems, 9, 9–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elton, J., Shah, B., & Voyzey, J. (2002). Intellectual property: Partnering for profit. The Mckinsey Quarterly, 4, 59–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Folta, T. (1998). Governance and uncertainty: The tradeoff between administrative control and commitment. Strategic Management Journal, 19, 1007–1028.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ford, D. (1988). Develop your technology strategy. Long Range Planning, 21(5), 85–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ford, D., & Ryan, C. (1981). Taking technology to market. Harvard Business Review, 59(2), 117–126.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galbraith, C. S., & Merrill, G. B. (1991). The effect of compensation program and structure on SBU competitive strategy: A study of technology intensive firms. Strategic Management Journal, 12, 353–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gambardella, A., Giuri, P., & Luzzi, A. (2007). The market for patents in Europe. Research Policy, 36, 1163–1183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Granstrand, O. (2000). The economics and management of intellectual property: Towards intellectual capitalism. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W. (1998). Gender economics courses in liberal arts colleges: Further results. Journal of Economic Education, 29(4), 291–300.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W. (2003). Econometric analysis. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B. H., Jaffe, A., & Trajtenberg, M. (2005). Market value and patent citations. RAND Journal of Economics, 36, 16–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Halstead, R. (1993). Protecting intellectual property: Understanding and using trademarks, patents, design, and copyright in business. London: ICSA Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamel, G. (1991). Competition for competence and interpartner learning within international strategic alliances. Strategic Management Journal, 12(1), 83–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamel, G., Doz, Y. L., & Prahalad, C. K. (1989). Collaborate with your competitors and win. Harvard Business Review, 67(1), 133–139.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harhoff, D., Narin, F., Scherer, F. M., & Vopel, K. (1999). Citation frequency and the value of patented inventions. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 81, 511–515.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, D., & Hegde, D. (2005). Highly innovative small firms in the markets for technology. Research Policy, 34, 703–716.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Irish, V. (2005). Intellectual property rights for engineers (2nd ed.). London: The Institute of Electrical Engineers.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kline, D. (2003). Sharing the corporate crown jewels. MIT Sloan Management Review, 44, 89–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kogut, B. (1991). Joint ventures and the option to expand and acquire. Management Science, 37, 19–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lanjouw, J., & Schankerman, M. (1999). The quality of ideas: Measuring innovation with multiple indicators. NBER, WP 7345.

  • Lawani, S. M. (1986). Some bibliometric correlates of quality in scientific research. Scientometrics, 9, 13–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lerner, J. (1994). The importance of patent scope: An empirical analysis. RAND Journal of Economics, 25, 319–333.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenthaler, U. (2005). External commercialization of knowledge: Review and research agenda. International Journal of Management Reviews, 7, 231–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenthaler, U. (2008). Open innovation in practice: An analysis of strategic approaches to technology transactions. Transactions on Engineering Management, 55(1), 148–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenthaler, U., & Ernst, H. (2006). Attitudes to externally organising knowledge management tasks: A review, reconsideration and extension of the NIH syndrome. R&D Management, 36(4), 367–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madhok, A., & Tallman, S. B. (1998). Stormy open marriages are better: Evidence from US, Japanese and French cooperative ventures in commercial aircraft. Columbia Journal of World Business, 22, 87–95.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGrath, R. (1997). A real options logic for initiating technology positioning investments. Academy of Management Review, 22, 974–996.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGrath, R., MacMillan, I., & Tushman, M. (1992). The role of executive team actions in shaping dominant designs: Towards the strategic shaping of technological progress. Strategic Management Journal, 13, 137–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Megantz, R. C. (2002). Technology management: Developing and implementing effective licensing programs. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merges, R. P., & Nelson, R. R. (1990). On the complex economics of patent scope. Columbia Law Review, 90, 839–916.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Motohashi, K. (2008). Licensing or not licensing? An empirical analysis of the strategic use of patents by Japanese firms. Research Policy, 37(9), 1548–1555.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R., & Winter, S. (1982). An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Belknap: Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palomeras, N. (2007). An analysis of pure-revenue technology licensing. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 16, 971–994.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Park, H. (2002). A study on improved roles of cyber technology market in Korea. The Journal of Internet Electronic Commerce Research, 2(2), 143–165.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patel, P., & Pavitt, K. (1997). The technological competencies of the world’s largest firms: Complex and path-dependent, but not much variety. Research Policy, 26, 141–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prahalad, C. K., & Hamel, G. (1990). The core competence and the corporation. Harvard Business Review, 3, 71–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pratt, J. W. (1964). Risk aversion in the small and in the large. Econometrics, 32, 132–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reitzig, M. (2002). Improving patent valuation methods for management: Validating new indicators by understanding patent strategies. LEFIC working paper 9.

  • Robertson, T. S., & Gatignon, H. (1998). Technology development mode: A transaction cost conceptualization. Strategic Management Journal, 19, 515–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robins, J. A. (1987). Organizational economics: Notes on the use of transaction cost theory in the study of organizations. Administrative Science Quarterly, 32, 68–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schankerman, M., & Pakes, A. (1986). Estimates of the value of patent rights in European countries during the post-1950 period. Economic Journal, 96, 1052–1076.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seo, S., Jeong, K., Choi, S., Lee, G., Park, K., Hng, J., et al. (1996). A study on the establishment of investment strategies of R&D projects in information and telecommunications area. Daejeon: ETRI.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapira, Z. (1995). Risk taking: A managerial perspective. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shenhar, A. J., Dvir, D., Milosevic, D., Mulenberg, J., Patanakul, P., Reilly, R., et al. (2005). Toward a NASA-specific project management framework. Engineering Management Journal, 17(4), 8–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steensma, K. H., & Corley, K. G. (2000). On the performance of technology-sourcing partnerships: The interaction between partner interdependence and technology attributes. Academy of Management Journal, 43, 1045–1067.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15, 285–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tripsas, M., Schrader, S., & Sobrero, M. (1995). Discouraging opportunistic behavior in collaborative R&D: A new role for government. Research Policy, 24, 367–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tushman, M., & Anderson, P. (1986). Technological discontinuities and organizational environments. Administrative Science Quarterly, 31, 439–465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sungki Lee.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Jeong, S., Lee, S. & Kim, Y. Licensing versus selling in transactions for exploiting patented technological knowledge assets in the markets for technology. J Technol Transf 38, 251–272 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-012-9252-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-012-9252-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation