Skip to main content

On the Choice of Organizational Form: Theory and Evidence from the Insurance Industry

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Handbook of Insurance

Abstract

Organizational forms within the insurance industry include stock companies, mutuals, reciprocals, and Lloyds. We focus on the association between the choice of organizational form and the firm’s contracting costs, arguing that different organizational forms reduce contracting costs in specific dimensions. This suggests that differing costs of controlling particular incentive conflicts among the parties of the insurance firm lead to the efficiency of alternative organizational forms across lines of insurance. We analyze the incentives of individuals performing the three major functions within the insurance firm—the manager function, the owner function, and the customer function. We review evidence from the insurance industry that directly examines this product-specialization hypothesis. We then examine evidence on corporate policy choices by the alternative organizational forms: executive compensation policy, board composition, distribution system choice, reinsurance purchases, and the use of participating policies. Finally, we review evidence of the relative efficiency of the alternative organizational forms.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 469.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 599.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 599.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See Mayers et al. (1997).

  2. 2.

    See Mayers and Smith (2005).

  3. 3.

    See Brickley et al. (1988, 1994).

  4. 4.

    See Smith and Watts (1982, 1992) and Gaver and Gaver (1993).

  5. 5.

    See Manne (1965), Jensen and Ruback (1983), and Jarrell et al. (1988).

  6. 6.

    See Smith and Warner (1979).

  7. 7.

    See Lee et al. (1997) and Downs and Sommer (1999).

  8. 8.

    See Mayers and Smith (2005).

  9. 9.

    Participating policies in insurance markets act somewhat like convertible bonds in credit markets. See Smith and Warner (1979), Mayers and Smith (1981), Garven and Pottier (1995), and Sect. 24.5, herein.

  10. 10.

    Hetherington (1969), Anderson (1973), and Kreider (1972) debate over the implications of these restrictions for policyholder control of mutuals.

  11. 11.

    Reinmuth (1967, p. 32) states, “Those reciprocals operating on a separate account basis usually provide in the subscriber’s agreement for the accumulation of a ‘contingency surplus’ by withholding a stated percentage of each subscriber’s deposit premium or ‘savings’ which will not be available on withdrawal.”

  12. 12.

    This is really an oversimplification. The management of a reciprocal is appointed by each policyholder through the subscriber’s agreement or power of attorney. Thus, whether a subscriber has voting rights depends on the terms of the subscriber’s agreement. The job of management can in fact be proprietary. If it is, the subscriber usually has the right to vote for an advisory committee, which may or may not have the right to replace the manager. For further discussion, see Reinmuth (p. 15–16).

  13. 13.

    As reported by Reinmuth, (p. 36): “It would appear that the subscribers of a reciprocal have the power to request a court of equity to dissolve the exchange. In McAlexander v. Waldscriber it was held that a court of equity, at the suit of a subscriber, had the power to appoint a receiver for a reciprocal insurance ‘fund,’ upon allegations that the fund was being mismanaged and dissipated by the attorney-in-fact. The receiver was directed to manage, disburse and liquidate the ‘fund’ so as to do justice to all parties in interest under their contract. In Irwin v. Missouri Valley Bridge and Iron company, a case involving a similar set of facts, the court reached a similar conclusion.”

  14. 14.

    A good example of a case where risks were changing frequently and managerial discretion was important is marine insurance in the early nineteenth century. Wright and Fayle (1928) report the adjustment of rates by an underwriter at Lloyd’s of London. “Take, for example, the year of Trafalgar, and the routes specially affected by movements of hostile fleets. For homeward voyages from the West Indies, the average rate on 76 risk accepted by Mr. Janson during the first quarter of the year was 81∕2 per cent. The arrival of Villeneuve’s fleet in the West Indies, sent it up to 131∕2 per cent, and thence to 15 per cent and over. It touched 16 per cent when he was making for the Channel, but fell to 11 per cent after his indecisive actions with Calder and his return to Cadiz.”

  15. 15.

    See Alchian (1950) and Stigler (1957). Fama and Jensen (1983) suggest this survivorship principle: that “the form of organization that survives in an activity is the one that delivers the product demanded by customers at the lowest price while covering costs.”

  16. 16.

    Adams (1995) analysis also suffers from this potential problem. Using canonical correlation methods, his examination of 33 New Zealand life insurance companies employing data from a single year finds little support for the managerial discretion hypothesis.

  17. 17.

    Kleffner and Doherty (1996) suggest that ownership structure is important because of stock companies’ more ready access to capital.

  18. 18.

    See also McNamara and Rhee (1992), Carson et al. (1998), and Jeng et al. (2007) who examine life insurer demutualizations, and Lai et al. (2008) and Viswanathan and Cummins (2003) who examine both life and property–liability insurer conversions.

  19. 19.

    Further evidence on managerial entrenchment among mutual executives is provided by Bohn (1995). He examines CEO turnover for a sample of 93 stock and 168 mutual insurance firms from 1984 to 1992. Inconsistent with the hypothesis that mutual managers are entrenched, he finds that the unconditional probability of CEO turnover is higher in mutuals than stocks (8.3 % per annum compared to 6 %). In addition, he reports that the probability of CEO turnover is related to firm’s performance in both stocks and mutuals.

  20. 20.

    Cole and McCullough (2006) examine overall demand for reinsurance by US insurers as well as the utilization of foreign reinsurance. Their analysis supports the prior findings. Their results suggest that the decision to utilize foreign reinsurance is driven primarily by the characteristics of the ceding company.

  21. 21.

    Shiu’s results are limited by data problems. First, he only has indicator variables [0,1] for the use of derivatives. Second, to the extent that any of the insurers employed hybrid debt or preferred stock to hedge exposures, his data misses those instruments. Third, disclosure has varied over time; some firms report derivatives’ use only if it is material. Finally, even with more detail about the firm’s hedging activities, judging the extent of a hedge is challenging. For example, assume that company A has $10 million (notional principal) of 3-year interest rate swaps; company B has $20 million of 3-year swaps. Company A clearly hedges less than either B or C, but company B with C is more difficult. For the next 3 years, B hedges more than C, but for the succeeding 4 years, C hedges more. If we turn to options, the problems become dramatically more difficult—attempting to compare firms with contracts of different size and different exercise prices is quite difficult. In principle, one could estimate the contracts’ deltas, but deltas depend on the prices at which they are evaluated. Such problems limit the power of all empirical work in this area.

  22. 22.

    In 1836, the Girard Life Insurance Annuity and Trust Co. Issued the first participating policy in the United States. A circular issued that year says, “The income of the company will be apportioned between the stockholders and the assured for life, an advantage given in America by this company alone.” (Stalson, 1942, p. 94).

References

  • Alchian AA (1950) Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. J Polit Econ 58:211–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson BM (1973) Policyholder control of a mutual life insurance company. Clevel State Law Rev 22:439–449

    Google Scholar 

  • Baranoff E, Sager T (2003) The relations among organizational and distribution forms and capital and asset risk structures in the life insurance industry. J Risk Insur 70(3):375–400

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bohn JG (1995) Management turnover and succession in the insurance industry. Working Paper, Harvard University

    Google Scholar 

  • Brickley JA, Lease RC, Smith CW (1988) Ownership structure and voting on antitakeover amendments. J Financial Econ 20(1/2):267–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brickley JA, Lease RC, Smith CW (1994) Corporate voting: evidence from charter amendment proposals. J Corp Financ 1(1):5–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browne MJ, Ma Y-L, Wang P (2009) Stock-based executive compensation and reserve errors in the property and casualty insurance industry. J Insur Regul 27:35–54

    Google Scholar 

  • Carson JM, Foster MD, McNamara MJ (1998) Changes in ownership structure: theory and evidence from life insurer demutualizations. J Insur Issues 21:1–22

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase R (1960) The problem of social cost. J Law Econ 3:1–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole CR, McCullough KA (2006) A reexamination of the corporate demand for reinsurance. J Risk Insur 73(1):169–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cummins DJ, Weiss MA, Zi H (1999) Organizational form and efficiency: the coexistence of stock and mutual property-liability insurers. Manag Sci 45(9):1254–1269

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Darwin C (1859) On the origin of species by means of natural selection. John Murray, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Doherty NA, Dionne G (1993) Insurance with undiversifiable risk: contract structure and organizational form of insurance firms. J Risk Uncertain 6:187–203

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs DH, Sommer DW (1999) Monitoring, ownership, and risk-taking: the impact of guaranty funds. J Risk Insur 66(3):477–497

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckles DL, Halek M (2010) Insurer reserve error and executive compensation. J Risk Insur 77:329–346

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, Jensen MC (1983) Agency problems and residual claims. J Law Econ 26:327–349

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frech HE III (1980) Health insurance: private, mutuals or government economics of nonproprietary organizations, Research in law and economics, Suppl 1. JAI Press, Greenwich, CT, pp 61–73

    Google Scholar 

  • Garven JR, Pottier SW (1995) Incentive contracting and the role of participation rights in stock insurers. J Risk Insur 62:253–270

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaver JJ, Gaver KM (1993) Additional evidence on the association between the investment opportunity set and corporate finance, dividend and compensation policies. J Account Econ 16:125–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green RC (1984) Investments incentives, debt, and warrants. J Financial Econ 13:115–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansmann H (1985) The organization of insurance companies: mutual versus stock. J Law Econ Organ 1: 125–154

    Google Scholar 

  • Hetherington JAC (1969) Fact v. fiction: who owns mutual insurance companies? Wis Law Rev 4:1068–1103

    Google Scholar 

  • Jarrell G, Brickley J, Netter J (1988) The market for corporate control: the empirical evidence since. J Econ Perspect 2:49–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jeng V, Lai GC, McNamara MJ (2007) Efficiency and demutualization: evidence from the U.S. life insurance industry in the 1980s and 1990s. J Risk Insur 74:683–711

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen M (1986) Agency cost of free cash flow, corporate finance and takeovers. Am Econ Rev 76:323–339

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen M, Ruback R (1983) The market for corporate control: the scientific evidence. J Financial Econ 11: 5–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim WJ, Mayers D, Smith CW (1996) On the choice of insurance distribution systems. J Risk Insur 63: 207–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleffner AE, Doherty NA (1996) Costly risk and the supply of catastrophic insurance. J Risk Insur 63: 657–671

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kreider GP (1972) Who owns the mutuals? Proposals for reform of membership rights in mutual insurance and banking companies. Cincinnati Law Rev 41:275–311

    Google Scholar 

  • Lai GC, McNamara MJ, Tong U (2008) The wealth effect of demutualization: evidence from the U.S. property-liability and life insurance industries. J Risk Insur 75:125–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lamm-Tennant J, Starks LT (1993) Stock versus mutual ownership structures: the risk implications. J Bus 66:29–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee SJ, Mayers D, Smith CW Jr (1997) Guaranty finds and risk-taking behavior: evidence for the insurance industry. J Financial Econ 44(1):3–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manne HG (1965) Mergers and the market for corporate control. J Polit Econ 73:110–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marx LM, Mayers D, Smith CW (2001) Insurer ownership structure and executive compensation as complements. J Risk Insur 68(3):449–464

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayers D, Smith CW (1981) Contractual provisions, organizational structure, and conflict control in insurance markets. J Bus 54:407–434

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayers D, Smith CW (1982) On the corporate demand for insurance with D. Mayers. J Bus 55(2):281–296

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayers D, Smith CW (1986) Ownership structure and control: the mutualization of stock life insurance companies. J Financial Econ 16:73–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayers D, Smith CW (1987) Corporate insurance and the underinvestment problem. J Risk Insur 54(1):45–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayers D, Smith CW (1988) Ownership structure across lines of property casualty insurance. J Law Econ 31:351–378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayers D, Smith CW (1990) On the corporate demand for insurance: evidence from the reinsurance market. J Bus 63:19–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayers D, Smith CW (1992) Executive compensation in the life insurance industry. J Bus 65:51–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayers D, Smith CW (1994) Managerial discretion, regulation, and stock insurer ownership structure. J Risk Insur 61:638–655

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayers D, Smith CW (2002) Ownership structure and control: property-casualty insurer conversion to stock charter. J Financial Serv Res 21(1/2):117–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayers D, Smith CW (2004) Incentives for managing accounting information: property-liability insurer stock-charter conversions. J Risk Insur 71:213–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayers D, Smith CW (2005) Agency problems and the corporate charter. J Law Econ Organ 21:417–440

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayers D, Smith CW (2010) Compensation and board structure: evidence from the insurance industry. J Risk Insur 77(2):297–327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayers D, Shivdasani A, Smith CW (1997) Board composition in the life insurance industry. J Bus 70:33–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McNamara MJ, Rhee SG (1992) Ownership structure and performance: the demutualization of life insurers. J Risk Insur 59:221–238

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton RC (1977) An analytic derivation of the cost of deposit insurance and loan guarantees: an application of modern option pricing theory. J Bank Financ 1: 3–11

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mikkelson WH (1981) Convertible calls and security returns. J Financial Econ 9:237–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom P, Roberts J (1995) Complementarities and fit strategy, structure, and organizational change in manufacturing. J Account Econ 19:179–208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myers SC (1977) Determinants of corporate borrowing. J Financial Econ 5:147–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norgaard RL (1964) What is a reciprocal? J Risk Insur 31:51–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pottier SW, Sommer DW (1997) Agency theory and life insurer ownership structure. J Risk Insur 64(3):529–543

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Regan L, Tzeng LY (1999) Organizational form in the property-liability insurance industry. J Risk Insur 66(2):253–273

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinmuth DF (1967) The regulation of reciprocal insurance exchanges. Richard D. Irwin, Homewood, IL

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwert GW (1981) Using financial data to measure effects of regulation. J Law Econ 24:121–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shiu Y-M (2007) An empirical investigation on derivatives usage: evidence from the United Kingdom general insurance industry. Appl Econ Lett 14:353–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith BD, Stutzer MJ (1990) Adverse selection, aggregate uncertainty, and the role for mutual insurance contracts. J Bus 63:493–510

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith CW Jr, Warner JB (1979) On financial contracting: an analysis of bond covenants. J Financial Econ 7:117–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith CW Jr, Watts R (1982) Incentive and tax effects of executive compensation plans. Aust J Manag 7:139–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith CW Jr, Watts R (1992) The investment opportunity set and corporate financing dividend and compensation policies. J Financial Econ 32:263–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spiller R (1972) Ownership and performance: stock and mutual life insurance companies. J Risk Insur 34: 17–25

    Google Scholar 

  • Stalson JO (1942) Marketing life insurance: its history in America. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler GJ (1957) The organization of industry. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL

    Google Scholar 

  • Viswanathan KS, Cummins JD (2003) Ownership structure changes in the insurance industry: an analysis of demutualization. J Risk Insur 70:401–437

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wells BP, Cox L, Gaver KM (1995) Free cash flow in the life insurance industry. J Risk Insur 62: 50–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wells BP, Epermanis K, Cox LA, McShane M (2009) Risky asset substitution in the insurance industry: an historical example. J Insur Regul 67–90

    Google Scholar 

  • Wright C, Fayle DE (1928) A history of Lloyd’s. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Zanjani G (2007) Regulation, capital, and the evolution of organizational form in U.S. life insurance. Am Econ Rev 97:973–983

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Clifford W. Smith .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer Science + Business media, New York

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Mayers, D., Smith, C.W. (2013). On the Choice of Organizational Form: Theory and Evidence from the Insurance Industry. In: Dionne, G. (eds) Handbook of Insurance. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-0155-1_24

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics