Skip to main content
Log in

Economic upgrading in a state-coordinated, liberal market economy

  • Published:
Asia Pacific Journal of Management Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Well-established research into different models of capitalism has not been applied well to developing countries. Changing global conditions, institutional differences, and path-dependent histories have forced late developing countries to create models of their own. By and large, however, these models have been less than successful in fostering economic development through technological upgrading. A comparison of skills upgrading in several fast-growing economies in Southeast Asia suggests that perhaps there is a new “State Coordinated, Liberal Market Economy” developmental model that can successfully lead to upgrading-driven economic development. This model combines elements from the Developmental State, Coordinated Market, and Liberal Market Economy models while differing significantly from each.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Chang (2002) argues that perhaps this difficulty is overstated.

  2. Recent research suggests there are no essential institutional configurations, only institutional capacities [see Evans (2002) and Haggard (2003)].

  3. Hall and Soskice argue that this will not be possible “because their business and labor associations usually lack the encompassing character required to administer such policies well...[and] do not possess enough structural influence to sanction the government for deviations from them” (2001: 48).

  4. See Hall and Soskice (2001) for a more complete discussion of the complementarities of institutions.

  5. This is important in any case, but especially because of the inductive nature of the research. Ultimately, generalizability will only be established through additional research in other countries.

  6. On the differences between North and Southeast Asia, see Booth (1999).

  7. In fact, the term ASEAN-4 was coined as a way to distinguish the capitalist countries of Southeast Asia MINUS Singapore.

  8. A distinguished colleague of mine who has lived and worked in Singapore is fond of saying that any research on Singapore is useless since, “as we all know, Singapore is not a country.”

  9. See http://www.becker-posner-blog.com/archives/2005/04/. In a personal communication, a Singaporean government official confided that Singapore was not sufficiently large to have a gene pool that would produce enough geniuses to ensure future economic competitiveness and must therefore import needed talent.

  10. Examples include IDEMA, the hard disk drive business association in Southeast Asia, which has seen some success in coordinating the research and development as well as product manufacturing efforts of several large, multinational computer peripheral companies (Personal communication with Peter Brimble, Bangkok 2005).

  11. Certainly this may vary by the nationality of the various firms. That is, German companies doing business in Singapore probably have access to Germany’s financial system, which is a coordinated market economy (Hall & Soskice, 2001: 21–27). The point is that financial systems in Singapore are driven primarily by market forces, although even here there is some coordination among government-owned banks and government-linked corporations in what appears to be a very weak form of kiretsu management.

  12. See Birdsall, Pinckney, and Sabot (2000) for more on resource endowments and development strategy and human capital development; See Shafer (1994) for an insightful look at how industrial structure influences institutional capacity to tax.

  13. Author Interviews, Bangkok 2006.

  14. These functions used to be carried out by the Productivity and Standards Board before its responsibilities were divided between a number of ministries.

  15. Author interviews with officials from the Ministry of Manpower and Productivity and Standards Board, Singapore 1999, 2000.

  16. See the Manpower 21 plan from the Ministry of Manpower, among others.

  17. In Singapore firms contribute to an overall pot from which any firm can draw. This creates a first come first served environment. If funds are not claimed, a competitor is likely to use them. The result is a 100% usage rate among firms with more than 10 employees. In Malaysia the usage rate of funds is closer to 50%.

  18. On the power and influence of big business in Thailand see Hewison (2001).

  19. Author interviews 1999–2004.

  20. A well-known literature on the developmental state explains well these “reciprocal” relationships. See, inter alia, Johnson, (1982), Wade (1990), Woo-Cumings (1999), and Amsden (1989).

  21. Author interview with corporate officers from Seagate Corporation, Singapore, 2000.

  22. Author interview with corporate R&D manager, Seagate corporation, Singapore, 2000.

  23. Personal conversation with two CEOs, one from an American firm and one from a Japanese firm at the MDC’s Advisory Panel Meetings in Cyberjaya, 2000.

  24. Hard Disk Drive Association Conference, Bangkok, 1999.

  25. Author interview with rubber farmers in Southern Thailand, May-June 2004.

References

  • Amsden, A. 1989. Asia’s next giant: South Korea and late industrialization. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ashton, D., Green, F. J., James, D., Sung, J., et al. 1999. Education and training for development in East Asia: The political economy of skill formation in East Asian newly industrialized economies. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. 1983. Human capital. (2nd Ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press(1962 first edition).

    Google Scholar 

  • Biddle, J., & Milor, V. 2000. Malaysia: Consultative mechanisms and economic governance case study. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Birdsall, N., Pinckney, T., & Sabot, R. 2000. Natural resources, human capital, and growth. Global Policy Program Working Paper, no. 9. Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.

  • Booth, A. 1999. Initial conditions and miraculous growth: Why is South East Asia different from Taiwan and South Korea? World Development, 27(2): 301–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borrus, M. 1994. Left for dead: Asian production networks and the revival of U.S. Electronics. In E. Doherty (Ed.). Japanese Investment in Asia: International Production Strategies in a Rapidly Changing World. San Francisco: BRIE-The Asia Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chan, C. B. 2002. Heart work. Singapore: Economic Development Agency.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, H.-J. 2002. The East Asian model of economic policy. In E. Huber (Ed.). Models of Capitalism: Lessons for Latin America. University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowhey, P. F. 1993. Domestic institutions and the credibility of international commitments: Japan and the United States. International Organization, 47(2, Spring): 299–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cumings, B. 1984. The origins and development of the Northeast Asian political economy: Industrial sectors, product cycles, and political consequences. International Organization, 38(1): 1–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deyo, F. C. 1989. Beneath the miracle: labor subordination in the new Asian industrialism. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doner, R. F., & Lathamatas, A. 1994. Thailand: Economic and political gradualism. In S. Haggard & S. B. Webb (Eds.). Voting for Reform: Democracy, Political Liberalization and Economic Adjustment: 411–452. Washington, DC: Oxford University Press for the World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doner, R. F., & Ramsay, A. 2004. Growing into trouble: Institutions and politics in the Thai sugar industry. Journal of East Asian Studies, 4(1): 97–138.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doner, R. F., & Ritchie, B. K. 2003. Economic crisis and technological trajectories: Hard disk drive production in Southeast Asia. Crisis and Innovation in Asian Technology. R. S. a. W. Keller. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doner, R. F., Ritchie, B. K., & Slater, D. 2005. Systemic vulnerability and the origins of developmental states: Northeast and Southeast Asia in comparative perspective. With Richard F. Doner and Dan Slater. International Organization, 59(2): 327–361(Spring).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly, W. 2002. The elusive quest for growth: Economists’ adventures and misadventures in the tropics. Boston: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Esping-Andersen, G. 1990. The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, P. 2002. Beyond institutional monocropping: Institutions, capabilities, and deliberative development. Unpublished manuscript. Berkeley: University of California.

  • Fearon, J. D. 1994. Domestic political audiences and the escalation of international disputes. American Political Science Review, 88(3): 577–592.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finegold, D. 1991. Institutional incentives and skill creation: Preconditions for a high-skill equilibrium. In P. Ryan (Ed.). International Comparisons of Vocational Education and Training for Intermediate Skills. London: The Falmer Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haggard, S. 2003. Institutions and growth in East Asia. Unpublished manuscript. San Diego: University of California.

  • Hall, P. A., & Soskice, D. 2001. An introduction to the varieties of capitalism. In P. Hall & D. Soskice (Eds.). Varieties of Capitalism. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Henisz, W. J. 2002. Politics and international investment: Measuring risk and protecting profits. London: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hewison, K. 2001. Pathways to recovery: Bankers, business and nationalism in Thailand. Working papers Series, No. 1. City University of Hong Kong.

  • Hicken, A., & Ritchie, B. K. 2002. The origin of credibility enhancing institutions in Southeast Asia. Paper delivered at the American Political Science Annual Meeting, 2002. Boston, MA.

  • Hobday, M. 1995. Innovation in East Asia: The challenge to Japan. London: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huber, E. (Ed.). 2002. Models of capitalism: Lessons for Latin America. University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.

  • Hutchcroft, P. 1998. Booty capitalism: The politics of banking in the Philippines. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, C. 1982. MITI and the Japanese miracle: The growth of industrial policy, 1925–1975. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jomo, K. S. 1993. Introduction. Industrialising Malaysia. K. S. Jomo. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katzenstein, P. J. 1985. Small states in world markets. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keller, W., & Samuels, R. (Eds.). 2003. Crisis and innovation in Asian technology. New York: Cambridge University Press.

  • Martin, L. 2000. Democratic commitments. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McKendrick, D., Doner, R. F., et al. 2000. From Silicon Valley to Singapore: Location and competitive advantage in the hard disk drive industry. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Metcalfe, J. S. 1995. Technology systems and technology policy in an evolutionary framework. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19: 25–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mowery, D. C. 2007. University-industry resaerch collaboration and technology transfer in the United States since 1980. In S. Yusuf & K. Nabeshima (Eds.). How Universities Promote Economic Growth. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mowery, D. C., & Oxley, J. E. 1995. Inward technology transfer and competitiveness: The role of national innovation systems. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19: 67–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. 1989. Constitution and commitment: The evaluation of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History, 49: 803–832.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Odagiri, H., & Goto, A. 1993. The Japanese system of innovation: Past, present, and future. In R. R. Nelson (Ed.). National Innovation Systems: A Comparative Analysis. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pempel, T. J. 2002. Labor exclusion and privatized welfare. In E. Huber (Ed.). Models of Capitalism: Lessons for Latin America. University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, A. C. 1912. Wealth and welfare. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ritchie, B. K. 2001. Innovation systems, collective dilemmas, and the formation of technical intellectual capital in Malaysia, Singapore, and Thailand. International Journal of Business and Society, 2(2): 21–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ritchie, B. K. 2005a. Coalitional politics, economic reform, and technological upgrading in Malaysia. World Development, 33(5): 745–762.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ritchie, B. K. 2005b. Progress through setback or mired in mediocrity? Crisis and institutional change in Southeast Asia. Journal of East Asian Studies, 5(2): 273–314.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schein, E. H. 1996. Strategic pragmatism: The culture of Singapore's economic development board. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shafer, D. M. 1994. Winners and losers: How sectors shape the developmental prospects of states. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Soskice, D. 1991. The institutional infrastructure for international competitiveness: A comparative analysis of the U.K. and Germany. In A. B. Atkinson & R. Brunetta (Eds.). The Economics of the New Europe. London: McMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Soskice, D. 1999. Divergent production regimes: Coordinated and uncoordinated market economies in the 1980s and 1990s. In H. Kitschelt, et al. (Ed.). Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Streeck, W. 1989. Skills and the limits of neo-liberalism: The enterprise of the future as a place of learning. Work, Employment and Society, 3(1): 89–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thelen, K., & Kume, I. 1999. The rise of nonmarket training regimes: Germany and Japan compared. Journal of Japanese Studies, 25(1): 33–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wade, R. 1990. Governing the market: Economic theory and the role of government in East Asian industrialization. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woo, J.-E. 1991. Race to the swift: State and finance in Korean industrialization. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woo-Cumings, M. (Ed.). 1999. The developmental state. Publisher Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

  • World Bank. 1993. The East Asian miracle: Economic growth and public policy. New York: Oxford University Press.

  • World Bank. 2003. Thailand economic monitor. Bangkok: World Bank, 43.

  • World Bank. 2006. Development indicators, CD-ROM. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bryan K. Ritchie.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ritchie, B.K. Economic upgrading in a state-coordinated, liberal market economy. Asia Pac J Manag 26, 435–457 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10490-008-9089-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10490-008-9089-0

Keywords

Navigation