Skip to main content
Log in

A note on the McKelvey uncovered set and Pareto optimality

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We consider the notion of Pareto optimality under the assumption that only the pairwise majority relation is known and show that the set of necessarily Pareto optimal alternatives coincides with the McKelvey uncovered set. As a consequence, the McKelvey uncovered set constitutes the coarsest Pareto optimal majoritarian social choice function. Moreover, every majority relation is induced by a preference profile in which the uncovered alternatives precisely coincide with the Pareto optimal ones. We furthermore discuss the structure of the McKelvey covering relation and the McKelvey uncovered set.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Antisymmetry is not required for any of our results to hold. In fact, Theorem 1 is even stronger when also assuming antisymmetric individual preferences (since this only increases the difficulty of constructing a suitable preference profile).

  2. Some authors call this strong Pareto optimality. In contrast, an alternative x would be weakly Pareto optimal if there is no alternative y with \(y\mathrel {P_i}x\) for all \(i\in N_{R}\). In the case of antisymmetric preferences, the two notions coincide.

  3. Consider, for instance, the simple case of \(A=\{a,b,c\}\) and \(Q=\{(a,b),(a,c)\}\), which is easily seen not to be the covering relation for any preference profile.

  4. Corollary 1 also entails an analogous weaker result for the special case of tournaments (i.e., antisymmetric majority relations \(R_\mathbf {Maj}\)), which was used as a Lemma by Brandt and Geist (2014).

  5. The whole example was obtained from and proved minimal by an automated computer search based on the method developed by Brandt et al. (2014).

  6. In fact, any tournament of size 7 can be realized by 3 agents.

  7. This even holds when individual preferences are allowed to be weak orders.

  8. The same counterexample also applies to the case of weak individual orders (i.e., without the assumption of antisymmetry of \(R_i\)). In this case there are 256 instead of 22 candidates for individual preferences relations, and additional constraints for the Pareto edges are required, which makes the resulting IP significantly larger, but still solvable within less than one second.

References

  • Bordes G (1983) On the possibility of reasonable consistent majoritarian choice: Some positive results. J Econ Theory 31(1):122–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandt F, Fischer F (2008) Computing the minimal covering set. Math Soc Sci 56(2):254–268

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandt F, Geist C (2014) Finding strategyproof social choice functions via SAT solving. In: Proceedings of the 13th international conference on autonomous agents and multi-agent systems (AAMAS), pp 1193–1200. IFAAMAS

  • Brandt F, Geist C, Seedig GH (2014) Identifying \(k\)-majority digraphs via SAT solving. In: Proceedings of the 1st AAMAS workshop on exploring beyond the worst case in computational social choice (EXPLORE)

  • Duggan J (2013) Uncovered sets. Soc Choice Welf 41(3):489–535

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dushnik B, Miller EW (1941) Partially ordered sets. Am J Math 63(3):600–610

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dutta B, Laslier J-F (1999) Comparison functions and choice correspondences. Soc Choice Welf 16(4):513–532

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaertner W (2009) A primer in social choice theory: revised edition. In: LSE perspectives in economic analysis. Oxford University Press, Oxford

  • Gebser M, Kaminski R, Kaufmann B, Ostrowski M, Schaub T, Schneider M (2011) Potassco: the Potsdam answer set solving collection. AI Commun 24(2):107–124

    Google Scholar 

  • Gebser M, Kaminski R, Kaufmann B, Schaub T (2012) Answer set solving in practice. Synth Lect Artif Intell Mach Learn 6(3):1–238

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGarvey DC (1953) A theorem on the construction of voting paradoxes. Econometrica 21(4):608–610

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey RD (1986) Covering, dominance, and institution-free properties of social choice. Am J Polit Sci 30(2):283–314

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moulin H (1986) Choosing from a tournament. Soc Choice Welf 3(4):271–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peris JE, Subiza B (1999) Condorcet choice correspondences for weak tournaments. Soc Choice Welf 16(2):217–231

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schrijver A (1986) Theory of linear and integer programming. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Felix Brandt.

Additional information

This material is based on work supported by Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft under Grants BR 2312/7-2 and BR 2312/9-1. Paul Harrenstein is supported by the ERC under Advanced Grant 291528 (“RACE”). The paper has benefitted from discussions at the 12th Meeting of the Society for Social Choice and Welfare in Boston (June 2014) as well as the Dagstuhl Seminar on Computational Social Choice (June 2015). The authors furthermore thank Jean-François Laslier and Hans Georg Seedig for helpful discussions and technical support.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Brandt, F., Geist, C. & Harrenstein, P. A note on the McKelvey uncovered set and Pareto optimality. Soc Choice Welf 46, 81–91 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-015-0904-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-015-0904-5

Keywords

Navigation