Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Crime, prosecutors, and the certainty of conviction

  • Published:
European Journal of Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

It has been laid down as a maxim on this subject, that the certainty of punishment is more effectual than the severity of punishment, in deterring offenders.

Leigh Hunt, in: ‘The Examiner’, No 365, 25 Dec. 1814, p. 829.

Abstract

This paper tests predictions of a structural, augmented supply-of-offenders model regarding the relative effects of police, public prosecution and courts, respectively, on crime. Using detailed data on the different stages of the criminal prosecution process in Germany, empirical evidence suggests that public prosecutors and their influence on the probability of conviction play a major role in explaining the variation of crime rates, while the impact of the severity of punishment is small and insignificant.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In 2008, the number of dismissals performed by German prosecutors was 1.006 Mio, compared to 0.886 Mio convictions and 0.170 Mio acquittals in courts (Heinz 2010, p. 49). The German practice is not directly comparable to plea bargaining in the US, where prosecutorial discretion comprises formulating the charge, deciding when or how to reduce the charge, and reductions of prison sentences against pleading guilty to the charge (see, e.g., Piehl and Bushway 2007). Over 90 % of cases were disposed of by a guilty plea (Pastore and Maguire 2003).

  2. See, among others, Heckman (2000) and Deaton (2010), and the Symposium of the Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24(2), for the importance of structural econometrics in public policy analysis.

  3. In the econometric model, p will be decomposed into p cl (measured as clearance rate) and p ac|cl p cv|ac (overall ‘conviction rate’). The reason for constructing a product instead of using all variables separately lies in the rather small variance of the share of convictions (given indictment), p cv|ac , over time and across states. Empirically, the variance of p ac|cl p cv|ac is driven by p ac|cl , i.e. discretionary influences of prosecutors covered by the indictment rate (see the descriptive evidence below).

  4. The presented model could be extended by separate treatment of all three different stages p = p cl p ac|cl p cv|ac of general deterrence, but expected effects of p are identical to those of all factors underlying p unless standard assumptions would be changed.

  5. In Germany, in 2008 less than every tenth (8.0%) judgment imposed an unconditional prison sentence. In 1950, this share was still at 39.1% (see Heinz 2010).

  6. In the aftermath of the Criminal Law Reform (1969) the prevailing opinion is to avoid any criminal record, or, if conviction still seemed justified, to avoid imprisonment. The rationale behind this legal norm is that offenders, in particular young offenders, should not lose their future legal income opportunities, because this would increase the risk of recidivism. According to German criminologists, the 1969 reform was considered the most important change in criminal policy after World War II. The reform, also dubbed the “Grand Criminal Law Reform” (Grosse Strafrechtsreform), which came into force in 1975, and is thus fully covered by the panel data set (1977–2001) used in this paper. See Busch (2005) and Heinz (2006) for historical details of the reform.

  7. This condition is in the vein of Bentham’s (1781) ‘Principles of Morals and Legislation’. According to Rule 1 of his ‘Of the Proportion between Punishments and Offences’ The value of the punishment must not be less in any case than what is sufficient to outweigh that of the profit of the offence (p. 141). Moreover, Rule 7 states To enable the value of the punishment to outweigh that of the profit of the offence, it must be increased, in point of magnitude, in proportion as it falls short in point of certainty (p. 143/144).

  8. In 1995, imprisonment rates in the respective countries have been as follows: Austria 84, France 89, Germany 81, Italy 83, Sweden 66, England and Wales 100 (International Center for Prison Studies 2012).

  9. Formally, criminologists refer to ‘diversion’ as the circumvention of formal sanctioning (or sentencing) of a crime suspect who, based on the circumstances of the case, could be successfully prosecuted but whose case is dropped conditionally or unconditionally for so-called ‘reasons of expediency’. Diversion can be applied in all cases concerning offences which are not punishable by a minimum penalty of 1 year or more (see Heinz 2006, or Weigend 1995, for details).

  10. Note that numbers in East Germany do not differ much from the development in West Germany (see Heinz 2010).

  11. In 2008, the ratio of dismissals without further legal restraints to all dismissals (by courts and prosecutors) amounted to 87% (own calculation based on Heinz 2010, p. 49–52).

  12. The creation of a comprehensive system of indicators for crime and prosecution requires merging data on crime and suspects from police data (PCS) with data on criminal prosecution collected by the German Statistical Office (StVStat). Among others, considerable difficulties were found in different registration categories in PCS and StVStat statistics, in treating offenders who have committed various offences which are simultaneously dealt with in court, the disparity between PCS and StVStat in the registration date, and revision of suspect counts in the PCS. As discussed at length in Spengler (2004, 2006), most of these data problems were dispelled by suitable approximations.

  13. However, given that the newly formed German states have had an impact on the overall German law system as well as on income, unemployment, population structure etc. after German unification in 1990, considering isolated ‘West’ or ‘East’ German universes more and more ceases to be a sensible research strategy. Considering a period such as 1977–2001 might thus be considered a compromise between the advantages of long time series on the one hand and structural changes in the population of interest on the other hand.

  14. Descriptive statistics of included variables are presented in the Appendix.

  15. Note that we distinguish between this conviction rate performed in a court and the conviction rate defined as the ratio of convictions to suspects with the latter being consistent with the theoretical and econometric meaning of ‘convictions’.

  16. According to BKA (2010), only 6.9% of suspects were 60 years or older in 2009 (in 1977, the first year which enters our econometric analyses, the share amounted to 4.2%, see BKA 1978).

  17. In 1990, the state passed a bill that renewed and extended the idea of the federal reform of 1969.

  18. As shown above, the theoretical prediction would be based on increasing marginal sanctions. To keep the model linear and in line with usual specifications of general deterrence models, we simplify this theoretical prediction.

  19. The German population statistics do not distinguish between migrants with and without German citizenship. For this reason, ‘migrants’ cover the share of foreign nationals in the German resident population.

  20. Deviating from official crime statistics, we do not treat robbery as violent but as property crime because it mainly entails illegally transferring ownership from one person to the other.

  21. Of, course, fines are not always applicable (e.g. in case of rape) such that the ratio of fines is zero in these cases.

  22. In general, data cover the time period 1977–2001, leading to 240 observations (in growth rates). Different starting points for few states, and, following some communication with representatives of the German Statistical Office, omitting faulty and evidently mis-recorded data points causes eight missing values such that Tables 5 and further results are based on 232 observations.

  23. Comparing this specification to an unrestricted FGLS model by use of an F Test again shows no statistical difference (also cf. the restricted and unrestricted R2s which are 0.397 and 0.417, respectively).

  24. One-third of petty thefts in Germany, for example, are cases of shoplifting (Bundeskriminalamt 2010). As a rule, however, registered cases of shoplifting are characterized by an offender being caught red-handed, the case being cleared immediately. If, ceteris paribus, the number of registered cases of shoplifting were now to increase (decrease) through an increase (decrease) in controls, the petty-theft rate would then rise (fall) with simultaneously increasing (decreasing) the specific clearance rate.

  25. Simultaneities between the crime rate and other criminal prosecution indicators are also conceivable. As these are less apparent than in the case of the clearance rate, however, they remain unaccounted for.

References

  • Aebi, M. (2004). Crime trends in Western Europe from 1990 to 2000. European Journal on Criminal Policy and Research, 10(2–3), 163–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, T. W., & Hsiao, C. (1981). Estimation of dynamic models with error components. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 76(375), 598–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment data. Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltagi, B. H. (2006). Estimating an economic model of crime using panel data from North Carolina, replication study. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 21(4), 543–547.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bayer, P., Hjalmarsson, R., & Pozen, D. (2009). Building criminal capital behind bars: Peer effects in juvenile corrections. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(1), 105–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, N., & Katz, J. N. (1995). What to do (and what not to do) with time-series cross-section data. American Political Science Review, 89(3), 634–647.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bentham, J. (1781). An introduction to the principles of morals and legislation. Batoche Books, Kitchener 2000, http://socserv.mcmaster.ca/econ/ugcm/3ll3/bentham/morals.pdf, 13 April 2011.

  • Bhargava, P., Franzini, L., & Narendranathan, W. (1982). Serial correlation and fixed effects models. Review of Economic Studies, 49, 129–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Block, M. K., & Heinecke, J. M. (1975). A labor theoretic analysis of the criminal choice. American Economic Review, 65(3), 314–325.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bundeskriminalamt (BKA). (1978). Polizeiliche Kriminalstatistik 1977. Wiesbaden.

  • Bundeskriminalamt (BKA). (2010). Polizeiliche Kriminalstatistik 2009. Wiesbaden.

  • Busch, T. (2005). Die deutsche Strafrechtsreform. Ein Rückblick auf die sechs Reformen des deutschen Strafrechts (19691998). Kieler rechtswissenschaftliche Abhandlungen (NF), Band 47, Baden–Baden: Nomos-Verlag.

  • Carr-Hill, R. A., & Stern, N. H. (1973). An Econometric model of the supply and control of recorded offenses in England and Wales. Journal of Public Economics, 2(4), 289–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, M. K., & Shapiro, J. M. (2007). Does prison harden inmates? A discontinuity-based approach. American Law and Economics Review, 9(1), 1–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornwell, C., & Trumbull, W. N. (1994). Estimating the economic model of crime with panel data. Review of Economics and Statistics, 76(2), 360–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton, A. (2010). Instruments, randomization and learning about development. Journal of Economic Literature, 48(2), 424–455.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Donohue, J. (2009). Assessing the relative benefits of incarceration: The overall change over the previous decades and the benefits on the margin. In S. Raphael & M. Stoll (Eds.), Do prisons make us safer? The benefits and costs of the prison boom. New York: Russell Sage Foundation Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Durbin, J. (1960). Estimation of parameters in time-series regression models. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series B, 22(1), 799–808.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehrlich, I. (1973). Participation in illegitimate activities: A theoretical and empirical investigation. Journal of Political Economy, 81(3), 521–565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eide, E., Rubin, P. H., & Shepherd, J. M. (2006). Economics of crime. Foundations and Trends in Microeconomics, 2(3), 205–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Entorf, H. (1997). Random walks with drifts: Nonsense regression and spurious fixed-effect estimation. Journal of Econometrics, 80(2), 287–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Entorf, H. (2012). Expected recidivism among young offenders: Comparing specific deterrence under juvenile and adult criminal law. European Journal of Political Economy, 28(4), 414–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Entorf, H., & Spengler, H. (2000). Socioeconomic and demographic factors of crime in Germany: Evidence from panel data of the German States. International Review of Law and Economics, 20(1), 75–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Entorf, H., & Spengler, H. (2008). Is being soft on crime the solution to rising crime rates? Evidence from Germany, IZA Discussion Paper No 3710.

  • Entorf, H., & Winker, P. (2008). Investigating the drugs-crime channel in economics of crime models: Evidence from panel data of the German States. International Review of Law and Economics, 28(1), 8–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Funk, P. (2004). On the effective use of stigma as a crime-deterrent. European Economic Review, 48(4), 715–728.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • GESIS. (2007). The German system of social indicators: Key indicators 1950–2005. Key Public Safety and Crime. http://www.gesis.org/fileadmin/upload/dienstleistung/daten/soz_indikatoren/Schluesselindikatoren_en/keyindicators.pdf?download=true, 13 April 2011.

  • Grogger, J. (1998). Market wages and youth crime. Journal of Labor Economics, 16(4), 756–791.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J. J. (2000). Causal parameters and policy analysis in economics: A twentieth century retrospective. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(1), 45–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heineke, J. M. (Ed.). (1978). Economic models of criminal behaviour. North Holland, Amsterdam.

  • Heinz, W. (2006). Penal sanctions and sanctioning practice in the Federal Republic of Germany 1882–2004. University of Konstanz, The Konstanz Repository of Crime and Sanctioning, http://www.uni-konstanz.de/rtf/kis/sanks04_eng.htm, 13 April 2011.

  • Heinz, W. (2010). Das strafrechtliche Sanktionensystem und die Sanktionspraxis in Deutschland 1882–2008. Stand: Berichtsjahr 2008. Version: 1/2010. University of Konstanz. Online publication: http://www.uni-konstanz.de/rtf/kis/Sanktionierungspraxis-in-Deutschland-Stand-2008.pdf, 13 April 2011.

  • Heiskanen, M. (2010). Trends in police-recorded crime. In Harrendorf, S, Heiskanen, M, & Malby, S (Eds.) International statistics on crime and justice, European institute for crime prevention and control (HEUNI) and United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime (UNODC), Helsinki, HEUNI Publication Series No. 64.

  • Hunt, L. (1814). General view of the arguments in favor of an amelioration of the penal laws. In The examiner, no 352, 25 Sept. 1814, p. 621; essay was continued in No 365, 25 Dec 1814, p. 828.

  • International Centre for Prison Studies. (2012). World prison brief. http://www.prisonstudies.org, 3 December 2012.

  • Kessler, D. P., & Piehl, A. M. (1998). The Role of Discretion in the Criminal Justice System. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 14(2), 256–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • LaCasse, C., & Payne, A. B. (1999). Federal sentencing guidelines and mandatory minimum sentences: Do defendants bargain in the shadow of the judge? Journal of Law and Economics, 42(1), 245–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, S. D. (1997). Using electoral cycles in police hiring to estimate the effect of police on crime. American Economic Review, 87(3), 270–290.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, S. (2002). Using electoral cycles in police hiring to estimate the effect of police on crime: Reply. American Economic Review, 92(4), 1244–1250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin, M.-J. (2008). Does unemployment increase crime? Evidence from US data 1974–2000. Journal of Human Resources, 43(2), 413–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendes, S. M., & McDonald, M. D. (2001). Putting severity of punishment back in the deterrence package. Policy Studies Journal, 29(4), 588–610.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mustard, D. B. (2003). Reexamining criminal behavior: The importance of omitted variable bias. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(1), 205–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pastore, A., & Maguire, K. (2003). Sourcebook of criminal justice statistics: 2002. Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piehl, A., & Bushway, S. (2007). Measuring and explaining charge bargaining. Journal of Quantitative Criminology, 23, 105–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raphael, S., & Stoll, M. (2009). Why are so many Americans in prison? In S. Raphael & M. Stoll (Eds.), Do prisons make us safer? The benefits and costs of the prison boom (pp. 27–72). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raphael, S., & Winter-Ebmer, R. (2001). Identifying the effect of unemployment on crime. Journal of Law and Economics, 44(1), 259–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rasmussen, E. (1996). Stigma and self-fulfilling expectations of criminality. Journal of Law and Economics, 39(2), 519–543.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reed, W. R., & Ye, H. (2009). Which panel data estimator should I use? Applied Economics, 43(8), 1–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • PCS (Bundeskriminalamt) (various issues). Polizeiliche Kriminalstatistik (Police Crime Statistics), Wiesbaden.

  • Scottish Government. (2012). Prison statistics and population projections Scotland: 2011–2012. Scottish Government Statistician Group, http://www.scotland.gov.uk/Resource/0039/00396363.pdf. Accessed 3 Dec 2012.

  • Sjoquist, D. L. (1973). Property crime and economic behavior: Some empirical results. American Economic Review, 63(3), 439–446.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spelman, W. (2008). Specifying the relationship between crime and imprisonment. Journal of Quantitative Criminology, 24(2), 149–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spengler, H. (2004). Ursachen und Kosten der Kriminalität in Deutschland—drei empirische Untersuchungen (Doctoral Dissertation). Downloadable: http://elib.tu-darmstadt.de/diss/000531/.

  • Spengler, H. (2006). Eine panelökonometrische Überprüfung der ökonomischen Theorie der Kriminalität mit deutschen Bundesländerdaten. Journal of Economics and Statistics, 226(6), 687–714.

    Google Scholar 

  • Statistisches Bundesamt. (2006). Bevölkerung bis 2050: 11. koordinierte Bevölkerungsvorausberechnung, Wiesbaden: Statistisches Bundesamt.

  • Statistisches Bundesamt. (2012). Lange Zeitreihen zur Strafverfolgungsstatistik, Wiesbaden: Statistisches Bundesamt.

  • StVStat (Statistisches Bundesamt) (various issues). (2012 December 5). Strafverfolgungsstatistik (Criminal Prosecution Statistics), Wiesbaden: Statistisches Bundesamt. https://www.destatis.de/DE/Publikationen/Thematisch/Rechtspflege/StrafverfolgungVollzug/StrafverfolgungsstatistikfrueheresBundesgebietPDF_5243102.pdf?__blob=publicationFile.

  • Van Tulder, F., & Van der Torre, A. (1999). Modeling crime and the law enforcement system. International Review of Law and Economics, 19(4), 471–486.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walmsley, R. (2009). World prison population list (8th ed.). London: King’s College London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weigend, T. (1995). In Germany, fines often imposed in lieu of prosecution. In M. H. Tonry & K. Hamilton (Eds.), Intermediate sanctions in overcrowded times (pp. 50–55). New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Witte, A. D. (1980). Estimating the economic model of crime with individual data. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 94(1), 57–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wolpin, K. I. (1978). An economic analysis of crime and punishment in England and Wales, 1894–1967. Journal of Political Economy, 86(5), 815–840.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wolpin, K. I. (1980). A time series-cross section analysis of international variation in crime and punishment. Review of Economics and Statistics, 62(3), 417–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J. M. (2002). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, J. (1997). The effect of welfare programs on criminal behavior: A theoretical and empirical analysis. Economic Inquiry, 35(1), 120–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to Michael Burda, Christoph Engel, Gil Epstein, Martin Hellwig, Jan van Ours, John de New, Christoph Schmidt, Christian Traxler, Ben Vollaard, and seminar participants at the MPI Bonn, the University of Tilburg, the IZA conference on the Economics of Risky Behavior in Washington D.C., the RWI Essen and the 1st Bonn & Paris Meeting on Law and Economics in Paris for useful discussions. We would also like to thank Birgit Herrmann and an anonymous reviewer for helpful comments on an earlier version of the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Horst Entorf.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 8, 9, 10, 11, 12 and 13.

Table 8 Descriptive statistics
Table 9 Estimation in levels
Table 10 Property crimes (robbery, serious theft, petty theft, fraud); residuals adjusted for serial correlation
Table 11 Violent crimes (murder/manslaughter, rape and indecent assault, serious assault); residuals adjusted for serial correlation
Table 12 Property crimes, estimation of individual crime categories
Table 13 Violent crimes, estimation of individual categories

1.1 Proof of theoretical results presented in Sect. 2 (Eq. 2.5)

  1. a.

    Maximize expected utility:

$$ \begin{aligned} E\left( U \right) &= p(1 - p_{s|c} )U\,\left[ {A + L^{b} \left( {t_{\ell } } \right) + G\,\left( {t_{i} } \right)} \right] +\, pp_{s|c} U\left[ {A + G\left( {t_{i} } \right) - F\,\left( {t_{i} } \right)} \right] \\ & \quad + \left( {1 - p} \right)U\left[ {A + L\left( {t_{\ell } } \right) + G\left( {t_{i} } \right)} \right] \\ \end{aligned} $$
(A1)

Thus, three different payoffs need to be distinguished. Define

$$ \,Y_{1} \, = \,A\,\, + \,\,L\,\left( {t_{\ell } } \right)\,\, + \,G\,\,\left( {t_{i} } \right),\,Y_{2} = \,A\,\, + \,L^{b} \,\left( {t_{\ell } } \right)\, + \,G\,\left( {t_{i} } \right),Y_{3} \, = \,A\,\, + \,\,G\,\left( {t_{i} } \right)\,\, - F\,\left( {t_{i} } \right) $$

Using the implicit function theorem, we first define

$$ \begin{aligned} E_{i} &= \frac{\partial E\left( U \right)}{{\partial t_{i} }} = p(1 - p_{s|c} )U^{\prime } \left( {Y_{1} } \right)G^{\prime } \left( {t_{i} } \right) + pp_{s|c} U^{\prime } \left( {Y_{2} } \right)\left[ {G^{\prime } \left( {t_{i} } \right) - F^{\prime } \left( {t_{i} } \right)} \right] \\ & \quad + \left( {1 - p} \right)U^{\prime } \left( {Y_{3} } \right)G^{\prime } \left( {t_{i} } \right) = 0 \\ \end{aligned} $$

The second-order condition is

$$ \begin{aligned} E_{ii} &= p(1 - p_{s|c} )U^{\prime \prime } \left( {Y_{1} } \right)G^{\prime } \left( {t_{i} } \right)^{2} + p(1 - p_{s|c} )U^{\prime } \left( {Y_{1} } \right)G^{\prime \prime } \left( {t_{i} } \right) \\ \quad + pp_{s|c} U^{\prime \prime } \left( {Y_{2} } \right)\left[ {G^{\prime } \left( {t_{i} } \right) - F^{\prime } \left( {t_{i} } \right)} \right]^{2} + pp_{s|c} U^{\prime } \left( {Y_{2} } \right)\left[ {G^{\prime \prime } \left( {t_{i} } \right) - F^{\prime \prime } \left( {t_{i} } \right)} \right] \\ \quad + \left( {1 - p} \right)U^{\prime \prime } \left( {Y_{3} } \right)G^{\prime } \left( {t_{i} } \right)^{2} + \,\left( {1 - p} \right)U^{\prime } \left( {Y_{3} } \right)G^{\prime \prime } \left( {t_{i} } \right) \\ \end{aligned} $$
(A2)

\( E_{ii} \, < \,0 \Leftrightarrow \) assumptions 1 to 3 hold, i.e.

  • \( U^{\prime\prime}\,\, < \,0\,\,\,\,\, \)

  • \( G^{\prime\prime}\left( {t_{i} } \right)\, < \,0 \)

  • \( F^{\prime\prime}\left( {t_{i} } \right) > 0 \)

  1. b.

    The effect of detection and conviction:

$$ \frac{{\partial t_{i} }}{\partial p}\,\,\, = \,\, - \frac{{\frac{{\partial E_{i} }}{\partial p}}}{{\frac{{\partial E_{i} }}{{\partial t_{i} }}}}\,\, = \,\, - \,\frac{{(1 - p_{s|c} )\,U^{\prime}\left( {Y_{1} } \right)G^{\prime}\left( {t_{i} } \right)\,\, + p_{s|c} U^{\prime}\left( {Y_{2} } \right)\left[ {G^{\prime}\left( {t_{i} } \right) - F^{\prime}\left( {t_{i} } \right)} \right]\,\,\, - \,U^{\prime}\,\left( {Y_{3} } \right)\,G^{\prime}\,\left( {t_{i} } \right)}}{{E_{ii} }} $$
$$ = \, - \,\frac{{G^{\prime}\,\left( {t_{i} } \right)\,\left( {(1 - p_{s|c} )U^{\prime}\,\left( {Y_{1} } \right)\, - U^{\prime}\,\left( {Y_{3} } \right)} \right)\, + \,p_{s|c} U^{\prime}\,\left( {Y_{2} } \right)\,\left( {G^{\prime}\left( {t_{i} } \right)\, - F^{\prime}\left( {t_{i} } \right)} \right)}}{{E_{ii} }} $$
(A3)
$$ \frac{{\partial t_{i} }}{\partial p}\, < 0 \Leftrightarrow $$
  • \( G^{\prime } \left( {t_{i} } \right)\, - F^{\prime } \left( {t_{i} } \right) < 0 \) (see assumption 4)

  • \( Y_{3} - Y_{1} = L\,\left( {t_{\ell } } \right) - L^{b} \left( {t_{\ell } } \right) > 0 \Rightarrow (1 - p_{s|c} )U^{\prime } \left( {Y_{1} } \right) - U^{\prime } \left( {Y_{3} } \right) < 0 \) (assumption of ‘stigma’)

  1. c.

    The effect of non-custodial sentencing:

$$ \frac{{\partial \,t_{i} }}{{\partial (1 - p_{s|c} )}}\,\, = \,\, - \,\frac{{\frac{{\partial \,E_{i} }}{{\partial (1 - p_{s|c} )}}}}{{E_{ii} }} = \, - \,\frac{{p\,U^{\prime}\,\left( {Y_{1} } \right)\,G^{\prime}\,\left( {t_{i} } \right)\, - pU^{\prime}\,\left( {Y_{2} } \right)\,\left[ {G^{\prime}\,\left( {t_{i} } \right)\, - \,F^{\prime}\left( {t_{i} } \right)} \right]}}{{E_{ii} }} = \, - \,\frac{\left( + \right)\,\,\, - \,\,\,\left( - \right)}{\left( - \right)}\,\, > \,0 $$

Again, the unambiguous sign depends on the validity of Assumption 4.

  1. d.

    The effect of punishment:

Stricter punishment means increasing costs of crime at given crime intensity t l . A sufficient condition for growing sentencing costs is an increase in \( F^{\prime } \left( {t_{i} } \right) \). Studying the ceteris-paribus effect of elevated (marginal) cost of imprisonment, \( \bar{F}^{\prime }, \) on crime activities, we obtain:

$$ \frac{{\partial \,t_{i} }}{{\partial \bar{F}^{\prime } }} = - \frac{{\frac{{\partial \,E_{i} }}{{\partial \bar{F}^{\prime } }}}}{{E_{ii} }} = - \frac{{\left( { - \,p\,p_{s|c} \,\,U^{\prime } \left( {Y_{2} } \right)} \right)}}{{E_{ii} }} < 0 $$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Entorf, H., Spengler, H. Crime, prosecutors, and the certainty of conviction. Eur J Law Econ 39, 167–201 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-012-9380-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-012-9380-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation