Skip to main content
Log in

Incentive contracting under ambiguity aversion

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Economic Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies a principal–agent model in which the information on future firm performance is ambiguous and the agent is averse to ambiguity. We show that if firm risk is ambiguous, while stocks always induce the agent to perceive a high risk, options can induce him to perceive a low risk. As a result, options can be less costly in incentivizing the agent than stocks in the presence of ambiguity. In addition, we show that providing the agent with more incentives would induce the agent to perceive a higher risk, and there is a discontinuous jump in the compensation cost as incentives increase, which makes the principal reluctant to reset contracts frequently when underlying fundamentals change. Thus, compensation contracts exhibit an inertia property. Lastly, the model sheds some light on the use of relative performance evaluation and provides a rationale for the puzzle of pay-for-luck in the presence of ambiguity.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Although there are models that argue that ambiguity should vanish through statistical learning, Zimper and Ma (2017) analyze a model of Bayesian learning with multiple priors for which ambiguity does not vanish over time.

  2. Dittmann and Spalt (2010) justify the use of options based on loss-averse managers.

  3. Since Weinschenk (2010) only considers linear contracts, the paper shows that the ambiguity-averse agent is always induced to perceive the lowest possible mean value of the shock. If the shock has a sufficiently low possible mean value, the principal may choose not to contract on such a performance measure due to the participation constraint.

  4. Kellner and Riener (2012) provide experimental evidence for Kellner (2015).

  5. Our paper is also related to studies on principal–agent problems with uncertainty. For example, He, Li, Wei, and Yu (2014) prove a positive relation between uncertainty and incentives with ambiguity-neutral agents, which helps reconcile mixed empirical evidence on the relation between risk and incentives. Standard principal–agent models predict a negative relation between risk and incentives. But empirical evidence is mixed. While some papers find a negative relation, others document no significant or even a positive relation. For a review of the literature, see Prendergast (2002).

  6. Here we follow Feltham and Wu (2001) to use mean-variance preference for tractability. The mean-variance preference is usually a proxy for a standard expected utility (it is equivalent to the expected exponential utility when the contract is linear) and captures the key feature of a general utility function that the agent likes a high payoff, but dislikes the variance of a payoff. In Sect. 4, we provide a robustness check to show that the key mechanism for our main results still holds for a general utility function.

  7. Here we normalize the reservation utility to be 0.

  8. It can be shown that if the principal is ambiguity-averse, \(\sigma _{p}=\sigma _{2}\).

  9. In reality, firms usually use at-the-money options to compensate their managers. Then, k is roughly equal to \(E[x]=a+l\). The condition (7) is satisfied automatically.

  10. Thus, the average correlation between m and e is zero.

References

  • Ahn, D., Choi S., Gale D., Kariv, S.: Estimating ambiguity-aversion in a portfolio choice experiment. Working Paper (2009)

  • Albuquerque, A.: Do growth-option firms use less relative performance evaluation. Working Paper (2012)

  • Bertrand, M., Mullainathan, S.: Are CEOs rewarded for luck? The ones without principals are. Q. J. Econ. 116, 901–932 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bettis, J.C., Bizjak, J.M., Lemmon, M.L.: Exercise behavior, valuation, and the incentives effects of employee stock options. J. Financ. Econ. 76, 445–470 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bizjak, J.M., Lemmon, M., Naveen, L.: Does the use peer groups contribute to higher pay and less efficient compensation. J. Financ. Econ. 90, 152–168 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, P., Scheinkman, J., Xiong, W.: Executive compensation and short-termist behaviour in speculative markets. Rev. Econ. Stud. 73, 577–610 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter, J.: Does option compensation increase managerial risk appetite. J. Financ. 55, 2311–2331 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, G.: Robustness and linear contracts. Am. Econ. Rev. 105(2), 536–563 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Angelis, D., Grinstein Y.: Relative performance evaluation in CEO compensation: evidence from the 2006 disclosure rules. Working Paper (2011)

  • Dickhaut, J., Shields, T., Stecher, J.: Generating ambiguity in the laboratory. Manag. Sci. 57(4), 705–712 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dittmann, I., Maug, E.: Lower salaries and no options? on the optimal structure of executive pay. J. Financ. 62, 303–343 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dittmann, I., Maug, E., Spalt, O.: Sticks or carrots? optimal CEO compensation when managers are loss-averse. J. Financ. 65, 2015–2050 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dittmann, I., Yu, K.-C.: How important are risk-taking incentives in executive compensation?. Working Paper (2011)

  • Easley, D., O’Hara, M.: Ambiguity and nonparticipation: the role of regulation. Rev. Financ. Stud. 22, 1818–1843 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easley, D., O’Hara, M.: Liquidity and valuation in an uncertain world. J. Financ. Econ. 97, 1–11 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edmans, A., Gabaix, X.: Tractability in incentive contracting. Rev. Financ. Stud. 24, 2865–2894 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellsberg, D.: Risk, ambiguity, and the savage axioms. Q. J. Econ. 75, 643–669 (1961)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, L.G., Wang, T.: Intertemporal asset pricing under Knightian uncertainty. Econometrica 62, 283–322 (1994)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, L.G., Schneider, M.: Ambiguity, information quality, and asset pricing. J. Financ. 63, 197–228 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faulkender, M., Yang, J.: Inside the black box: the role and composition of compensation peer groups. J. Financ. Econ. 96, 257–270 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feltham, G.A., Wu, M.G.H.: Incentive efficiency of stock versus options. Rev. Acc. Stud. 6, 7–28 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaver, J.J., Gaver, K.M.: Additional evidence on the association between the investment opportunity set and corporate financing, dividend and compensation policies. J. Acc. Econ. 16, 125–160 (1993)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilboa, I., Schmeidler, D.: Maxmin expected utility with nonunique prior. J. Math. Econ. 18, 141–153 (1989)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gong, G., Li, L.Y., Shin J.Y.: Relative performance evaluation and related peer groups in executive compensation contracts. Working Paper (2010)

  • Grossman, S., Hart, O.: An analysis of the principal-agent problem. Econometrica 51, 7–45 (1983)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B.J., Murphy, K.J.: Optimal exercise prices for executive stock options. Am. Econ. Rev. Pap. Proc. 90, 209–214 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayes, R.M., Lemmon, M., Qiu, M.: Stock options and managerial incentives for risk-taking: evidence from FAS 123R. Working Paper (2010)

  • He, Z., Li, S., Wei, B., Yu, J.: Uncertainty, risk, and incentives: theory and evidence. Manag. Sci. 60, 206–226 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • He, Z., Wei B., Yu J.: Optimal long-term contracting with learning. Working Paper (2014)

  • Holmstrom, B., Milgrom, P.: Aggregation and linearity in the provision of intertemporal incentives. Econometrica 55, 303–328 (1987)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B., Tirole, J.: Market liquidity and performance monitoring. J. Polit. Econ. 101, 678–709 (1993)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Illeditsch, P.: Ambiguous information, portfolio inertia, and excess volatility. J. Financ., forthcoming (2011)

  • Jin, L.: CEO compensation, diversification, and incentives. J. Financ. Econ. 66, 29–63 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karni, E.: A reformulation of the maxmin expected utility model with application to agency theory. J. Math. Econ. 45, 97–112 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kellner, C.: Tournaments as response to ambiguity aversion in incentive contracts. J. Econ. Theory 159, 627–655 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kellner, C., Riener G.: The effect of ambiguity aversion on reward scheme choice. Working Paper (2012)

  • Mukerji, S.: Ambiguity aversion and cost-plus procurement contracts. Working Paper (2010)

  • Murphy, K.: Executive compensation. In: Ashenfelter, O., Card, D. (eds.) Handbook of Labor Economics. Elsevier/North-Holland, New York (1999)

    Google Scholar 

  • Oyer, P.: Why do firms use incentives that have no incentive effects. J. Financ. 59, 1619–1650 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prendergast, C.: The tenuous trade-off between risk and incentives. J. Polit. Econ. 110, 1071–1102 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross, S.: Incentives and the duality of risk aversion and riskiness. J. Financ. 59, 207–225 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, C., Watts, R.: The investment opportunity set and corporate financing, dividend, and compensation policies. J. Financ. Econ. 32, 263–292 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sung, J.: Linearity with project selection and controllable diffusion rate in continuous-time principal-agent problems. RAND J. Econ. 26, 720–743 (1995)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Szydlowski, M.: Ambiguity in dynamic contracts. Working Paper (2012)

  • Viero, M.-L.: Contracting in vague environments. Am. Econ. J. Microecon. 4(2), 104–130 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weinschenk, P.: Moral hazard and ambiguity, Working Paper (2010)

  • Wu Y., Yang J.: Ambiguity sharing and the lack of relative performance evaluation. Econ. Theory (2017). doi:10.1007/s00199-017-1056-x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zimper A., Ma W.: Bayesian learning with multiple priors and nonvanishing ambiguity. Econ. Theory (2016). doi:10.1007/s00199-016-1007-y

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Qi Liu.

Additional information

The views expressed herein are the authors’ and do not necessarily reflect the opinions of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Qi Liu acknowledges support by National Natural Science Foundation of China (No. 71502004).

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

For stock compensation, the agent’s utility is given by \(E[u]=\alpha _s+ \beta _{s}(a+l)-\frac{1}{2}\lambda \beta _{s}^{2}\sigma ^{2}-\frac{1}{2}a^{2}\). So to induce the effort a, we must have \(\beta _{s}=a\). For a fixed target effort a, the principal wants to minimize the cost. So \(\alpha _{s}\) must be set so that the IR constraint is binding. Thus, it is easy to derive that the cost of the contract (dropping the constant \(\frac{1}{2}a^{2}\)) is: \(C_{s}=\frac{1}{2}\lambda a^{2}\sigma ^{2}\).

We derive the agent’s utility for an option compensation as follows. \(E[u]=\alpha _{k}+\beta _{k}m_{k}-\frac{1}{2}\lambda \beta _{k}^{2}\sigma _{k}^{2}-\frac{1}{2}a^{2}.\) Taking partial derivative of \(m_{k}\) and \(\sigma _{k}^{2}\) w.r.t. a yields that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial m_{k}}{\partial a}= & {} 1-\Phi \\ \frac{\partial \sigma _{k}^{2}}{\partial a}= & {} 2\Phi m_{k} \end{aligned}$$

To induce the effort a, we must have that \(\frac{\partial E[u]}{\partial a}\ge 0\), which yields that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{(1-\Phi )-\sqrt{\Delta }}{2\lambda \Phi m_{k}}\le \beta _{k}\le \frac{(1-\Phi )+\sqrt{\Delta }}{2\lambda \Phi m_{k}}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\Delta =(1-\Phi )^{2}-4a\lambda \Phi m_{k}\). Similarly, we have the binding IR constraint. So the cost is

$$\begin{aligned} C_{k}\ge \frac{1}{2}\lambda \left( \frac{(1-\Phi )-\sqrt{\Delta }}{2\lambda \Phi m_{k}}\right) ^{2}\sigma _{k}^{2}=\frac{2\lambda a^{2}\sigma ^{2}y_{1}}{(1+\sqrt{1-4a\lambda \sigma y_{2}})^{2}}, \end{aligned}$$
(9)

where

$$\begin{aligned} y_{1}= & {} \frac{(1-\Phi -\phi ^{2})-\phi (2\Phi -1)\eta +\Phi (1-\Phi )\eta ^{2}}{(1-\Phi )^{2}},\\ y_{2}= & {} \frac{\Phi [\phi -(1-\Phi )\eta ]}{(1-\Phi )^{2}}. \end{aligned}$$

It can be shown that \(y_{1}^{\prime }(\eta )\ge 0\) and \(y_{2}^{\prime }(\eta )\ge 0\) (see Feltham and Wu 2001). Thus, \(C_k\) is increasing in k. As k goes to \(-\infty \), \(\Phi \) goes to zero. So \(\sigma ^2y_1=\frac{\sigma _k^2}{(1-\Phi )^{2}}\rightarrow \sigma ^2\), and \(\sigma y_2=\frac{\Phi m_k}{(1-\Phi )^{2}}\rightarrow 0\). Hence, the right-hand side of (9) goes to \(\frac{1}{2}\lambda a^2\sigma ^2\) when k goes to \(-\infty \). Thus, we obtain that \(C_{s}<C_{k}\).\(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 2

If the agent is granted with stocks, his utility \(E[u]=\beta _{s}(a+l)-\frac{1}{2}\lambda \beta _{s}^{2}\sigma ^{2}-\frac{1}{2}a^{2}\) is minimized at \(\sigma =\sigma _{2}\). So he will always perceive the highest risk \(\sigma _{2}\). Following the proof of Proposition 1, we can show that \(C_{s}=\frac{1}{2}\lambda a^{2}\sigma _{2}^{2}\).

If the agent is granted with options, his utility is given by

$$\begin{aligned} E[u]=\alpha _{k}+\beta _{k}(\sigma _{1})m_{k}(\sigma _{a})-\frac{1}{2}\lambda \beta _{k}(\sigma _{1})^{2}\sigma _{k}(\sigma _{a})^2-\frac{1}{2}a^{2}. \end{aligned}$$

Let

$$\begin{aligned} A_{1}=\{\hat{a}: E[u(\hat{a})| \sigma _{a}=\sigma _{1}]\le \min _{\sigma _{a}\in (\sigma _{1},\sigma _{2}]}E[u(\hat{a})]\} \end{aligned}$$

be the set of effort for which the agent’s utility is minimized at the lowest risk \(\sigma _{1}\). By condition (5), for any \(\sigma \in (\sigma _{1},\sigma _{2}]\), we have \(\lambda <\frac{2}{\beta _{k}(\sigma _{1})} \frac{m_{k}(\sigma )-m_{k}(\sigma _{1})}{\sigma _{k}^{2}(\sigma )-\sigma _{k}^{2}(\sigma _{1})}\). This implies that \(\alpha _{k}+\beta _{k}(\sigma _{1})m_{k}(\sigma _{1})-\frac{1}{2}\lambda \beta _{k}(\sigma _{1})^{2}\sigma _{k}(\sigma _{1})^2-\frac{1}{2}a^{2}<\alpha _{k}+\beta _{k}(\sigma _{1})m_{k}(\sigma )-\frac{1}{2}\lambda \beta _{k}(\sigma _{1})^{2}\sigma _{k}(\sigma )^2-\frac{1}{2}a^{2}\), i.e., \( E[u(a) | \sigma _{a}=\sigma _{1}] < E[u(a) | \sigma _{a}=\sigma ]\). So the target effort a belongs to \(A_{1}\), i.e., \(a\in A_{1}\). Note that \(\beta _{k}(\sigma _{1})\) is exactly the number of options to induce the effort a given \(\sigma _{a}=\sigma _{1}\). If the agent perceives another risk \(\sigma \ne \sigma _{1}\) and exerts an effort \(\hat{a}\), we must have

$$\begin{aligned} E[u(\hat{a}) | \sigma _{a}=\sigma ]\le E[u(\hat{a}) | \sigma _{a}=\sigma _{1}]\le E[u(a) | \sigma _{a}=\sigma _{1}], \end{aligned}$$

where \(E[u(\hat{a}) | \sigma _{a}=\sigma ]\le E[u(\hat{a}) | \sigma _{a}=\sigma _{1}]\) follows from the fact that the agent has a max-min preference, which means that under the same level of effort, his perception of risk should minimize his expected utility. Therefore at the optimum, the agent will perceive the lowest risk \(\sigma _{1}\) and exert the target effort a. The binding IR constraint yields that \(\alpha _{k}+\beta _{k}(\sigma _{1})m_{k}(\sigma _{1}) =\frac{1}{2}\lambda \beta _{k}(\sigma _{1})^{2}\sigma _{k}(\sigma _{1})^2+\frac{1}{2}a^{2}\). From the principal’s perspective, the cost (dropping the constant \(\frac{1}{2}a^{2}\)) is \(C_{k}=\alpha _{k}+\beta _{k}(\sigma _{1})m_{k}(\sigma _{p})=\frac{1}{2}\lambda \beta _{k}(\sigma _{1})^{2}\sigma _{k}(\sigma _{1})^2 +\beta _{k}(\sigma _{1})[m_{k}(\sigma _{p})-m_{k}(\sigma _{1})].\) \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 2

By Lemma 2, the right-hand side of (6) ensures that an option of exercise price k induces the agent to perceive \(\sigma _{1}\) and exert the effort a. The cost of the contract is \(C_{k}=\frac{1}{2}\lambda \beta _{k}(\sigma _{1})^{2}\sigma _{k}(\sigma _{1})^2 +\beta _{k}(\sigma _{1})[m_{k}(\sigma _{p})-m_{k}(\sigma _{1})].\) Since the cost of stock compensation is \(C_{s}=\frac{1}{2}\lambda a^{2}\sigma _{2}^{2}\), the left-hand side of (6) ensures that the option compensation is less costly.

Analysis of Condition (6)

We first solve for the right-hand side of (6) to obtain an upper bound of \(\lambda \). Let \(M=\min _{\sigma \in [\sigma _{1},\sigma _{2}]}\frac{m_{k}(\sigma )-m_{k}(\sigma _{1})}{\sigma _{k}^{2}(\sigma )-\sigma _{k}^{2}(\sigma _{1})}\), which does not depend on \(\lambda \). From the proof of Proposition 1, we know that \(\beta _{k}=\frac{(1-\Phi )-\sqrt{\Delta }}{2\lambda \Phi m_{k}}\), where \(\Delta =(1-\Phi )^{2}-4a\lambda \Phi m_{k}\). Plugging the formula of \(\beta _{k}\) into the right-hand side of (6), we can solve that the right-hand side of (6) is equivalent to \(\lambda <\frac{K(2-2\Phi (\sigma _1)-K)}{4a\Phi (\sigma _1)m_{k}(\sigma _1)}\), where \(K=4M\Phi (\sigma _1)m_{k}(\sigma _1)\).

For the left-hand side of (6), it can be simplified to \(\lambda \beta _{k}^{2}(\sigma _{1})\sigma _{k}^2(\sigma _{1})+2[m_{k}(\sigma _{p})-m_{k}(\sigma _{1})]\beta _{k}(\sigma _{1})-\lambda a^{*2}\sigma _{2}^{2}<0\). Note that \(\lambda \beta _k^2=\frac{1-\Phi }{\Phi m_k}\beta _k-\frac{a}{\Phi m_k}\), so the left-hand side of (6) is equivalent to

$$\begin{aligned} \left[ \frac{(1-\Phi (\sigma _{1}))\sigma _{k}^2(\sigma _{1})}{\Phi (\sigma _{1}) m_k(\sigma _{1})}+2[m_{k}(\sigma _{p})-m_{k}(\sigma _{1})] \right] \beta _{k}(\sigma _{1})-\frac{a\sigma _{k}^2(\sigma _{1})}{\Phi (\sigma _{1}) m_k(\sigma _{1})}-\lambda a^{2}\sigma _{2}^{2}<0. \end{aligned}$$
(10)

It is easy to check that the left-hand side of (10) is convex in \(\lambda \) and is nonnegative when \(\lambda =0\). So there could be three cases: Case 1: the left-hand side of (10) never crosses with the x-axis, which means that (10) will never be satisfied. In this case, the condition (6) cannot be satisfied. Case 2: the left-hand side of (10) crosses with the x-axis once. Let \(\lambda _1\) denote the crossed point, then the condition (6) is equivalent to \(\lambda _1<\lambda <\frac{K(2-2\Phi (\sigma _1)-K)}{4a\Phi (\sigma _1)m_{k}(\sigma _1)}\). Case 3: the left-hand side of (10) crosses with the x-axis twice. Let \(\lambda _1<\lambda _2\) denote the two crossed points, then the condition (6) is equivalent to \(\lambda _1<\lambda <\min \left( \frac{K(2-2\Phi (\sigma _1)-K)}{4a\Phi (\sigma _1)m_{k}(\sigma _1)}, \lambda _2 \right) \). \(\square \)

Proof of Lemma3

Suppose the principal uses a contract \(w=\alpha +\beta _{s}x+\beta _{k}\max (x-k,0)\) to induce the agent to perceive \(\sigma _{1}\) and exert the target effort \(a_{2}\). Then we must have that for any \(\sigma _{a}\in (\sigma _{1},\sigma _{2}]\),

$$\begin{aligned}&\alpha +\beta _{s}(a_2+l)+\beta _{k}m_{k}(\sigma _{1})-\frac{1}{2}\lambda \left[ \beta _{s}^{2}\sigma _{1}^{2}+\beta _{k}^{2}\sigma _{k}(\sigma _{1})^{2} +2\beta _{s}\beta _{k}\sigma _{0,k}(\sigma _{1})\right] \\&\quad \le \alpha +\beta _{s}(a_2+l)+\beta _{k}m_{k}(\sigma _{a})-\frac{1}{2}\lambda \left[ \beta _{s}^{2}\sigma _{a}^{2}+\beta _{k}^{2}\sigma _{k}(\sigma _{a})^{2} +2\beta _{s}\beta _{k}\sigma _{0,k}(\sigma _{a})\right] , \end{aligned}$$

where \(\sigma _{0,k}\) denotes the covariance between stocks and options. The inequality can be simplified to

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{1}{2}\lambda \left[ \frac{\beta _{s}^2}{\beta _k}(\sigma _{a}^{2}-\sigma _{1}^{2})+\beta _{k}(\sigma _{k}(\sigma _{a})^{2}-\sigma _{k}(\sigma _{1})^{2})+2\beta _{s}(\sigma _{0,k}(\sigma _{a})-\sigma _{0,k}(\sigma _{1}))\right] \\&\quad \le m_{k}(\sigma _{a})-m_{k}(\sigma _{1}). \end{aligned}$$

Note that \(\sigma _{k}(\sigma )^{2}\), \(\sigma _{0,k}(\sigma )\) and \(m_{k}(\sigma )\) are increasing in \(\sigma \). As we gradually reduce \(\beta _{s}\) and \(\beta _{k}\), the inequality above can still hold, so the agent will continue to perceive the lowest risk \(\sigma _{1}\). We keep reducing \(\beta _{s}\) and \(\beta _{k}\) until \(a_{1}\) is induced. Then we are done.\(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 4

When the effort a is induced, the agent’s utility is

$$\begin{aligned} E[u|\sigma _{a}]= & {} \alpha +\beta _{s}(a+l)+\beta _{k}m_{k}(\sigma _{a})\\&\quad -\frac{1}{2}\lambda \left[ \beta _{s}^{2}\sigma _{a}^{2}+\beta _{k}^{2}\sigma _{k}(\sigma _{a})^{2} +2\beta _{s}\beta _{k}\sigma _{0,k}(\sigma _{a})\right] -\frac{1}{2}a^2. \end{aligned}$$

We can calculate that \(\frac{\partial ^{2}m_{k}(\sigma )}{\partial \sigma ^{2}}=\frac{\phi \eta ^{2}}{\sigma }\); \(\frac{\partial ^{2}\sigma _{k}(\sigma )^{2}}{\partial \sigma ^{2}}=2(1-\Phi -\phi ^{2}+\phi \eta -\phi ^{2}\eta ^{2}+\phi \eta ^{3}-\phi \Phi \eta ^{3})\); \(\frac{\partial ^{2}\sigma _{0,k}(\sigma )}{\partial \sigma ^{2}}=2(1-\Phi )+2\phi \eta +\phi \eta ^{3}\).

Since a is induced, we must have

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{\sigma \in [\sigma _{1},\sigma _{2}]}\frac{\partial E[u|\sigma ]}{\partial a}\ge 0. \end{aligned}$$

Let \(\sigma _{0}\in \arg \max _{\sigma \in [\sigma _{1},\sigma _{2}]}\frac{\partial E[u|\sigma ]}{\partial a}\). Then, we obtain that

$$\begin{aligned} \beta _{s}+\beta _{k}(1-\Phi (\sigma _{0}))-\frac{1}{2}\lambda \left[ \beta _{k}^{2}\frac{\partial \sigma _{k}(\sigma _{0})^{2}}{\partial a}+ 2\beta _{s}\beta _{k}\frac{\partial \sigma _{0,k}(\sigma _{0})}{\partial a}\right] -a\ge 0. \end{aligned}$$

Since \(\frac{\partial \sigma _{k}(\sigma _{0})^{2}}{\partial a}>0\) and \(\frac{\partial \sigma _{0,k}(\sigma _{0})}{\partial a}>0\), \(\beta _{s}+\beta _{k}>a\).

Fig. 4
figure 4

Two functions

Taking the second-order derivative of \(E[u|\sigma _{a}]\) w.r.t. \(\sigma _{a}\) yields that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^{2}E[u]}{\partial \sigma _{a}^{2}}= & {} \beta _k\frac{\phi \eta ^2}{\sigma _a} -\frac{1}{2}\lambda \left[ 2\beta _s^2 \right. \\&+\, 2\beta _k^2(1-\Phi -\phi ^{2}+\phi \eta -\phi ^{2}\eta ^{2}+\phi \eta ^{3}-\phi \Phi \eta ^{3}) \\&\left. +\, 2\beta _s \beta _k(2(1-\Phi )+2\phi \eta +\phi \eta ^{3})\right] \\< & {} \beta _k\left[ \frac{\phi \eta ^2}{\sigma _a} -\frac{1}{2}\lambda \left[ 2\beta _k(1-\Phi -\phi ^{2}+\phi \eta -\phi ^{2}\eta ^{2}+\phi \eta ^{3}-\phi \Phi \eta ^{3}) \right. \right. \\&\left. \left. +\, 2\beta _s (2(1-\Phi )+2\phi \eta +\phi \eta ^{3})\right] \right] \end{aligned}$$

If \(|k-a-l|<\sigma _{1}\cdot \min \left( 1, \sqrt{\frac{1}{2}\lambda a\sigma _{1}}\right) \), then \(|\eta (\sigma _a)| < \min \left( 1, \sqrt{\frac{1}{2}\lambda a\sigma _{1}}\right) \). Thus, \(\frac{\phi \eta ^2}{\sigma _a}<\frac{\phi \cdot \frac{1}{2}\lambda a\sigma _1}{\sigma _1}=\frac{1}{2}\lambda a \phi \). Using MATLAB, we can draw the graph for the functions \(1-\Phi -\phi ^{2}+\phi \eta -\phi ^{2}\eta ^{2}+\phi \eta ^{3}-\phi \Phi \eta ^{3}\) and \(2(1-\Phi )+2\phi \eta +\phi \eta ^{3}\) with \(|\eta |<1\). From Fig. 4, we can see that both functions are greater than 0.5 when \(|\eta |<1\). Note that \(\phi <\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi } }\) for any \(\eta \). Thus,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^{2}E[u]}{\partial \sigma _{a}^{2}}<\frac{1}{2}\lambda \beta _k \left[ \frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi } }a -(\beta _s +\beta _k) \right] <0. \end{aligned}$$

Thus, we prove that if \(|k-a-l|<\sigma _{1}\cdot \min \left( 1, \sqrt{\frac{1}{2}\lambda a\sigma _{1}}\right) ,\) \(\frac{\partial ^{2}E[u]}{\partial \sigma _{a}^{2}}<0.\) Since \(E[u|\sigma _{a}]\) is concave in \(\sigma _{a}\), \(E[u|\sigma _{a}]\) must be minimized at \(\sigma _{a}=\sigma _{1}\) or \(\sigma _{a}=\sigma _{2}\). So the agent will perceive either the lowest risk \(\sigma _{1}\) or the highest risk \(\sigma _{2}\).\(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 4

It is straightforward from the proofs of Lemma 2 and Proposition 2.\(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 6

We can calculate that

$$\begin{aligned} E[u(\alpha _s+\beta _s x)]= & {} \int _{-\infty }^{\infty }u(\alpha _s+\beta _s (a+l+y))\frac{1}{\sigma \sqrt{2\pi }}e^{-\frac{y^2}{2\sigma ^2}}\mathrm{d}y, \text { let }z=\frac{y}{\sigma }\\= & {} \int _{-\infty }^{\infty }u(\alpha _s+\beta _s (a+l+z\sigma ))\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}e^{-\frac{z^2}{2}}\mathrm{d}z. \end{aligned}$$

Thus, taking the derivative w.r.t. \(\sigma \) yields that

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial }{\partial \sigma }E[u(\alpha _s+\beta _s x)] \\&\quad =\int _{-\infty }^{\infty }u'(\alpha _s+\beta _s (a+l+z\sigma ))\beta _s z\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}e^{-\frac{z^2}{2}}\mathrm{d}z,\\&\quad =\int _{0}^{\infty }u'(\alpha _s+\beta _s (a+l+z\sigma ))\beta _s z\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}e^{-\frac{z^2}{2}}\mathrm{d}z \\&\qquad -\int _{0}^{\infty }u'(\alpha _s+\beta _s (a+l-z\sigma ))\beta _s z\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}e^{-\frac{z^2}{2}}\mathrm{d}z. \end{aligned}$$

Since u is concave, it means that \(u'(\cdot )\) is a decreasing function. So \(\int _{0}^{\infty }u'(\alpha _s+\beta _s (a+l+z\sigma ))\beta _s z\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}e^{-\frac{z^2}{2}}\mathrm{d}z<\int _{0}^{\infty }u'(\alpha _s+\beta _s (a+l))\beta _s z\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}e^{-\frac{z^2}{2}}\mathrm{d}z\), and \(\int _{0}^{\infty }u'(\alpha _s+\beta _s (a+l-z\sigma ))\beta _s z\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}e^{-\frac{z^2}{2}}\mathrm{d}z>\int _{0}^{\infty }u'(\alpha _s+\beta _s (a+l))\beta _s z\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}e^{-\frac{z^2}{2}}\mathrm{d}z\). Thus, \(\frac{\partial }{\partial \sigma }E[u(\alpha _s+\beta _s x)]<0\). Hence, \(E[u(\alpha _s +\beta _s x)]\) is decreasing in \(\sigma \). \(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 7

Similar to the proof of Lemma 6, we can calculate that

$$\begin{aligned}&E[u(\alpha _k+\beta _k \max (x-k,0))] \\&\quad = \int _{-\infty }^{\infty }u(\alpha _k+\beta _k \max (a+l+\sigma z-k,0))\frac{1}{\sigma \sqrt{2\pi }}e^{-\frac{z^2}{2}}\mathrm{d}z, \\&\quad =u(\alpha _k)\Phi (\frac{k-a-l}{\sigma })+\int _{\frac{k-a-l}{\sigma }}^{\infty }u(\alpha _k+\beta _k (a+l+z\sigma -k))\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}e^{-\frac{z^2}{2}}\mathrm{d}z. \end{aligned}$$

Taking the derivative w.r.t. \(\sigma \) yields that

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial }{\partial \sigma }E[u(\alpha _k+\beta _k \max (x-k,0))] \\&\quad =\int _{\frac{k-a-l}{\sigma }}^{\infty }u'(\alpha _k+\beta _k (a+l+z\sigma -k))\beta _k z\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}e^{-\frac{z^2}{2}}\mathrm{d}z \end{aligned}$$

If \(k-a-l\ge 0\), then it is obvious that \(\frac{\partial }{\partial \sigma }E[u(\alpha _k+\beta _k \max (x-k,0))]>0\). If \(k-a-l<0\), then since \(\int _{\frac{k-a-l}{\sigma }}^{\infty }u'(\alpha _k+\beta _k (a+l+z\sigma -k))\beta _k z\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}e^{-\frac{z^2}{2}}\mathrm{d}z = \int _{\frac{k-a-l}{\sigma }}^{\frac{a+l-k}{\sigma }}u'(\alpha _k+\beta _k (a+l+z\sigma -k))\beta _k z\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}e^{-\frac{z^2}{2}}\mathrm{d}z + \int _{\frac{a+l-k}{\sigma }}^{\infty }u'(\alpha _k+\beta _k (a+l+z\sigma -k))\beta _k z\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}e^{-\frac{z^2}{2}}\mathrm{d}z\). The first part equals to zero when \(u''(\cdot )=0\), and the second part is always positive, so there must exist a bound B such that if \(|u''(y)|<B\) for any y, then \(\frac{\partial }{\partial \sigma }E[u(\alpha _k+\beta _k \max (x-k,0))]>0\), i.e., \(E[u(\alpha _k +\beta _k \max (x-k,0))]\) is increasing in \(\sigma \). \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Liu, Q., Lu, L. & Sun, B. Incentive contracting under ambiguity aversion. Econ Theory 66, 929–950 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-017-1073-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-017-1073-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation