Skip to main content
Log in

Extinction in common property resource models: an analytically tractable example

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Economic Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We discuss an analytically tractable discrete-time dynamic game in which a finite number of players extract a renewable resource. We characterize a symmetric Markov-perfect Nash equilibrium of this game and derive a necessary and sufficient condition under which the resource does not become extinct in equilibrium. This condition requires that the intrinsic growth rate of the resource exceeds a certain threshold value that depends on the number of players and on their time-preference rates.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Dasgupta (2005) provides a comprehensive account of the early static models which appeared in the economic literature on common property resources. His survey covers some game-theoretic ideas, but these are in static or repeated game frameworks, not in dynamic games such as the one analyzed in the present paper.

  2. The concept of asymptotic extinction has to be contrasted with extinction in finite time, which does not occur in the model under consideration.

  3. The focus of Benhabib and Rustichini (1994) is on the implications of various depreciation schemes which they incorporate using a vintage capital approach.

  4. Of course, the problem depends also on the parameters \(b,\,\eta \), and \(\rho \). For our purpose, however, it is convenient to focus on the dependence on \(a\).

  5. The relevant condition is stated in (4) in Sorger (1998), and its relation to our condition (21) from above is discussed in the middle paragraph on page 86 in Sorger (1998).

References

  • Benhabib, J., Radner, R.: The joint exploitation of a productive asset: a game-theoretic approach. Econ. Theory 2, 155–190 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib, J., Rustichini, A.: A note on a new class of solutions to dynamic programming problems arising in economic growth. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 18, 807–813 (1994)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brander, J.A., Taylor, M.S.: The simple economics of Easter Island: a Ricardo-Malthus model of renewable resource use. Am. Econ. Rev. 88, 119–138 (1998)

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, C.W.: Mathematical Bioeconomics: The Optimal Management of Renewable Resources, 2nd edn. Wiley, New York (1990)

    Google Scholar 

  • Cropper, M.L.: A note on the extinction of renewable resources. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 15, 64–70 (1988)

    Google Scholar 

  • Cropper, M.L., Lee, D.R., Pannu, S.S.: The optimal extinction of a renewable natural resource. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 6, 341–349 (1979)

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, P.: The economics of common property resources: a dynamic formulation of the fisheries problem. Indian Econ. Rev. 16, 169–197 (1981)

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, P.: Common property resources: economic analytics. Econ. Polit. Weekly 40, 1610–1622 (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Dutta, P.K., Sundaram, R.K.: The tragedy of the commons? Econ. Theory 3, 413–426 (1993)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, H.S.: The economic theory of a common property resource: the fishery. J. Polit. Econ. 62, 124–142 (1954)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hardin, G.: The tragedy of the commons. Science 162, 1243–1248 (1968)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamihigashi, T.: Almost sure convergence to zero in stochastic growth models. Econ. Theory 29, 231–237 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamihigashi, T.: Stochastic optimal growth with bounded or unbounded utility and with bounded or unbounded shocks. J. Math. Econ. 43, 477–500 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levhari, D., Mirman, L.: The great fish war: an example using a Cournot-Nash solution. Bell J. Econ. 11, 322–334 (1980)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, T.R., Schmalensee, R.: Nonconvexity and optimal exhaustion of renewable resources. Int. Econ. Rev. 18, 535–552 (1977)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matkowski, J., Nowak, A.S.: On discounted dynamic programming with unbounded returns. Econ. Theory 46, 455–474 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitra, T., Roy, S.: Optimal exploitation of renewable resources under uncertainty and the extinction of species. Econ. Theory 28, 1–23 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rincón-Zapatero, J.P., Rodriguez-Palmero, C.: Existence and uniqueness of solutions to the Bellman equation in the unbounded case. Econometrica 71, 1519–1555 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rincón-Zapatero, J.P., Rodriguez-Palmero, C.: Corrigendum to existence and uniqueness of solutions to the Bellman equation in the unbounded case. Econometrica 77, 317–318 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V.L.: Economics of production from natural resources. Am. Econ. Rev. 58, 409–431 (1968)

    Google Scholar 

  • Sorger, G.: Markov-perfect Nash equilibria in a class of resource games. Econ. Theory 11, 79–100 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stokey, N., Lucas Jr, R.: Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics. Harvard University Press, Cambridge (1989)

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The helpful comments of two anonymous referees are gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gerhard Sorger.

Appendix

Appendix

In this “Appendix,” we prove that for every \(x_0\ge 0\), the trajectory generated by (10) and the consumption stream defined by \(c_t=\lambda f(x_t)\) form an optimal solution to problem (1)–(3).

Suppose first that \(x_0=0\). Because of \(f(0)=0\), it follows that every feasible state trajectory satisfies \(x_t=0\) for all \(t\in \mathbb {N}_0\). Since this is the only feasible state trajectory, it must be an optimal one.

Now assume that \(x_0>0\) and denote by \((x_t)_{t=0}^{+\infty }\) the unique trajectory of (10) emanating from \(x_0\). Let \((\tilde{x}_t)_{t=0}^{+\infty }\) be any other feasible state trajectory with the same initial state \(\tilde{x}_0=x_0\). Finally, denote by \(c_t=\lambda f(x_t)\) and \(\tilde{c}_t=f(\tilde{x}_t)-\tilde{x}_{t+1}\) the corresponding control paths. We need to show that

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{T\rightarrow +\infty }\sum _{t=0}^T\rho ^t\left[ u(c_t)-u(\tilde{c}_t)\right] \ge 0. \end{aligned}$$
(22)

We define

$$\begin{aligned} p_t=u'(c_t) \end{aligned}$$
(23)

for all \(t\in \mathbb {N}_0\). Since \(x_t>0\) and \(u\) is strictly increasing and continuously differentiable on \((0,+\infty ),\,p_t\) is well defined for all \(t\in \mathbb {N}_0\), and it holds that \(p_t>0\). Since \(c_t\) maximizes the right-hand side of the Bellman equation given by \(u(c)+\rho W(f(x_t)-c)\) and since \(c_t\in (0,f(x_t))\), it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} p_t=u'(c_t)=\rho W'(f(x_t)-c_t)=\rho W'(x_{t+1}). \end{aligned}$$

Furthermore, from the envelope theorem applied to the optimization problem in (6), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} W'(x_t)=\rho W'(f(x_t)-c_t)f'(x_t)=\rho W'(x_{t+1})f'(x_t). \end{aligned}$$

Combining the last two equations, we get

$$\begin{aligned} p_t=\rho p_{t+1}f'(x_{t+1}) \end{aligned}$$
(24)

for all \(t\in \mathbb {N}_0\). Let us define for \((x,c)\in \mathbb {R}^2_+\) and \(t\in \mathbb {N}_0\)

$$\begin{aligned} L(x,c,t)=u(c)+p_t[f(x)-c] \end{aligned}$$

and note that \(L\) is strictly concave in \((x,c)\) for all \(t\in \mathbb {N}_0\). Furthermore, it holds that

$$\begin{aligned} L_x(x_t,c_t,t)&= p_tf'(x_t),\end{aligned}$$
(25)
$$\begin{aligned} L_c(x_t,c_t,t)&= u'(c_t)-p_t=0, \end{aligned}$$
(26)

where we have used (23). We have

$$\begin{aligned}&\sum _{t=0}^T\rho ^t\left[ u(c_t)-u(\tilde{c}_t)\right] \\&= \sum _{t=0}^T\rho ^t\left\{ L(x_t,c_t,t)-p_t[f(x_t)-c_t]-L(\tilde{x}_t,\tilde{c}_t,t)+p_t[f(\tilde{x}_t)-\tilde{c}_t]\right\} \\&\ge \sum _{t=0}^T\rho ^t\left[ L_x(x_t,c_t,t)(x_t-\tilde{x}_t)+L_c(x_t,c_t,t)(c_t-\tilde{c}_t)-p_t(x_{t+1}-\tilde{x}_{t+1})\right] \\&= \sum _{t=0}^T\rho ^t\left[ p_tf'(x_t)(x_t-\tilde{x}_t)-p_t(x_{t+1}-\tilde{x}_{t+1})\right] \\&= p_0f'(x_0)(x_0-\tilde{x}_0)+\sum _{t=0}^T\rho ^t\left[ \rho p_{t+1}f'(x_{t+1})(x_{t+1}-\tilde{x}_{t+1})-p_t(x_{t+1}-\tilde{x}_{t+1})\right] \\&-\rho ^{T+1}p_{T+1}f'(x_{T+1})(x_{T+1}-\tilde{x}_{T+1})\\&= \sum _{t=0}^T\rho ^t\left[ p_t(x_{t+1}-\tilde{x}_{t+1})-p_t(x_{t+1}-\tilde{x}_{t+1})\right] -\rho ^{T}p_{T}(x_{T+1}-\tilde{x}_{T+1})\\&\ge -\rho ^{T}p_{T}x_{T+1}. \end{aligned}$$

In the first step, we have used the definition of the function \(L\) and, in the second step, the concavity of \(L\) in \((x,c)\) and the feasibility of the two solutions. In the third step, we have made use of (25)–(26); in step four, we have rearranged the terms; in step five, we have used \(x_0=\tilde{x}_0\) and (24). The last step follows from \(\tilde{x}_{T+1}\ge 0\) and \(p_{T}\ge 0\). From the above result, it follows that (22) is implied by the transversality condition

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{T\rightarrow +\infty }\rho ^{T}p_{T}x_{T+1}=0. \end{aligned}$$
(27)

We distinguish two cases. First, if \(a\rho >1\), then we know from Lemma 2(a) that \(\lim _{T\rightarrow +\infty }x_T=x^*>0\), and therefore, \(\lim _{T\rightarrow +\infty }p_T=\lim _{T\rightarrow +\infty }u'(c_T)=\lim _{T\rightarrow +\infty }u'(\lambda f(x_T))=u'(\lambda f(x^*))\). Since both \(x_{T+1}\) and \(p_T\) have finite limits and \(\rho \in (0,1)\), it is obvious that (27) holds.

Second, let us assume that \(a\rho \le 1\) holds. We have

$$\begin{aligned} p_T=u'(c_T)=u'(\lambda f(x_T))=u'([\lambda /(1-\lambda )]x_{T+1})=\left( \frac{\lambda }{1-\lambda }\right) ^{-\eta }x_{T+1}^{-\eta } \end{aligned}$$

and it follows therefore that (27) holds if \(\lim _{T\rightarrow +\infty }\rho ^Tx_{T+1}^{1-\eta }=0\). Since this property has been proven in Lemma 2(b), we have verified the transversality condition (27) also in this case.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Mitra, T., Sorger, G. Extinction in common property resource models: an analytically tractable example. Econ Theory 57, 41–57 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-013-0799-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-013-0799-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation