Skip to main content
Log in

Gambling for redemption and self-fulfilling debt crises

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Economic Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We develop a model for analyzing the sovereign debt crises of 2010–2013 in the Eurozone. The government sets its expenditure–debt policy optimally. The need to sell large quantities of bonds every period leaves the government vulnerable to self-fulfilling crises in which investors, anticipating a crisis, are unwilling to buy the bonds, thereby provoking the crisis. In this situation, the optimal policy of the government is to reduce its debt to a level where crises are not possible. If, however, the economy is in a recession where there is a positive probability of recovery in fiscal revenues, the government also has an incentive to smooth consumption and increase debt. Our exercise identifies conditions on fundamentals for which the incentive to smooth consumption dominates, giving rise to a situation where governments optimally “gamble for redemption,” running fiscal deficits and increasing their debt, thereby increasing their vulnerability to crises.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13
Fig. 14
Fig. 15
Fig. 16
Fig. 17

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aguiar, M., Amador, M.: Sovereign debt. In: Helpman, E., Rogoff, K., Gopinath, G. (eds.) Handbook of International Economics, vol. 4, pp. 647–687. North-Holland, Amsterdam (2014)

    Google Scholar 

  • Aguiar, M., Amador, M., Hopenhayn, H., Werning, I.: Take the short route: equilibrium default and debt maturity. Unpublished manuscript, University of Minnesota, UCLA, and MIT, Princeton (2016)

  • Aguiar, M., Gopinath, G.: Defaultable debt, interest rates, and the current account. J. Int. Econ. 69, 64–83 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aiyagari, S.R.: Uninsured idiosyncratic risk and aggregate saving. Q. J. Econ. 109, 659–684 (1994)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alonso-Ortiz, J., Colla, E., Da-Rocha, J.-M.: The productivity cost of sovereign default: evidence from the European debt crisis. Econ. Theor. (2015). doi:10.1007/s00199-015-0939-y

  • Arellano, C.: Default risk and income fluctuations in emerging economies. Am. Econ. Rev. 98, 690–712 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, C., Conesa, J.C., Kehoe, T.J.: Chronic sovereign debt crises in the Eurozone, 2010–2012. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis economic policy paper, 12-4 (2012)

  • Arellano, C., Ramanarayanan, A.: Default and the maturity structure in sovereign bonds. J. Political Econ. 120, 187–232 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bocola, L., Dovis, A.: Self-fulfilling debt crises: a quantitative analysis. NBER working paper 22694 (2016)

  • Broner, F.A., Lorenzoni, G., Schmukler, S.L.: Why do emerging economies borrow short term? J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 11, 67–100 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, G.A.: Servicing the public debt: the role of expectations. Am. Econ. Rev. 78, 647–661 (1988)

    Google Scholar 

  • Chamley, C.P., Pinto, B.: Why official bailouts tend not to work: an example motivated by Greece 2010. Econ. Voice 8, 1–5 (2011)

    Google Scholar 

  • Chatterjee, S., Corbae, D., Nakajima, M., Ríos-Rull, J.V.: A quantitative theory of unsecured consumer credit with risk of default. Econometrica 75, 1525–1589 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chatterjee, S., Eyigungor, B.: Maturity, indebtedness, and default risk. Am. Econ. Rev. 102, 2674–2699 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole, H.L., Kehoe, T.J.: A self-fulfilling model of Mexico’s 1994–1995 debt crisis. J. Int. Econ. 41, 309–330 (1996)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole, H.L., Kehoe, T.J.: Self-fulfilling debt crises. Rev. Econ. Stud. 67, 91–116 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conesa, J.C., Kehoe, T.J.: Is it too late to bail out the troubled countries in the Eurozone? Am. Econ. Rev. Pap. Proc. 104, 88–93 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conesa, J.C., Kehoe, T.J., Ruhl, K.J.: Optimal austerity. Unpublished manuscript, Stony Brook University, University of Minnesota, and Pennsylvania State University (2017)

  • Hatchondo, J.C., Martinez, L.: Long-duration bonds and sovereign defaults. J. Int. Econ. 79, 117–125 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hatchondo, J.C., Martinez, L., Sosa-Padilla, C.: Debt dilution and sovereign default risk. J. Political Econ. 124, 1383–1422 (2016)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huggett, M.: The risk-free rate in heterogeneous-agent incomplete-insurance economies. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 17, 953–969 (1993)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kehoe, T.J., Prescott, E.C.: Great depressions of the 20th century. Rev. Econ. Dyn. 5, 1–18 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Livshits, I., MacGee, J., Tertilt, M.: Consumer bankruptcy: a fresh start. Am. Econ. Rev. 97, 402–418 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lorenzoni, G., Werning, I.: Slow moving debt crises. NBER working paper 19228 (2013)

  • Mendoza, E.G., Yue, V.Z.: A general equilibrium model of sovereign default and business cycles. Q. J. Econ. 127, 889–946 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mihalache, G.: The Stock and Flow of Maturity Choice. Unpublished manuscript, Stony Brook University, Stony Brook (2017)

  • Reinhart, C.M., Rogoff, K.S.: This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton University Press, Princeton (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  • Roch, F., Uhlig, H.: the dynamics of sovereign debt crises and bailouts. IMF working paper 16/136 (2016)

  • Sanchez, J.M., Sapriza, H., Yurdagul, E.: Sovereign default and maturity choice. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis working paper 2014-031 (2014)

  • Sosa-Padilla, C.: Sovereign Defaults and Banking Crises. Unpublished manuscript, McMaster University, Hamilton (2014)

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Timothy J. Kehoe.

Additional information

We thank Tito Cordella, Isabel Correia, Patrick Kehoe, Narayana Kocherlakota, David Levine, Thomas Lubik, Fabrizio Perri, and Pedro Teles, as well as participants at numerous conferences and seminars, for helpful discussions. We also thank Jose Asturias, Wyatt Brooks, Daniela Costa, Laura Sunder-Plassmann, and Gajendran Raveendranathan for excellent research assistance. The research has been supported by the European Union’s 7th Framework Collaborative Project Integrated Macro-Financial Modelling for Robust Policy Design (MACFINROBODS), Grant 612796, and by the National Science Foundation through Grant SES-0962993. All of the data used in this paper are available at www.econ.umn.edu/~tkehoe. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis or the Federal Reserve System.

Appendices

Appendix A: Characterization of equilibria of the model without self-fulfilling crisis

Our analysis in Sect. 4 distinguishes between two cases. We consider first case 1, where the government chooses to never violate the constraint \(B\le \bar{{B}}(0)\). The optimal government policy is the solution to the dynamic programming problem:

$$\begin{aligned} V(B,a)= & {} \max u\left( (1-\theta )A^{1-a}\bar{{y}},\theta A^{1-a}\bar{{y}}+\beta B^{\prime }-B\right) +\beta EV(B^{\prime },a^{\prime })\nonumber \\&\hbox {s.t. }B\le \bar{{B}}(0). \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

We write the Bellman’s equation explicitly as

$$\begin{aligned} V(B,0)= & {} \max u\left( (1-\theta )A\bar{{y}},\theta A\bar{{y}}+\beta B^{\prime }-B\right) +\beta (1-p)V(B^{\prime },0)+\beta pV(B^{\prime },1)\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)
$$\begin{aligned} V(B,1)= & {} \max u\left( (1-\theta )\bar{{y}},\theta \bar{{y}}+\beta B^{\prime }-B\right) +\beta V(B^{\prime },1). \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)

The first-order condition is

$$\begin{aligned} \beta u_g \left( (1-\theta )A^{1-a}\bar{{y}},\theta A^{1-a}\bar{{y}}+\beta B^{\prime }-B\right) =\beta EV_B (B^{\prime },a^{\prime }), \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)

and the envelope condition is

$$\begin{aligned} V_B (B,a)=-u_g \left( (1-\theta )A^{1-a}\bar{{y}},\theta A^{1-a}\bar{{y}}+\beta B^{\prime }-B\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)

The envelope condition implies that V(Ba) is decreasing in B. A standard argument—that the operator on the space of functions defined by the Bellman’s equation maps concave value functions into concave value functions—implies that V(Ba) is concave in B.

The first-order condition (A.4) implies that the policy function for debt \(B^{\prime }(B,a)\) is increasing in B, while the policy function for government spending g(Ba) is decreasing in B. Our assumption that

$$\begin{aligned} u_g ((1-\theta )A\bar{{y}},\theta A\bar{{y}}-B)>u_g ((1-\theta )\bar{{y}},\theta \bar{{y}}-B) \end{aligned}$$
(A.6)

implies that \(B^{\prime }(0,0)>0\) and that it is impossible for \(B^{\prime }(B,0)=B\) unless the constraint \(B^{\prime }\le \bar{{B}}(0)\) binds, which implies that \(B^{\prime }(B,0)>B\).

We now consider case 2, where the government chooses to violate the constraint \(B\le \bar{{B}}(0)\) with its sale of debt in period T, defaulting in period \(T+1\) unless the private sector recovers. The optimal government policy is the solution to the finite horizon dynamic programming problem:

$$\begin{aligned} V_t (B_t )= & {} \max u\left( (1-\theta )A\bar{{y}},\theta A\bar{{y}}+\beta B_{t+1} -B_t \right) \nonumber \\&+\,\beta (1-p)V_{t+1} (B_{t+1} )+\beta p\frac{u\left( (1-\theta )\bar{{y}},\theta \bar{{y}}+(1-\beta )B_{t+1} )\right) }{1-\beta } \nonumber \\&\hbox {s.t. }B_t \le \bar{{B}}(0). \end{aligned}$$
(A.7)

We solve this problem by backward induction with the terminal value function:

$$\begin{aligned} V_T (B_T )= & {} \max u\left( (1-\theta )A\bar{{y}},\theta A\bar{{y}}+\beta pB_{T+1} -B_T \right) \nonumber \\&+\,\beta (1-p)\frac{u((1-\theta )Z\bar{{y}},\theta Z\bar{{y}}))}{1-\beta }+\beta p\frac{u((1-\theta )\bar{{y}},\theta \bar{{y}}+(1-\beta )B_{T+1} ))}{1-\beta } \nonumber \\&\hbox {s.t. }\bar{{B}}(1)\ge B_{T+1} \ge \bar{{B}}(0). \end{aligned}$$
(A.8)

We then choose the value of T for which \(V_0 (B_0 )\) is maximal. As long as the constraint \(B_{T+1} \ge \bar{{B}}(0)\) binds, we can increase the value of \(V_0 (B_0 )\) by increasing T.

The algorithm for calculating the optimal policy function is a straightforward application of backward induction. We work backward from the period in which the government borrows at price \(\beta p\) and defaults in the next period unless a recovery of the private sector occurs. Define

$$\begin{aligned} V_T (B)= & {} \max u((1-\theta )A\bar{{y}},\theta A\bar{{y}}+\beta pB^{\prime }-B) \nonumber \\&+\,\beta (1-p)\frac{u((1-\theta )Z\bar{{y}},\theta Z\bar{{y}}))}{1-\beta }+\beta p\frac{u((1-\theta )\bar{{y}},\theta \bar{{y}}+(1-\beta )B^{\prime }))}{1-\beta } \nonumber \\&\hbox {s.t. }\bar{{B}}(0)\le B^{\prime }\le \bar{{B}}(1). \end{aligned}$$
(A.9)

The steps of the algorithm are as follows:

  1. 1.

    Solve for the value function \(V_0 (B)\) and the policy function \(B_0 ^{\prime }(B)\) on a grid of bonds B on the interval \([{\underline{B}},\bar{{B}}(0)]\). We can set the lower limit \(\underline{B}\) equal to any value, including a negative value. In an application with a given initial stock of debt, we could set \(\underline{B}=B_0 \). We have already solved this problem analytically. The solution is \(B^{\prime }(B)=\min [\hat{{B}}^{\prime }(B),\bar{{B}}(1)]\) unless \(B^{\prime }(B)<\bar{{B}}(0)\), in which case \({B}_0^{'} (B)=\bar{{B}}(0)\). Consequently,

    $$\begin{aligned} B_0 ^{\prime }(B)=\max \left[ {\bar{{B}}(0),\min [\hat{{B}}^{\prime }(B),\bar{{B}}(1)]} \right] . \end{aligned}$$
    (A.10)

    The values of B for which \(B^{\prime }(B)<\bar{{B}}(0)\) are those for which it is not optimal to set \(T=0\).

  2. 2.

    Let \(t=0\), and set \(\tilde{B}_0 =\bar{{B}}(0)\).

  3. 3.

    Solve for the value function \(V_{t+1} (B,0)\) and the policy function \(B_{t+1} ^{\prime }(B)\) in the Bellman’s equation

    $$\begin{aligned} V_{t+1} (B,0)= & {} \max u((1-\theta )A\bar{{y}},\theta A\bar{{y}}+\beta B^{\prime }-B) \nonumber \\&+\,\beta (1-p)V_t (B^{\prime },0)+\beta p\frac{u((1-\theta )\bar{{y}},\theta \bar{{y}}+(1-\beta )B))}{1-\beta }.\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
    (A.11)

    Let \(\tilde{B}_t \) be the largest value of B for which \(V_{t+1} (B,0)\ge V_t (B,0)\).

  4. 4.

    Repeat step 3 until \(\tilde{B}_t =\underline{B}\).

Let T be such that \(\tilde{B}_T =\underline{B}\). We can prove that \(\underline{B}<\tilde{B}_{T-1}<\tilde{B}_{T-2}<\cdots<\tilde{B}_1 <\bar{{B}}(0)\). Our algorithm divides the interval \([\underline{B},\bar{{B}}(0)]\) into subintervals \([\underline{B},\tilde{B}_{T-1} )\), \([\tilde{B}_{T-1} ,\tilde{B}_{T-2} ),{\ldots },\,[\tilde{B}_1 ,\bar{{B}}(0;p,0)]\). If the initial capital stock \(B_0 \) is in the subinterval \([\tilde{B}_t ,\tilde{B}_{t-1} ]\), then the optimal government policy is to increase B, selling debt B, \(\bar{{B}}(0)<B\le \bar{{B}}(1)\), in period \(t-1\), and defaulting in period t unless the private sector recovers. The optimal sequence of debt is \(B_0\), \(B_{t-1} ^{\prime }(B_0 )\), \(B_{t-2} ^{\prime }(B_{t-1} ^{\prime }(B_0 )){\ldots }, B_0 (B_1 (\cdots (B_{t-1} ^{\prime }(B_0 ))))\).

Appendix B: The algorithm for computing an equilibrium in the general model

The algorithm computes the four debt thresholds, the value functions, and the policy functions.

  1. 1.

    Compute the value function \(V\left( {B,a,z_{-1} ,\zeta } \right) \) of being in the default state, where \(B=0\) and \(z_{-1} =0\). To simplify notation, we denote it \(V_d (a)\). Notice that these values are independent of the sunspot \(\zeta \), which becomes irrelevant after a default has occurred. The value function of defaulting in normal times, where \(a=1\), is

    $$\begin{aligned} V_d (1)=u(\left( {1-\theta } \right) Zy,\theta Zy)+\beta V_d (1) \end{aligned}$$
    (B.1)

    which is just a constant:

    $$\begin{aligned} V_d (1)=\frac{1}{1-\beta }u((1-\theta )Zy,\theta Zy). \end{aligned}$$
    (B.2)

    Similarly, in a recession, where \(a=0\),

    $$\begin{aligned} V_d (0)=u((1-\theta )AZy,\theta AZy)+\beta pV_d (1)+\beta (1-p)V_d (0) \end{aligned}$$
    (B.3)

    which is also a constant:

    $$\begin{aligned} V_d (0)= & {} \frac{1}{1-\beta \left( {1-p} \right) }u((1-\theta )AZy,\theta AZy) \nonumber \\&+\,\frac{\beta p}{\left( {1-\beta \left( {1-p} \right) } \right) \left( {1-\beta } \right) }u((1-\theta )Zy,\theta Zy) \end{aligned}$$
    (B.4)

    Notice that the value functions become those obtained above whenever the state of the economy determines that a self-fulfilling debt crisis happens or has happened in the past. To simplify notation, from this point on, we describe how to compute the value functions in the case of no default and drop the variable \(z_{-1} \) that determines whether a government has defaulted in the past and the sunspot \(\zeta \) as arguments of the value functions. That is, from this point on, V(Ba) is the value function if default has not happened today or anytime in the past.

  2. 2.

    Guess initial values for the thresholds \(\bar{{b}}(0)\), \(\bar{{b}}(1)\), \(\bar{{B}}(0)\), \(\bar{{B}}(1)\), where \(\bar{{b}}(0)<\bar{{b}}(1)<\bar{{B}}(0)<\bar{{B}}(1)\), and the associated prices. (We could also modify the algorithm to calculate an equilibrium in the case where \(\bar{{b}}(0)<\bar{{B}}(0)<\bar{{b}}(1)<\bar{{B}}(1)\).)

  3. 3.

    Perform value function iteration on a finite grid of values of debt to compute the value function in normal times, \(a=1\). Guess an initial value function in normal times if default has not happened in the past, \(\tilde{V}(B,1)\), and an optimal debt policy, which is needed to recursively compute the prices, \(\tilde{q}({B}^{'},1)\), defined as in equation (57), in the case with multiperiod debt. Then:

    1. 3.1.

      For values of initial debt \(B\le \bar{{B}}(1)\), the value function is

      $$\begin{aligned} V(B,1)=\max [V_1 (B,1),V_2 (B,1)], \end{aligned}$$
      (B.5)

      where \(V_1 ,V_2 \) are the value functions if next period bonds are in the regions \(B^{\prime }\le \bar{{b}}(1)\) or \(\bar{{b}}(1)<B^{\prime }\le \bar{{B}}(1)\), respectively:

      $$\begin{aligned} V_1 ({B,1})= & {} \max u((1-\theta )y,\theta y+\tilde{q}({B}^{'},1)(B^{\prime }\nonumber \\&-(1-\delta )B)-\delta B)+\beta \tilde{V}(B^{\prime },1) \nonumber \\&\hbox { s.t. }B^{\prime }\le \bar{{b}}(1) \end{aligned}$$
      (B.6)

      and

      $$\begin{aligned} V_2 \left( {B,1} \right)= & {} \max u((1-\theta )y,\theta y+\tilde{q}({B}^{'},1)(B^{\prime }-(1-\delta )B)-\delta B)\nonumber \\&\quad +\,\beta (1-\pi )\tilde{V}(B^{\prime },1)+\beta \pi V_d (1) \nonumber \\&\hbox { s.t. }\bar{{b}}(1)<B^{\prime }\le \bar{{B}}(1). \end{aligned}$$
      (B.7)
    2. 3.2.

      For high values of initial debt, \(B>\bar{{B}}(1)\), set \(V(B,1)=V_d (1)\).

    3. 3.3.

      If there is multiperiod debt, compute the pricing function, q(B, 1), recursively, as in Eq. (57), using the optimal policy function.

    4. 3.4.

      If \(\max \limits _B \left| {V(B,1)-\tilde{V}(B,1)} \right| >\varepsilon \) and \(\max \limits _B \left| {q(B,1)-\tilde{q}(B,1)} \right| >\varepsilon \), where \(\varepsilon \) is a preset convergence criterion, then \(\tilde{V}\left( {B,1} \right) =V\left( {B,1} \right) \) and \(\tilde{q}\left( {B,1} \right) =q\left( {B,1} \right) \) and go to 3.1. Else, go to 4.

  4. 4.

    Perform value function iteration on a finite grid of values of debt to compute the value function in a recession, \(a=0\). Guess an initial value function if we are in a recession and the government has not defaulted in the past: \(\tilde{V}({B,0})\), and an optimal debt policy, which is needed to recursively compute the prices, \(\tilde{q}({B}^{'},0)\), defined as in Eq. (58). Remember the value function in normal times, V(B, 1), is already known from step 3. Then:

    1. 4.1.

      For values of initial debt where \(B\le \bar{{B}}(0)\), the value function is

      $$\begin{aligned} V(B,0)=\max [V_1 (B,0),V_2 (B,0),V_3 (B,0),V_4 (B,0)], \end{aligned}$$
      (B.8)

      where \(V_1 \), \(V_2 \), \(V_3 \), \(V_4 \) are the associated value functions if next period bonds are in the regions \(B^{\prime }\le \bar{{b}}(0)\), \(\bar{{b}}(0)<B^{\prime }\le \bar{{b}}(1)\), \(\bar{{b}}(1)<B^{\prime }\le \bar{{B}}(0)\), \(\bar{{B}}(0)<B^{\prime }\le \bar{{B}}(1)\), respectively:

      $$\begin{aligned} V_1 (B,0)= & {} \max u((1-\theta )Ay,\theta Ay+\tilde{q}(B^{\prime },0)(B^{\prime }-(1-\delta )B)-\delta B) \nonumber \\&\quad +\,\beta pV(B^{\prime },1)+\beta (1-p)\tilde{V}(B^{\prime },0) \nonumber \\&\hbox { s.t. }B^{\prime }\le \bar{{b}}(0) \end{aligned}$$
      (B.9)
      $$\begin{aligned} V_2 (B,0)= & {} \max u((1-\theta )Ay,\theta Ay+\tilde{q}(B^{\prime },0)(B^{\prime }-(1-\delta )B)-\delta B) \nonumber \\&\quad +\,\beta pV(B^{\prime },1)+\beta (1-p)\pi V_d (0)+\beta (1-p)(1-\pi )\tilde{V}(B^{\prime },0) \nonumber \\&\hbox { s.t. }\bar{{b}}(0)<B^{\prime }\le \bar{{b}}(1) \end{aligned}$$
      (B.10)
      $$\begin{aligned} V_3 (B,0)= & {} \max u\left( (1-\theta )Ay,\theta Ay+\tilde{q}(B^{\prime },0)(B^{\prime }-(1-\delta )B)-\delta B\right) \nonumber \\&\quad +\,\beta p\pi V_d (1)+\beta p(1-\pi )V(B^{\prime },1) \nonumber \\&\quad +\,\beta (1-p)\pi V_d (0)+\beta (1-p)(1-\pi )\tilde{V}(B^{\prime },0) \nonumber \\&\hbox { s.t. }\bar{{b}}(1)<B^{\prime }\le \bar{{B}}(0) \end{aligned}$$
      (B.11)
      $$\begin{aligned} V_4 (B,0)= & {} \max u((1-\theta )Ay,\theta Ay+\tilde{q}(B^{\prime },0)(B^{\prime }-(1-\delta )B)-\delta B) \nonumber \\&\quad +\,\beta p\pi V_d (1)+\beta p(1-\pi )V(B^{\prime },1)+\beta (1-p)V_d (0) \nonumber \\&\hbox { s.t. }\bar{{B}}(0)<B^{\prime }\le \bar{{B}}(1). \end{aligned}$$
      (B.12)
    2. 4.2.

      For high values of initial debt, \(B>\bar{{B}}(0)\), set \(V(B,0)=V_d (0)\).

    3. 4.3.

      If there is multiperiod debt, compute the pricing function, q(B, 0), recursively, as in Eq. (58), using the optimal policy function.

    4. 4.4.

      If \(\max \limits _B \left| {V\left( {B,0} \right) -\tilde{V}\left( {B,0} \right) } \right| >\varepsilon \) and \(\mathop {\max }\limits _B \left| {q\left( {B,0} \right) -\tilde{q}\left( {B,0} \right) } \right| >\varepsilon \), then \(\tilde{V}\left( {B,0} \right) =V\left( {B,0} \right) \) and \(\tilde{q}({B,0})=q({B,0})\) and go to 4.1. Else, go to 5.

  5. 5.

    Update the threshold values:

    1. 5.1.

      Choose \(\bar{{b}}_{new} (0)\) to be the highest point in the grid for B for which

      $$\begin{aligned}&u((1-\theta )Ay,\theta Ay-\delta B)+\beta pV((1-\delta )B,1)\nonumber \\&\quad +\,\beta (1-p)V((1-\delta )B,0)\ge V_d (0). \end{aligned}$$
      (B.13)
    2. 5.2.

      Choose \(\bar{{b}}_{new} (1)\) to be the highest point in the grid for which

      $$\begin{aligned} u((1-\theta )y,\theta y-\delta B)+\beta V((1-\delta )B,1)\ge V_d (1). \end{aligned}$$
      (B.14)
    3. 5.3.

      Choose \(\bar{{B}}_{new} (0)\) to be the highest point in the grid for which

      $$\begin{aligned}&V\left( {B,0} \right) \ge u((1-\theta )ZAy,\theta ZAy+q(B^{\prime },0)(B^{\prime }(B,0)-(1-\delta )B)) \nonumber \\&\quad +\,\beta pV_d (1)+\beta (1,p)V_d (0), \end{aligned}$$
      (B.15)

      where \(q(B^{\prime },0)\) are the prices computed in step 5.

    4. 5.4.

      Choose \(\bar{{B}}_{new} (1)\) to be the highest point in the grid for which

      $$\begin{aligned}&V(B,1)\ge u((1-\theta )Zy,\theta Zy+q(B^{\prime },1)(B^{\prime }(B,1)-(1-\delta )B))\nonumber \\&\quad +\,\beta V_d (1). \end{aligned}$$
      (B.16)
    5. 5.5.

      If \(\left| {\bar{{b}}_{new} (0)-\bar{{b}}(0)} \right| >\varepsilon \) or \(\left| {\bar{{b}}_{new} (1)-\bar{{b}}(1)} \right| >\varepsilon \) or \(\left| {\bar{{B}}_{new} (0)-\bar{{B}}(0)} \right| >\varepsilon \) or \(\left| {\bar{{B}}_{new} (1)-\bar{{B}}(1)} \right| >\varepsilon \), then \(\bar{{b}}(0)=\bar{{b}}_{new} (0),\bar{{b}}(1)=\bar{{b}}_{new} (1),\bar{{B}}(0)=\bar{{B}}_{new} (0),\bar{{B}}(1)=\bar{{B}}_{new} (1)\) and go to 3. Else, exit.

      Notice that the lower threshold in normal times, \(\bar{{b}}(1)\), can be computed directly since no information about policy functions is required. Hence, the iterative procedure would not be necessary, but we choose to do it this way to be consistent with the computation of the upper thresholds and the lower threshold in recession, which do depend on the policy function and hence require an iterative procedure.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Conesa, J.C., Kehoe, T.J. Gambling for redemption and self-fulfilling debt crises. Econ Theory 64, 707–740 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-017-1085-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-017-1085-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation