Skip to main content
Log in

Improving Voluntary Public Good Provision Through a Non-governmental, Endogenous Matching Mechanism: Experimental Evidence

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Social norms can help to foster cooperation and to overcome the free-rider problem in the private provision of public goods. This paper focuses on the endogenous establishment of an average-oriented norm which sanctions deviations from average public good contributions. In a laboratory experiment, we analyse whether subjects are willing to implement a punishment and reward scheme at their own expense by applying the theory of non-governmental norm enforcement put forward by Buchholz et al. (J Public Econ Theory 16(6):899–916, 2014). Based on their theory, which omits a central authority but introduces an endogenously determined enforcement mechanism, we implement a two-stage public good game. In the first stage, subjects determine the strength of the sanctioning mechanism on their own. In the second stage, they decide on their personal contributions to the public good based on the established mechanism. In line with comparable pool punishment experiments, we find that subjects are apparently willing to contribute funds in order to establish a norm enforcement mechanism. Groups over-invest in the mechanism, but this over-investment decreases over time. These investments seem to be driven by the subjects’ previous individual contributions and partly by a number of strategic considerations, i.e. the previous average contribution made to the public good lowers the investment in the sanctioning mechanism. In the second stage of our experiment, higher norm enforcement parameters tend to lead to higher public good contributions. The earnings with the mechanism are on average higher than without.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See also Löschel and Rübbelke (2014), who discuss voluntary provision and undersupply of public goods in an international context.

  2. Buchholz et al. (2015) analyse Guttman’s scheme in a one-sided matching setting.

  3. For an approach with endogenously determined intensity of the social norm, see Lindbeck et al. (1999). Mengel (2008) provides another approach in which the rising number of agents internalising the social norm defines the degree of the social norm in a prisoners’ dilemma interaction model.

  4. Households initially consuming less than the average amount of energy use the descriptive norm as justification to consume more.

  5. Please note that the nominal unit prices of the private and public goods are assumed to be equal to unity.

  6. Please see Rege (2008) for a model in which social status is used to signal the non-observable abilities of subjects.

  7. For further discussion on voluntary provision of public goods with interior solutions, please see Laury and Holt (2008).

  8. In the instructions the attached table is based on Eq. (5) and provides the conversion of group investment, which the enforcement agency receives in order to determine the level of sanctioning (see Supporting Material).

  9. In settings with second-order punishment, individuals who do not contribute to the punishment regime are also punished.

  10. The high values result from some very high contributions which might indicate that subjects did not understand how the mechanism works.

  11. The upper bound of the first stage contribution is based on the theoretical proposition, put forward by Buchholz et al. (2014), that the average contribution to the enforcement mechanism is never higher than half of the endowment which in our case is 25.

  12. The individual’s contribution to the enforcement mechanism is the dependent variable. It is censored between zero and the endowment of 50 LD which calls for a censored model. Therefore, we provide a pooled Tobit analysis. We expect learning effects which are the reason for including the dependent variable—previous contributions to the mechanism—and previous public good contributions.

  13. Summary statistics of public good contribution by groups for each treatment can be provided upon request.

  14. Alternatively, one can use individual contributions as the basis for the calculation of the CIs. These intervals are similar, but a little smaller.

  15. Analyses for the baseline treatment can be provided upon request.

  16. See Goodwin (2012), Hagman et al. (2015) and Michalek et al. (2016) for the use of nudging in politics.

References

  • Allcott H (2011) Social norms and energy conservation. J Public Econ 95(9–10):1082–1095

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allcott H, Rogers T (2014) The short-run and long-run effects of behavioral interventions: experimental evidence from energy conservation. Am Econ Rev 104(10):3003–3037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni J (1988) Why free ride? Strategies and learning in public goods experiments. J Public Econ 37(3):291–304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni J (1993) An experimental test of the public-goods crowding-out hypothesis. Am Econ Rev 83(5):1317–1327

    Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni J, Bergstrom T (1996) Do government subsidies increase the private supply of public goods? Public Choice 88:295–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni J, Varian HR (1999) Preplay contracting in the prisoners’ dilemma. Proc Nat Acad Sci USA 96:10933–10938

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni J, Bernheim BD (2009) Social image and the 50–50 norm: a theoretical and experimental analysis of audience effects. Econometrica 77(5):1607–1636

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni J, Gee LK (2012) Gun for hire: delegated enforcement and peer punishment in public goods provision. J Public Econ 96(11):1036–1046

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni J, Gee LK (2015) Gunning for efficiency with third party enforcement in threshold public goods. Exp Econ 18(1):154–171

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod R (1986) An evolutionary approach to norms. Am Polit Sci Rev 80(4):1095–1111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azar OH (2004) What sustains social norms and how they evolve? The case of tipping. J Econ Behav Organ 54(1):49–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker RJ II, Walker JM, Williams AW (2009) Matching contributions and the voluntary provision of a pure public good: experimental evidence. J Econ Behav Organ 70(1–2):122–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balliet D (2010) Communication and cooperation in social dilemmas: a meta-analytic review. J Conflict Resolut 54(1):39–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balliet D, Mulder LB, Van Lange PAM (2011) Reward, punishment, and cooperation: a meta-analysis. Psychol Bull 137(4):594–615

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrom T, Blume L, Varian H (1986) On the private provision of public goods. J Public Econ 29(1):25–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boadway R, Pestieau P, Wildasin D (1989) Tax-transfer policies and the voluntary provision of public goods. J Public Econ 39(2):157–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bracht J, Figuières C, Ratto M (2008) Relative performance of two simple incentive mechanisms in a public goods experiment. J Public Econ 92(1–2):54–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchholz W, Cornes R, Rübbelke D (2011) Interior matching equilibria in a public good economy: an aggregative game approach. J Public Econ 95(7–8):639–645

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchholz W, Cornes R, Peters W, Rübbelke D (2015) Pareto improvement through unilateral matching of public good contributions: the role of commitment. Econ Lett 132:9–12

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchholz W, Falkinger J, Rübbelke D (2011) Non-governmental public norm enforcement in large societies as a two-stage game of voluntary public good provision. ANU working papers in economics and econometrics, 566

  • Buchholz W, Falkinger J, Rübbelke D (2014) Non-governmental public norm enforcement in large societies as a two-stage game of voluntary public good provision. J Public Econ Theory 16(6):899–916

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen Y, Li X, MacKie-Mason JK (2006) Online fund-raising mechanisms: a field experiment. Contrib Econ Anal Policy 5(2):1–37

  • Coleman J (1990) Foundations of social theory. Belknap Press/Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornes R, Sandler T (1985) The simple analytics of pure public good provision. Economica 52(205):103–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denant-Boemont L, Masclet D, Noussair CN (2007) Punishment, counterpunishment and sanction enforcement in a social dilemma experiment. Econ Theor 33:145–167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckel CC, Grossman PJ (2003) Rebate versus matching: does how we subsidize charitable contributions matter? J Public Econ 87(3):681–701

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckel CC, Grossman PJ (2004) Giving to secular causes by the religious and nonreligious: an experimental test of the responsiveness of giving to subsidies. Nonprofit Volunt Sect Q 33(2):271–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckel CC, Grossman PJ (2006) Do donors care about subsidy type: an experimental study, experiments investigating fundraising and charitable contributors. Res Exp Econ 11:157–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckel CC, Grossman PJ (2008) Subsidizing charitable contributions: a natural field experiment comparing matching and rebate subsidies. Exp Econ 11(3):234–252

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckel CC, Grossman PJ (2017) Comparing rebate and matching subsidies controlling for donors’ awareness: evidence from the field. J Behav Exp Econ 66:88–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egas M, Riedl A (2008) The economics of altruistic punishment and the maintenance of cooperation. Proc R Soc 275(1637):871–878

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellickson RC (2001) The evolution of social norms: a perspective from the legal academy. In: Hechter M, Opp KD (eds) Social norms. Russel Sage Foundation, New York, pp 35–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Ertan A, Page T, Putterman L (2009) Who to punish? Individual decisions and majority rule in mitigating the free rider problem. Eur Econ Rev 53(5):495–511

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falkinger J (1996) Efficient private provision of public goods by rewarding deviations from average. J Public Econ 62:413–422

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falkinger J, Fehr E, Gächter S, Winter-Ebmer R (2000) A simple mechanism for the efficient provision of public goods: experimental evidence. Am Econ Rev 90(1):247–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Fischbacher U (2004a) Social norms and human cooperation. Trends Cogn Sci 8(4):185–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Fischbacher U (2004b) Third-party punishment and social norms. Evol Human Behav 25(2):63–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Fischbacher U, Gächter S (2002) Strong reciprocity, human cooperation, and the enforcement of social norms. Human Nature 13(1):1–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Gächter S (2000) Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. Am Econ Rev 90(4):980–994

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Gächter S (2002) Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature 415:137–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher U (2007) z-tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Exp Econ 10(2):171–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gächter S, Renner R, Sefton M (2008) The long-run benefits of punishment. Science 322(5907):1510

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin T (2012) Why we should reject ‘nudge’. Politics 32(2):85–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greiner B (2004) An online recruitment system for economic experiments. In: Forschung und wissenschaftliches Rechnen, Kremer, K, Macho, V (eds) GWDG Bericht 63. Gesellschaft für Wissenschaftliche Datenverarbeitung Göttingen, pp 79–93

  • Gürerk Ö, Irlenbusch B, Rockenbach B (2006) The competitive advantage of sanctioning institutions. Science 312:108–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guttman JM (1978) Understanding collective action: matching behaviour. Am Econ Rev 68(2):251–255

    Google Scholar 

  • Guttman JM (1986) Matching behavior and collective action: some experimental evidence. J Econ Behav Organ 7:171–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guttman JM (1987) A non-Cournot model of voluntary collective action. Economica 54(213):1–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guttman JM (2013) On the evolution of conditional cooperation. Eur J Polit Econ 30:15–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hagman W, Andersson D, Västfjäll D, Tinghög G (2015) Public views on policies involving nudges. Rev Philos Psychol 6(3):439–453

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hechter M, Opp KD (2001) Introduction. In: Hechter M, Opp KD (eds) Social norms. Russel Sage Foundation, New York :xi-xx

    Google Scholar 

  • Horne C (2001) Sociological perspectives on the emergence of norms. In: Hechter M, Opp KD (eds) Social norms. Russel Sage Foundation, New York, pp 3–34

    Google Scholar 

  • Kamei K, Putterman L, Tyran JR (2015) State or nature? Endogenous formal versus informal tions in the voluntary provision of public goods. Exp Econ 18(1):38–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamijo Y, Nihonsugi T, Takeuchi A, Funaki Y (2014) Sustaining cooperation in social dilemmas: comparison of centralized punishment institutions. Games Econ Behav 84:180–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karlan D, List JA, Shafir E (2011) Small matches and charitable giving: evidence from a natural field experiment. J Public Econ 95(5):344–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keser C (1996) Voluntary contributions to a public good when partial contribution is a dominant strategy. Econ Lett 50(3):359–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kesternich M, Römer D, Löschel A (2016) The long-term impact of matching and rebate subsidies when public goods are impure: field experimental evidence from the carbon offsetting market. J Public Econ 137:70–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kesternich M, Löschel A, Ziegler, A (2014) Negotiating weights for burden sharing rules among heterogeneous parties: empirical evidence from a survey among delegates in international climate negotiations. ZEW discussion paper no 14-031, Mannheim

  • Kirchsteiger G, Puppe C (1997) On the possibility of efficient private provision of public goods through government subsidies. J Public Econ 66(1997):489–504

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kosfeld M, Okada A, Riedl A (2009) Institution formation in public goods games. Am Econ Rev 99(4):1335–1355

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krupka EL, Weber RA (2013) Identifying social norms using coordination games: why does dictator game sharing vary? J Eur Econ Assoc 11(3):495–524

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lange A, Löschel A, Vogt C, Ziegler A (2010) On the self-interested use of equity in international climate negotiations. Eur Econ Rev 54(3):359–375

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laury SK, Holt CA (2008) Voluntary provision of public goods: experimental results with interior Nash equilibria. Handbook of experimental economics results, vol 1, Chapter 84:792–801

  • Ledyard JO (1995) Public goods: a survey of experimental research. In: Kagel J, Roth AE (eds) Handbook of experimental economics. Princeton University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck A (1997) Incentives and social norms in household behaviour. AEA Pap Proc 87(2):370–377

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck A, Nyberg S, Weibull JW (1999) Social norms and economic incentives in the welfare state. Quart J Econ 114(1):1–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Löschel A, Rübbelke D (2014) On the voluntary provision of international public goods. Economica 81(322):195–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markussen T, Putterman L, Tyran JR (2014) Self-organization for collective action: an experimental study of voting on sanction regimes. Rev Econ Stud 81:301–324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Masclet D, Noussair CN, Tucker S, Villeval MC (2003) Monetary and nonmonetary punishment in the voluntary contributions mechanism. Am Econ Rev 93(1):366–380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Masclet D, Noussair CN, Tucker S, Villeval MC (2013) Threat and punishment in public good experiments. Econ Inq 51(2):1421–1441

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mengel F (2008) Matching structure and the cultural transmission of social norms. J Econ Behav Organ 67:608–623

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michalek G, Meran G, Schwarze R, Yildiz Ö (2016) Nudging as a new ’soft‘ tool in environmental policy—an analysis based on insights from cognitive and social psychology. J Environ Law Policy 2–3:169–207

    Google Scholar 

  • Nicklisch A, Grecenig K, Thöni C (2015) Information-sensitive leviathans—the emergence of centralized punishment. WiSO-HH working paper series, no 24

  • Nikiforakis N (2008) Punishment and counter-punishment in public good games: can we really govern ourselves? J Public Econ 92(1–2):91–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nikiforakis N (2010) Feedback, punishment and cooperation in public good experiments. Games Econ Behav 68(2):689–702

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nikiforakis N, Noussair CN, Wilkening T (2012) Normative conflicts and feuds: the limits of self-enforcement. J Public Econ 96(9–10):797–807

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (2000) Collective action and the evolution of social norms. J Econ Perspect 14(3):137–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rege M (2004) Social norms and private provision of public goods. J Public Econ Theory 6(1):65–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rege M (2008) Why do people care about social status? J Econ Behav Organ 66(2):233–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reuben E, Riedl A (2013) Enforcement of contribution norms in public good games with heterogenous populations. Games Econ Behav 77(1):122–137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts RD (1987) Financing public goods. J Polit Econ 95(2):420–437

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts RD (1992) Government subsidies to private spending on public goods. Public Choice 74(2):133–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz PW, Nolan JM, Cialdini RB, Goldstein NJ, Griskevicius V (2007) The constructive, destructive, and reconstructive power of social norms. Psychol Sci 18(5):429–434

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sefton M, Steinberg R (1996) Reward structures in public good experiments. J Public Econ 61(2):263–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sethi R, Somanathan E (1996) The evolution of social norms in common property resource use. Am Econ Rev 86(4):766–788

    Google Scholar 

  • Sigmund K, De Silva H, Traulsen A, Hauert C (2010) Social learning promotes institutions for governing the commons. Nature 466:861–863

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler RH, Sunstein CR (2008) Nudge—improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Traulsen A, Röhl T, Milinski M (2012) An economic experiment reveals that humans prefer pool punishment to maintain the commons. Proc R Soc Lond B Biol Sci 279(1743):3716–3721

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vesterlund L (2016) Voluntary giving in public goods: moving beyond the linear VCM. In: Kagel JH (ed) Handbook of experimental economics, vol 2. Princeton, Roth AE

    Google Scholar 

  • Voss T (2001) Game-theoretical perspectives on the emergence of social norms. In: Hechter M, Opp KD (eds) Social norms. Russel Sage Foundation, New York, pp 105–138

    Google Scholar 

  • Yamagishi T (1986) The provision of a sanctioning system as a public good. J Pers Soc Psychol 51(1):110–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang B, Li C, De Silva H, Bednarik P, Sigmund K (2014) The evolution of sanctioning institutions: an experimental approach to the social contract. Exp Econ 17(2):285–303

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Financial support by the German Federal Ministry of Education and Research (FKZ 01UN1016A) and the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft (DFG, Grant No. SFB504) for the experimental laboratory University Mannheim is gratefully acknowledged. We thank Jürgen Bracht, Josef Falkinger, and Simon Gächter for the kind provision of their experimental instructions. We are also indebted to the participants of seminars and conferences held in Bilbao, Istanbul, Kiel, Mannheim, and Oxford for helpful comments. Part of the research was conducted during a research stay at the Basque Centre for Climate Change (BC3). We thank the Institute for its hospitality. We thank Carlo Gallier for his support.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christiane Reif.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (docx 203 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Reif, C., Rübbelke, D. & Löschel, A. Improving Voluntary Public Good Provision Through a Non-governmental, Endogenous Matching Mechanism: Experimental Evidence. Environ Resource Econ 67, 559–589 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-017-0126-7

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-017-0126-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation