Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The politics of constitutional amendment in postcommunist Europe

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper analyzes the causes and consequences of constitutional amendments in Eastern Europe. Its results challenge the conventional wisdom that constitutional change is a consequence of institutions and that major changes will increase executive powers and limit rights. It finds that the political and social context rather than institutions is the main cause of amendments. These amendments moreover tend to reduce the power of executives and strengthen guarantees of human rights. The paper attributes these results to the particular circumstances of the postcommunist transition.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Lutz develops a point system for scoring difficulty. In a reanalysis of his data, Ferejohn (1997) finds that it is mainly legislative procedures rather than referenda or initiatives that affect amendment rates. See also Rasch and Congleton (2006). Sharlet (1997) has argued that difficult procedures explain Russia’s lack of amendments.

  2. Even legislative fragmentation has roots in institutional choices, particularly electoral rules.

  3. On the other hand, authoritarian rulers may simply ignore the constitution.

  4. The countries are Armenia, Bulgaria, Croatia, Czech Republic, Estonia, Georgia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Macedonia, Moldova, Poland, Romania, Russia, Slovakia, Slovenia, and Ukraine.

  5. One country, Albania, was excluded due to an inability to find data.

  6. The exception is Russia which has been rated unfree for the period 2004–2006.

  7. Lutz is not clear on his counting rule for amendments.

  8. There is some fuzziness in this measure due to different numbering systems.

  9. Precise data on the number of articles change was not available for Armenia. Blaustein and Flanz (1971-Present), however, report that “There are only a handful of provisions of the original constitution which have not been amended one way or another.” I conservatively assumed that three-quarters of articles were amended.

  10. It is even smaller, r = .02, if Macedonia is excluded.

  11. The amendment rate is the total number of amendments adopted across all countries in a given year divided by the number of countries. The figure excludes Macedonia’s anomalous experience in 2001 when it passed 15 amendments. Note also that some countries adopted a new constitution later than others and thus have not reached the final points.

  12. Countries who experienced improvements in their democracy scores were Bulgaria, Croatia, Georgia, Macedonia, Romania, Slovakia, and Ukraine.

  13. I also considered an interaction between difficulty and fragmentation; greater fragmentation might reduce amendments only when procedures are difficult. This variable was not significant in any specification.

  14. The particular institutions adopted in Eastern Europe do not explain the general low rates of amendment relative to other countries. Eastern European constitutions had very similar amendment procedures and lengths to those in other regions (Roberts 2006).

  15. For a comprehensive review of these historical arguments, see Holmes (1988).

  16. A common occurrence is presidents amending the constitution to remove term limits.

  17. More speculatively, it could be argued that flexible constitutions create both democratic accountability and a constitutional culture. In the first place, they force legislatures to make decisions. Legislative bodies cannot defer to courts or excuse non-action with reference to the restrictiveness of the constitution. This may be important for new democracies because accountability has been missing for so long. Similarly, debate over constitutional changes might introduce citizens to the substance and importance of the constitution. Neither possibility is considered here because they are difficult to measure. See Holmes and Sunstein (1995).

  18. Several amendments did not fit these categories, for example, Hungary’s amendment to change its coat of arms.

  19. Even countries that did not change the powers of presidents witnessed important debates over the nature of the presidency. Few countries seem to be satisfied with the state of presidential powers. Their concerns mirror the findings of political scientists that the strength of the presidency has a strong effect on democracy, economics, and the party system.

  20. The opposition urged a boycott of the referendum on this amendment and claimed fraud in the counting of votes. Its main criticism was that the amendment still left too much power in the hands of the president. On the other hand, the Council of Europe gave the amendment a positive evaluation (Venice Commission 2005a).

  21. An amendment passed under Mečiar actually transferred presidential power to parliament, though this was in his self-interest at the time since the president was associated with the opposition.

  22. Though in some cases they deliberately misinterpreted or ignored the constitution to serve their ends.

  23. The upper house had only a suspensory veto.

  24. A further provision stipulated that international rights treaties would trump Romanian law.

  25. These provisions replaced ones proclaiming solidarity with Macedonians living outside the country’s borders. Pressure from Greece was behind these changes.

  26. For example, several countries have a provision that gives the national bank the sole right to emit currency.

  27. Future accession to the EU was not forefront in the minds of constitution writers operating at the start of the transition because they had other more pressing concerns.

  28. An example of indirect influence is the Venice Commission which was created in 1990 by the Council of Europe as an advisory body on constitutional issues. Consisting of experts in constitutional law, the Commission provides working groups to help countries prepare constitutional changes and independently offers written opinions on amendment proposals.

  29. It is still a mystery though why Putin chose not to amend the constitution to allow himself a third consecutive term as president.

References

  • Albi, A. (2005). EU enlargement and the constitutions of central and eastern Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Armingeon, K., & Careja, R. (2004). Comparative data set for 28 post-communist countries, 1989–2004. University of Berne, Institute of Political Science.

  • Blaustein, A. P., & Flanz, G. H. (1971-Present). Constitutions of the countries of the world. Dobbs Ferry, NY: Oceana Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: Logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bunce, V., & Csanádi, M. (1993). Uncertainty in transition: Postcommunism in Hungary. East European Politics and Societies, 7, 240–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Commander, S., & Frye, T. (1999). The politics of post-communist economic reform. In Transition report. London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn, J. (1997). The politics of imperfection: The amendment of constitutions. Law and Social Inquiry, 22, 501–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fish, M. S. (2005). Democracy derailed in Russia: The failure of open politics. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freedom House. (2007). Freedom in the world 2007: The annual survey of political rights and civil liberties. New York: Freedom House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frye, T. (2002). Presidents, parliaments, and democracy: Insights from the post-communist world. In A. Reynolds (Ed.), The architecture of democracy: Constitutional design, conflict management, and democracy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney, J., & Lawson, R. with Sobel, R. S., & Leeson, P. T. (2007). Economic freedom of the world: 2007 annual report. Washington, DC: Cato Institute.

  • Hammons, C. W. (1999). Was James Madison wrong? Rethinking the American preference for short, framework-oriented constitutions. American Political Science Review, 93, 837–849.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hellman, J. S. (1997). Constitutions and economic reform in the post-communist transitions. In J. D. Sachs & K. Pistor (Eds.), The rule of law and economic reform in Russia. Boulder: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmes, S. (1997). What Russia teaches us now: How weak states threaten freedom. The American Prospect, 33, 30–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmes, S. (1988). Precommitment and the paradox of democracy. In J. Elster & R. Slagstad (Eds.), Constitutionalism and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmes, S., & Sunstein, C. (1995). The politics of constitutional revision in eastern Europe. In L. Sanford (Ed.), Responding to imperfection: The theory and practice of constitutional amendment. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2007). Governance matters VI: Governance indicators for 1996–2006. World Bank Policy Research, June.

  • King, G. (1989). Event count models in international relations: Generalizations and applications. International Studies Quarterly, 33, 123–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laakso, M., & Taagepera, R. (1979). Effective number of parties: A measure with application to West Europe. Comparative Political Studies, 23, 3–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1999). Patterns of democracy: Government forms and performance in thirty-six countries. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lutz, D. S. (1994). Toward a theory of constitutional amendment. American Political Science Review, 88, 355–375.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Metelska-Szaniawska, K. (forthcoming). Constitutions and economic reforms in transition: An empirical study. Constitutional Political Economy.

  • North, D. C., & Weingast, B. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in 17th century England. Journal of Economic History, 49, 803–832.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Offe, C. (1991). Capitalism by democratic design? Democratic theory facing the triple transition in east central Europe. Social Research, 58, 865–892.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ordeshook, P. L. (1996). Russia’s party system: Is Russian federalism viable? Post-Soviet Affairs, 12, 195–217.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2003). The economic effects of constitutions. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rasch, B. E., & Congleton, R. D. (2006). Amendment procedures and constitutional stability. In R. D. Congleton & B. Swedenborg (Eds.), Democratic constitutional design and public policy: Analysis and evidence. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. (1982). Liberalism against populism. Prospect Heights, IL: Waveland Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roberts, A. (2006). What kind of democracy is emerging in eastern Europe? Post-Soviet Affairs, 21, 37–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rohrschneider, R., & Whitefield, S. (2004). Support for foreign ownership and integration in eastern Europe: Economic interests, ideological commitment, and democratic context. Comparative Political Studies, 37, 313–339.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose, R., Mishler, W., & Haerpfer, C. (1998). Democracy and its alternatives: Understanding post-communist societies. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharlet, R. (1997). The politics of constitutional amendment in Russia. Post-Soviet Affairs, 13, 197–227.

    Google Scholar 

  • Snyder, J. L. (2000). From voting to violence: Democratization and nationalist conflict. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein, C. R. (1993). On property and constitutionalism. Cardozo Law Review, 14, 907–935.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vachudova, M. A. (2005). Europe undivided: Democracy, leverage, and integration after communism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Venice Commission. (2004). Opinion on the draft amendments to the constitution of Georgia. Opinion no. 281/2004, 29 March.

  • Venice Commission (2005a). Final opinion on constitutional reform in the Republic of Armenia. Opinion no. 313/2004, 25 October.

  • Venice Commission (2005b). Opinion on the amendments to the constitution of Ukraine adopted on 8.12.2004. Opinion no. 339/2005, 13 June.

  • Zakaria, F. (2003). The future of freedom: Illiberal democracy at home and abroad. New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andrew Roberts.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Roberts, A. The politics of constitutional amendment in postcommunist Europe. Const Polit Econ 20, 99–117 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-008-9059-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-008-9059-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation