Skip to main content
Log in

Impacts of retailer’s risk averse behaviors on quick response fashion supply chain systems

  • S.I.: BOM in Social Networks
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Supply chain systems for fashion apparel products face a high level of risk as the market demand is very volatile and unpredictable. In order to cope with demand volatility, the quick response system which aims to shorten replenishment lead time has been well-established. With a shortened lead time, retailers can postpone the ordering decision and improve their demand forecast by gathering updated market information. However, there is a limit for quick response in which the market demand forecast is never fully accurate and uncertainty can never be fully eliminated. Thus, to keep the level of risk under control, retailers tend to possess a risk-averse behaviour in making their respective inventory decisions. In this paper, we explore the make-to-order quick response fashion supply chain with a risk averse retailer. We employ the mean-risk framework to incorporate the retailer’s risk averse behavior into the optimization model. With the focal point on uncovering the impacts brought by the retailer’s risk averse behavior to the quick response fashion supply chain system, we analytically derive important theoretical insights regarding the retailer’s optimal decisions, the implied inventory service levels, the values of quick response, and the contractual arrangements to attain Pareto improvement when the retailer is risk averse.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Please refer to a recent review by Croson et al. (2013) for more details of behavioral operations management.

  2. Under QR, with the use of market information, the retailer can update its prior demand forecast (and hence the respective demand distribution) to get the more accurate posterior demand forecast. This point is reflected by having a smaller posterior demand uncertainty \(\sigma _1 \) than the prior demand uncertainty \(\sigma _0 \).

References

  • Agrawal, V., & Seshadri, S. (2000). Risk intermediation in supply chains. IIE Transactions, 32, 819–831.

    Google Scholar 

  • Asian, S., & Nie, X. (2014). Coordination in supply chains with uncertain demand and disruption risks: existence, analysis, and insights. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics: Systems, 44(9), 1139–1154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buzacott, J., Yan, H., & Zhang, H. (2011). Risk analysis of commitment-option contracts with forecast updates. IIE Transactions, 43, 415–431.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cachon, G. (2003). Supply chain coordination with contracts. In S. Graves, T. de Kok, (Ed.), Handbooks in Operations Research and Management Science: Supply Chain Management, (pp. 229–340) North Holland.

  • Cachon, G., & Swinney, R. (2011). The value of fast fashion: Quick response, enhanced design, and strategic consumer behavior. Management Science, 57, 778–795.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chan, H. L., Choi, T. M., Hui, C. L., & Ng, S. F. (2015). Quick response healthcare apparel supply chains: value of RFID and coordination. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics—Systems, 45, 887–890.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chao, G. H., Iravani, S. M. R., & Savaskan, R. C. (2009). Quality improvement incentives and product recall cost sharing contracts. Management Science, 55(7), 1122–1138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, F., & Federgruen, A. (2000). Mean-variance analysis of basic inventory models. Working paper, Columbia University.

  • Chen, J., Zhang, H., & Sun, Y. (2012). Implementing coordination contracts in a manufacturer Stackelberg dual-channel supply chain. Omega, 40, 571–583.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, X., Sim, M., Simchi-Levi, S., & Sun, P. (2007). Risk aversion in inventory management. Operations Research, 55, 828–842.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheng, T. C. E., & Choi, T. M. (2010). Innovative quick response programs in supply chain and logistics management. Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Chiu, C. H., & Choi, T. M. (2016). Supply chain risk analysis with mean-variance models: A technical review. Annals of Operations Research, 240(2), 489–507.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, T. M. (2014). Fast Fashion Systems. London: CRC Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Choi, T. M. (2016a). Quick response in fashion supply chains with retailers having boundedly rational managers. International Transactions in Operational Research, (in press).

  • Choi, T. M. (2016b). Inventory service target in quick response fashion retail supply chains. Service Science, (in press).

  • Choi, T. M., & Chiu, C. H. (2012). Risk analysis of stochastic supply chains: A mean-risk approach. New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, T. M., & Chow, P. S. (2008). Mean-variance analysis of quick response program. International Journal of Production Economics, 114, 456–475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, T. M., Li, D., & Yan, H. (2008). Mean-variance analysis for the newsvendor problem. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics—Part A, 38, 1169–1180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chow, P. S., Choi, T. M., & Shen, B. (2014). Supply contracting with risk sensitive retailers under information asymmetry: An exploratory behavioral study. Systems Research and Behavioral Science, 31(4), 554–564.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Croson, R., Schultz, K., Siemsen, E., & Yeo, M. L. (2013). Behavioral operations: The state of the field. Journal of Operations Management, 31, 1–5.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Matta, R. E., Lowe, T. J., & Zhang, D. (2014). Consignment or wholesale: Retailer and supplier preferences and incentives for compromise. Omega, 49, 93–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Donohue, K. L. (2000). Efficient supply contract for fashion goods with forecast updating and two production modes. Management Science, 46, 1397–1411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Du, P., & Chen, Q. (2014). Skimming or penetration: optimal pricing of new fashion products in the presence of strategic consumers. Annals of Operations Research, (in press).

  • Du, S., Nie, T., Chu, C., & Yu, Y. (2014). Newsvendor model for a dyadic supply chain with Nash bargaining fairness concerns. International Journal of Production Research, 52, 5070–5085.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, M., & Raman, A. (1996). Reducing the cost of demand uncertainty through accurate response to early sales. Operations Research, 44, 87–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gan, X., Sethi, S. P., & Yan, H. (2004). Coordination of supply chains with risk-averse agents. Production and Operations Management, 13, 135–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gan, X., Sethi, S. P., & Yan, H. (2005). Channel coordination with a risk-neutral supplier and a downside-risk-averse retailer. Production and Operations Management, 14, 80–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerchak, Y., & Wang, Y. (2004). Revenue-sharing vs. wholesale-price contracts in assembly systems with random demand. Production and Operations Management, 13, 23–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iyer, A. V., & Bergen, M. E. (1997). Quick response in manufacturer–retailer channels. Management Science, 43, 559–570.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kolay, S., & Shaffer, G. (2013). Contract design with a dominant retailer and a competitive fringe. Management Science, 59(9), 2111–2116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lau, H. S. (1980). The newsboy problem under alternative optimization objectives. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 31, 525–535.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, C. H., Choi, T. M., & Cheng, T. C. E. (2015a). Selling to strategic and loss-averse consumers: Stocking, procurement, and product design policies. Naval Research Logistics, 62, 435–453.

  • Lee, C. Y., Li, X., & Yu, M. (2015b). The loss-averse newsvendor problem with supply options. Naval Research Logistics, 62(1), 46–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leider, S., & Lovejoy, W. S. (2016). Bargaining in supply chains. Management Science, (in press).

  • Leng, M., & Parlar, M. (2010). Game-theoretic analyses of decentralized assembly supply chains: Non-cooperative equilibria vs. coordination with cost-sharing contracts. European Journal of Operational Research, 204, 96–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, Z., Ryan, J. K., Shao, L., & Sun, D. (2015). Supply contract design for competing heterogeneous suppliers under asymmetric information. Production and Operations Management, 24(5), 791–807.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin, Y. T., & Parlakturk, A. (2012). Quick response under competition. Production and Operations Management, 21(3), 518–533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, Z., & Nagurney, A. (2013). Supply chain networks with global outsourcing and quick-response production under demand and cost uncertainty. Annals of Operations Research, 208(1), 251–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mukhopadhyay, S. K., Zhu, X., & Yue, X. (2008). Optimal contract design for mixed channels under information asymmetry. Production and Operations Management, 17, 641–650.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oi, W. (1971). A Disneyland dilemma: two part-tariffs for a Mickey Mouse monopoly. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 85, 77–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reimann, M. (2015). Accurate response with refurbished consumer returns. Decision Sciences, 47(1), 31–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ryan, J. K., Sun, D., & Zhao, X. (2013). Coordinating a supply chain with a manufacturer-owned online channel: a dual channel model under price competition. IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management, 60(2), 247–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shen, B., Choi, T. M., Wang, Y., & Lo, K. Y. (2013). The coordination of fashion supply chains with a risk-averse supplier under markdown money policy. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics: Systems, 43(2), 266–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shen, B., Chow, P. S., & Choi, T. M. (2014). Supply chain contracts in fashion department stores: coordination and risk analysis. Mathematical Problems in Engineering, vol. 2014, Article ID 954235, 10 pages.

  • Wang, C. X., Webster, S., & Suresh, N. C. (2009). Would a risk-averse newsvendor order less at a higher selling price? European Journal of Operational Research, 196(2), 544–553.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Webster, S., & Weng, Z. K. (2000). A risk-free perishable item returns policy. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management, 2(1), 100–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, D. Y., & Chen, K. Y. (2014). Supply chain contract design: Impact of bounded rationality and individual heterogeneity. Production and Operations Management, 23, 253–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, D., Qi, E., & Li, Y. (2015). Quick response and supply chain structure with strategic consumers. Omega, 52, 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, J., Gou, Q., Liang, L., & Huang, Z. (2013). Supply chain coordination through cooperative advertising with reference price effect. Omega, 41, 345–353.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tsan-Ming Choi.

Additional information

The author sincerely thanks the editors and two anonymous reviewers for their insightful comments which led to major improvements of this paper. This paper is partially supported by the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong under the General Research Fund (PolyU5421-12H).

Appendix: All proofs

Appendix: All proofs

Proof of Lemma 5.1

First of all, from the literature (see, e.g, Chen and Federgruen 2000; Choi et al. 2008), we know that: (i) \({ EP}_i (q)|\mu _i \) is concave, increasing in the region between 0 and \(q_{i,{ EP}^*} |\mu _i =\mu _i +\sigma _i \Phi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{r-c}{r-v}} \right) \), and its peak is attained at \(q_{i,{ EP}^*} |\mu _i\), (ii) \(\textit{VP}_i (q)|\mu _i \) is an increasing function. As a result, for Problem \((\mathrm{P}i)\), if \(R_i (q_{i,{ EP}^*} )|\mu _i \le k\Leftrightarrow k\ge (r-v)^{2}\xi \left( {\Phi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{r-c}{r-v}} \right) } \right) \) holds, the constraint \(R_i (q)|\mu _i \le k\) will become inactive. In this case, the optimal solution is \(q_{i,{ EP}^*} |\mu _i =\mu _i +\sigma _i \Phi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{r-c}{r-v}} \right) \) and the retailer is just an expected profit maximizer (i.e., risk neutral). If \(R_i (q_{i,{ EP}^*} )|\mu _i >k\Leftrightarrow k<(r-v)^{2}\xi \left( {\Phi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{r-c}{r-v}} \right) } \right) \) holds, the constraint \(R_i (q)|\mu _i \le k\) will become active and binding. In this case, the optimal solution is less than \(q_{i,{ EP}^*} |\mu _i \) and the retailer is risk averse. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 5.1

As we discussed in the proof of Lemma 5.1, since \({ EP}_i (q)|\mu _i \) is concave, increasing in the region between 0 and \(q_{i,{ EP}^*} |\mu _i =\mu _i +\sigma _i \Phi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{r-c}{r-v}} \right) \), and \(\textit{VP}_i (q)|\mu _i \) is an increasing function, when the retailer is risk averse with the level of risk tolerance of k:

(a) The optimal ordering quantity at Stage i is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} q_{i^*} |\mu _i = \mathop {\arg }\limits _q [R_i (q)|\mu _i =k] \Rightarrow \mu _i +\sigma _i \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) . \end{aligned}$$

Thus, we have: \(q_{i^*} |\mu _i =\hat{{q}}_i (k)|\mu _i \).

(b) This part is proven by observing the necessary and sufficient condition for the risk averse behavior of the retailer as shown in Lemma 5.1. \(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 5.2

(a) By definition, the inventory service level with a quantity q is given by: \(\Phi \left( {\frac{q-\mu _i }{\sigma _i }} \right) \).

(b) The inventory service level (achieved with the retailer’s optimal ordering quantity) under SR =\(\Phi \left( {\frac{q_{0^*} |\mu _0 -\mu _0 }{\sigma _0 }} \right) =\Phi \left[ {\xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) } \right] \). The inventory service level (achieved with the retailer’s optimal ordering quantity under QR) =\(\Phi \left( {\frac{q_{1^*} |\mu _1 -\mu _1 }{\sigma _1 }} \right) =\Phi \left[ {\xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) } \right] \). Since from Proposition 5.1, we have: \(q_{0^*} |\mu _0 <q_{0,{ EP}^*} |\mu _0 \) and \(q_{1^*} |\mu _1 <q_{1,{ EP}^*} |\mu _1 \), thus: \(q_{i,{ EP}^*} |\mu _i =\mu _i +\sigma _i \Phi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{r-c}{r-v}} \right) \) and \(q_{i^*} |\mu _i =\mu _i +\sigma _i \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) \) yields: \(\Phi \left[ {\xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) } \right] <\left( {\frac{r-c}{r-v}} \right) \).

(c) The inventory service level is \(\Phi \left[ {\xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) } \right] \). As \(\Phi (\cdot )\) and \(\xi ^{-1}(\cdot )\) are both increasing functions, we know \(\Phi \left[ {\xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) } \right] \) is also increasing in k. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 6.1

From (6.2), we have: \({ EVQR}^{(R)}=(\sigma _0 -\sigma _1 )\left[ (r-v)\right. \left. \Psi \left( {\xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) } \right) +(c-v)_1 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) \right] \).

As we consider the case when the inventory service level is larger than 0.5, we know that \(\Psi \left( {\xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) } \right) \) and \(\xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) \) must be positive. Thus, \({ EVQR}^{(R)}\) is positive.

Denote \(\xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) \) by \(\beta \). Taking partial derivative with respect to \(\beta \), we have:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial { EVQR}^{(R)}}{\partial \beta }= (c-v)(\sigma _0 -\sigma _1 )+(r-v)(\sigma _0 -\sigma _1 )\frac{\partial \Psi (\beta )}{\partial \beta }. \end{aligned}$$

As \(\frac{\partial \Psi (\beta )}{\partial \beta }=-(1-\Phi (\beta ))\), we can simplify \(\frac{\partial { EVQR}^{(R)}}{\partial \beta }\) to be the following:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial { EVQR}^{(R)}}{\partial \beta }= (\sigma _0 -\sigma _1 )[c-v-(r-v)+(r-v)\Phi (\beta )]. \end{aligned}$$

Since from Lemma 5.2(b), we have \(\Phi \left[ {\xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) } \right] <\left( {\frac{r-c}{r-v}} \right) \) which implies \(\beta =\xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) <\Phi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{r-c}{r-v}} \right) \). Thus, we have:

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial { EVQR}^{(R)}}{\partial \beta }<(\sigma _0 -\sigma _1 )\left[ c-v-(r-v)+(r-v)\Phi \left( {\Phi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{r-c}{r-v}} \right) } \right) \right] \\&\Rightarrow \frac{\partial { EVQR}^{(R)}}{\partial \beta }<0. \end{aligned}$$

As \(\xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) \) is increasing in k, we have: \(\frac{\partial { EVQR}^{(R)}}{\partial k}=\left( {\frac{\partial { EVQR}^{(R)}}{\partial \beta }} \right) \left( {\frac{\partial \beta }{\partial k}} \right) <0\).

Thus, \({ EVQR}^{(R)}\) is a decreasing function of k. Plus, from the analytical expression of \({ EVQR}^{(R)}\), it is crystal clear that it is an increasing function of \((\sigma _0 -\sigma _1 )\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 6.2

(a)(b) Similar to the proof of Proposition 6.1, and by direct observation.

(c) Checking the expressions of \({ EVQR}^{(R)}\) and \(\left| {{ EVQR}^{(M)}} \right| \) reveals that \({ EVQR}^{(R)}-\left| {{ EVQR}^{(M)}} \right| \) is always positive. \(\square \)

Proof of Corollary 7.1

(a) Pareto improvement for QR implementation can be attained if the retailer offers a credit transfer L as low as \(\hat{{L}}=(c-m)(\sigma _0 -\sigma _1 )\xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) \) because this value is equal to the expected loss suffered by the manufacturer after implementing QR, i.e. \(\left| {{ EVQR}^{(M)}} \right| \), and it is lower than \({ EVQR}^{(R)}\). On the other hand, in order to ensure the retailer is not worse off after adopting QR, the credit transfer is bounded above by \(\overline{L} =(\sigma _0 -\sigma _1 )J(k)\) which is equal to the \({ EVQR}^{(R)}\). Therefore, Pareto improvement for QR implementation can be attained if the retailer offers a credit transfer L which is bounded in the range of \([\hat{{L}},\;\overline{L} ]\), i.e. \(\hat{{L}}\le L\le \overline{L} \), under the two-part tariff contract to the manufacturer. (b) From \(\hat{{L}}=(c-m)(\sigma _0 -\sigma _1 )\xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) \), it is obvious that the minimum required credit transfer \(\hat{{L}}\) is an increasing function of k. \(\square \)

Proof of Corollary 7.2

(a) Under the wholesale pricing contract, Pareto improvement for QR implementation can be attained if the retailer offers a wholesale price \(\hat{{c}}\) under QR such that the manufacturer’s expected loss is fully compensated:

$$\begin{aligned}&(\hat{{c}}-m)\left( {\mu _0 +\sigma _1 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) } \right) =(c-m)\left( {\mu _0 +\sigma _0 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) } \right) \\&\quad \Leftrightarrow \hat{{c}}=m+(c-m)G(k). \end{aligned}$$

Notice that \(\hat{{c}}=m+(c-m)G(k)\) is the minimum required wholesale price to achieve Pareto improvement. On the other hand, in order to ensure the retailer does not get worse off after exercising QR, we denote the maximum extra unit wholesale price that the retailer is willing to grant to the manufacturer under QR to be \(\bar{{w}}\), and hence we have:

$$\begin{aligned}&\bar{{w}}\left( {\mu _0 +\sigma _1 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) } \right) = { EVQR}^{(R)}\\&\Leftrightarrow \bar{{w}}= \frac{(\sigma _0 -\sigma _1 )J(k)}{\mu _0 +\sigma _1 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) }. \end{aligned}$$

Thus, the maximum unit wholesale price that the retailer can grant to the manufacturer is \(\bar{{c}}=c+\bar{{w}}\) which is: \(\bar{{c}}=c+\frac{(\sigma _0 -\sigma _1 )J(k)}{\mu _0 +\sigma _1 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) }\).

(b) Checking the first order partial derivative reveals that \(\hat{{c}}\) is an increasing function of k.

\(\square \)

Proof of Corollary 7.3

(a) Under the manufacturing cost sponsorship scheme, suppose that the minimum new manufacturing cost under the sponsorship scheme (with QR) is \(\hat{{m}}\). Pareto improvement for QR implementation can be attained if the retailer offers \(\hat{{m}}\) under QR such that:

$$\begin{aligned}&(c-\hat{{m}})\left( {\mu _0 +\sigma _1 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) } \right) =(c-m)\left( {\mu _0 +\sigma _0 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) } \right) \nonumber \\&\Leftrightarrow c-\hat{{m}}=\left( {\frac{\mu _0 +\sigma _0 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) }{\mu _0 +\sigma _1 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) }} \right) (c-m). \end{aligned}$$
(8.1)

Since \(\left( {\frac{\mu _0 +\sigma _0 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) }{\mu _0 +\sigma _1 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) }} \right) >1\), we define:

$$\begin{aligned} \left( {\frac{\mu _0 +\sigma _0 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) }{\mu _0 +\sigma _1 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) }} \right) =1+\varepsilon ,\hbox { where } \varepsilon >0. \end{aligned}$$
(8.2)

Substituting (8.2) into (8.1) gives:

$$\begin{aligned}&(c-\hat{{m}})\left( {\mu _0 +\sigma _1 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) } \right) =(c-m)\left( {\mu _0 +\sigma _0 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) } \right) \\&\Leftrightarrow c-\hat{{m}}=(1+\varepsilon )(c-m)\\&\Leftrightarrow \hat{{m}}=m-\varepsilon (c-m). \end{aligned}$$

Thus, \(\hat{{m}}<m\). In addition, \(m-\hat{{m}}=\varepsilon (c-m)\), which implies that the minimum amount of needed sponsor is equal to \(\varepsilon (c-m)\), i.e. \(\hat{{\Omega }}=\frac{\hat{{L}}}{\mu _0 +\sigma _1 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) }\).

In order to ensure the retailer is not worse off after granting the manufacturing cost sponsorship, we denote the maximum manufacturing cost sponsorship as \(\bar{{\Omega }}\), and we have:

$$\begin{aligned}&\bar{{\Omega }}\left( {\mu _0 +\sigma _1 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) } \right) = { EVQR}^{(R)}\\&\Leftrightarrow \bar{{\Omega }}=\frac{(\sigma _0 -\sigma _1 )J(k)}{\mu _0 +\sigma _1 \xi ^{-1}\left( {\frac{k}{(r-v)^{2}}} \right) }. \end{aligned}$$

(b) Checking the first order partial derivative reveals that \(\hat{{\Omega }}\) is an increasing function of k.

\(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Choi, TM. Impacts of retailer’s risk averse behaviors on quick response fashion supply chain systems. Ann Oper Res 268, 239–257 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-016-2257-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-016-2257-6

Keywords

Navigation