Skip to main content
Log in

Proximity, network formation and inventive performance: in search of the proximity paradox

  • Special Issue Paper
  • Published:
The Annals of Regional Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Based on patent data in the field of genomics between 1990 and 2010, we investigate how social network relationships, various proximity dimensions (geographical, organizational, technological) and their interplay affect the likelihood of forming technological collaborations and their inventive performance. We show that the network and proximity characteristics of co-inventors enable them to access different sources of knowledge, in different geographical and organizational contexts, and finally affect the quality of inventive collaboration. Based on econometric estimations, our results enable to address the proximity paradox argument that proximity acts differently on the formation of collaborations and innovative performance. Our results partly support this paradox. Although all types of proximity positively impact on the formation of new collaborations, only organizational and technological proximities directly impact performance. Moreover, the optimal level of technological proximity critically varies given the organizational and social network context.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Berliant and Fujita (2012) propose a similar argument in a different theoretical framework. They argue that “[i]deas in common are important for communication, whereas ideas known exclusively by one of the partners are important for bringing originality into the potential partnership” (p. 649). The two arguments are fairly similar but with a different definition of what knowledge and learning are. In this case, knowledge is represented by an individual endowment of ideas and learning is a production of new ideas, which depends on the personal stock of each individual and their overlap.

  2. The interaction term is not equivalent to the correlation. If we consider a simple model with two variables, the interaction term captures the fact that the main effect of a variable, say \(x_{1}\), depends on the value of another variable, \(x_{2}{:}\, y = {\upbeta }_{0}+{\upbeta }_{1}x_{1}+{\upbeta }_{2}x_{2}+ {\upbeta }_{3}x_{1}x_{2}+{\upvarepsilon }\). Thus although, \(x_{1}\) has a positive impact on y, if the interaction is negative (\({\upbeta }_{3}<0\)), then the marginal impact of \(x_{1}\) is lowered when \(x_{2}\) is different from zero as the following derivative illustrates: \(\frac{\partial y}{\partial x_1 }=\beta _1 +\beta _3 x_2 \).

  3. The database was built during a recent research project carried out by ADIS-Paris Sud, LERECO-INRA and the OST—Observatoire des Sciences et des Techniques—supported by the French national research agency (ANR—Agence National pour la Recherche).

  4. The disambiguation of inventors’ homonymies has been dealt following the methodology proposed in Carayol and Cassi (2009).

  5. Social Network Analysis computation has been programmed, by the authors, themselves with SAS. The SPAM modules developed by Moody (2000) have been extremely helpful.

  6. For a different approach where affiliation data are integrated with survey data, see, for instance, Rost (2011).

  7. Even for industry–university collaborations, most of the time there is only one affiliation for a given patent; for this reason, inventors of a given patent have the same affiliation even if the applicant designated in the patent does not employ them.

  8. Dyadic data are typically not independent since residual involving the same individual are likely to be correlated, that is, Cov(\({\upvarepsilon }_{ij},{\upvarepsilon }_{ik})\ne 0\). In consequence, standard errors must correct for cross-observation in the error terms involving the same inventors. The quadratic assignment procedure enables to handle this non-independence using a permutation procedure. Given the number of possible dyads, the procedure is difficult to apply on the whole sample. As a robustness check, we have applied the Netlogit procedure of the SNA R package on the final sample. The results provided as a supplementary material lead to similar results (Supplement 1).

  9. If n is the number of active inventors, n*(n-1) is the number of potential ties between these inventors. We estimate this number to be approximately 14190 European inventors. The probability of an event to occur in the sample is approximately equal to \(2133/((14190^{*}14189)/2)\) given that the sample is composed of 2133 realized links.

  10. Rare event logit has been implemented through the ReLogit Stata routine proposed by Tomz (1999).

  11. We only observe the performance of dyads for which patents have been applied for and this induces a selection bias. A solution would be to employ a two-stage Heckman selection model, but this requires specifying independent variables that affect the probability of a dyad to patent but that do not affect the level of citations. Since we lack a theory that would suggest such variables, we are not totally confident in this two-stage procedure. However, estimates have been implemented after bootstrapping and the Mills Ratio is not significant.

  12. We adjust the latitude and longitude coordinates for the earth curvature; thus, the distance in km between two points \(A\) and \(B\) is computed as:

    $$\begin{aligned} d(A,B)&= 6371 \times \hbox {arccos}[\hbox {sin}(\hbox {latitude}(A)) \times \hbox {sin}(\hbox {latitude}(B)) + \hbox {cos}(\hbox {latitude}(A)) \times \hbox {cos}(\hbox {latitude}(B))\\&\quad \times \hbox {cos}(|\hbox {longitude}(A) - \hbox {longitude}(B) |)]. \end{aligned}$$
  13. Model 1a introduces technological proximity in a quadratic way, since it is not significant, we do not replicate this specification in the following logit models.

  14. The turning point is equal to coefficient of technological proximity/2*coefficient of technological proximity sq.

  15. The marginal effect of closure with interaction is tested with a Wald test; the null hypothesis that closure\(\,=\,\)0 & closure*technological proximity\(\,=\,\)0, is rejected with a \(p\) value of 0.0394 (\(\hbox {Chi}^{2}(2)=8.34\)).

    Fig. 4
    figure 4

    Predicted number of forward citations—closure versus non-closure

References

  • Agrawal A, Cockburn I, McHale J (2006) Gone but not forgotten: labor flows, knowledge spillovers, and enduring social capital. J Econ Geogr 6(5):571–591

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agrawal A, Kapur D, McHale J (2008) How do spatial and social proximity influence knowledge flows? Evidence from patent data. Jo Urban Econ 64(2):258–269

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Albert MB, Avery D, Narin F, McAllister P (1991) Direct validation of citation counts as indicators of industrially important patents. Res Policy 20(3):251–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch BD, Feldman PM (1996) R&D spillovers and the geography of innovation and production. Am Econ Rev 86(3):630–640

    Google Scholar 

  • Autant-Bernard C, Billand P, Frachisse D, Massard N (2007) Social distance versus spatial distance in R&D cooperation: empirical evidence from European collaboration choices in micro and nanotechnologies. Pap Reg Sci 86(3):495–519

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bathelt H, Malmberg A, Maskell P (2004) Clusters and knowledge: local buzz, global pipelines and the process of knowledge creation. Progress Human Geogr 28:31–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beaudry C, Breschi S (2003) Are firms in clusters really more innovative? Econ Innov New Technol 12:325–342

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berliant M, Fujita M (2012) Culture and diversity in knowledge creation. Reg Sci Urban Econ 42(4):648–662

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boschma RA (2005) Proximity and innovation: a critical assessment. Reg Stud 39(1):61–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boschma RA, Frenken K (2010) The spatial evolution of innovation networks. A proximity perspective. In: Boschma RA, Martin R (eds) Handbook of evolutionary economic geography, chapter 5. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

  • Boufaden N, Plunket A (2007) Proximity and innovation: do biotechnology firms located in the Paris Region benefit from localized technological externalities? Les Annales d’Economie et Statistique 87/88:197–220

    Google Scholar 

  • Breschi S, Lissoni F (2001) Knowledge spillovers and local innovation systems: a critical survey. Ind Corp Change 10:975–1005

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breschi S, Lissoni F (2009) Mobility of skilled workers and co-invention networks: an anatomy of localized knowledge flows. J Econ Geogr 9(4):439–468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broekel T, Boschma R (2012) Knowledge networks in the Dutch aviation industry—the proximity paradox. J Econ Geogr 12:409–433

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron AC, Trivedi PK (2005) Microeconometrics: methods and applications. Cambridge University Press, NY

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Carayol N, Cassi L (2009) Who’s who in patents. A Bayesian approach, Université paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne, hal-00631750, HAL

  • Cassi L, Plunket A (2014) Research collaboration in co-inventor networks: combining closure, bridging and proximities, regional studies (forthcoming)

  • Cohen WM, Levinthal DA (1990) Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation. Adm Sci Q 35:128–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fafchamps M, Goyal S, van der Leij MJ (2010) Matching and network effects. J Eur Econ Assoc 8(1):203–231

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fornahl D, Broekel T, Boschma R (2011) What drives patent performance of German biotech firms? The impact of R&D subsidies, knowledge networks and their location. Pap Reg Sci 90(2):395–418

  • Frenken K, Ponds R, Van Oort FG (2010) The citation impact of research collaboration in science-based industries: a spatial-institutional analysis. Pap Reg Sci 89(2):351–371

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gambardella A, Harhoff D, Verspagen B (2008) The value of European patents. Eur Manag Rev 5(2):69–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilsing V, Nooteboom B, Vanhaverbeke W, Duysters G, van den Oord A (2008) Network embeddedness and the exploration of novel technologies: technological distance, betweenness centrality and density. Res Policy 37(10):1717–1731

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harhoff D, Scherer FM, Vopel K (2003) Citations, family size, opposition and the value of patent rights—evidence from Germany. Res Policy 32:1343–1363

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman J, Hall B, Griliches Z (1984) Economic models for count data with an application to patents and R&D relationship. Econometrica 52:909–938

  • Huber F (2011) On the role and interrelationship of spatial, social and cognitive proximity: personal knowledge relationships of R&D workers in the Cambridge Information Technology. Cluster 46(9):1169–1182

  • Jaffe AB (1989) Real effects of academic research. Am Econ Rev 79(5):957–970

    Google Scholar 

  • King G, Zeng L (2001) Logistic regression in rare events data. Political Anal 9:137–163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laurens P, Zitt M, Bassecoulard E (2010) Delineation of the genomics field by hybrid citation-lexical methods: interaction with experts and validation process. Scientometrics 82(3):647–662

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martinez C (2010) Insight into different types of patent families. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers, 2010/02, OECD Publishing

  • Moody J (2000) SPAN: SAS programs for analyzing networks. University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill

  • Mowery DC, Oxley JE, Silverman BS (1998) Technological overlap and interfirm cooperation: implications for the resource-based view of the firm. Res Policy 27(5):507–523

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newman MEJ, Park J (2003) Why social networks are different from other types of networks. Phys Rev E 68(3)

  • Nooteboom B, Van Haverbeke W, Duysters G, Gilsing V, van den Oord A (2007) Optimal cognitive distance and absorptive capacity. Res Policy 36(7):1016–1034

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2009) OECD patent statistics manual. http://www.oecdbookshop.org/oecd/display.asp?sf1=identifiers&st1=9789264056442

  • Ponds R, Van Oort F, Frenken K (2007) The geographical and institutional proximity of research collaboration. Pap Reg Sci 86(3):423–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rost K (2011) The strength of strong ties in the creation of innovation. Res Policy 40(4):588–604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh J (2005) Collaborative networks as determinants of knowledge diffusion patterns. Manag Sci 51(5):756–770

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sorenson O, Rivkin JW, Fleming L (2006) Complexity, networks and knowledge flows. Res Policy 35:994–1017

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ter Wal ALJ (2014) The dynamics of the inventor network in German biotechnology: geographic proximity versus triadic closure. J Econ Geogr 14(3):589–620

  • Tomz M (1999) Relogit (Stata ado file). http://www.stanford.edu/~tomz/software/software.shtml

  • Trajtenberg M (1990) A penny for your quotes: patent citations and the value of innovations. RAND J Econ 21(1):172–187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trajtenberg M, Henderson R, Jaffe A (1997) University versus corporate patents: a window on the basicness of invention. Econ Innov New Technol 5(1):19–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wittington KB, Owen-Smith J, Powell WW (2009) Networks, propinquity, and innovation in knowledge-intensive industries. Adm Sci Q 54:90–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wuyts SHK, Colombo M, Dutta S, Nooteboom B (2005) Empirical tests of optimal cognitive distance. J Econ Behav Organ 58(2):277–302

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Anne Plunket.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (doc 44 KB)

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 3 and 4.

Table 3 Descriptive statistics
Table 4 Correlations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cassi, L., Plunket, A. Proximity, network formation and inventive performance: in search of the proximity paradox. Ann Reg Sci 53, 395–422 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-014-0612-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-014-0612-6

JEL Classification

Navigation