Skip to main content
Log in

Mis-judging merit: the effects of adjudication errors in contests

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Experimental Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Within contests, adjudication errors imply at the same time the exclusion of a meritorious candidate and the inclusion of a non-meritorious one. We study theoretically how adjudication errors affect bids in all-pay auctions, by disentangling the respective effects of exclusion and inclusion errors, and showing how they interact with the framing of incentives (prize or penalty) under different assumptions on preferences. We test our theoretical predictions with an experiment where we manipulate the presence of exclusion errors, inclusion errors, and the framing of incentives. The experimental evidence indicates that errors of either exclusion or inclusion significantly decrease bids in all-pay auctions relative to a setting without errors, interacting negatively, with no significant difference in the size of their effects. Bid levels are significantly higher in a penalty framing relative to a prize framing, both in the absence of errors and in the presence of adjudication errors.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In fact, as argued by Jia et al., (2013), the randomness described by Lazear and Rosen (1981) can be seen as a stochastic foundation for Tullock contest functions, under specific assumptions on the distribution of the noise term (see also Jia 2008).

  2. We can alternatively assume that contest committees are heterogeneous in their commitment to properly judge candidates, and that contest participants are aware of this: while most committees work hard and do not make errors, few shirk and, in order to avoid an adjudication error, select one of two extreme strategies—reward all contestants or none—depending on which outcome is admitted by the contest terms.

  3. Examples of penalties in the workplace are demotion, wage cut, dismissal or unpaid leave of absence.

  4. For a theoretical analysis of optimal prize structures in contests with loss-averse bidders in the absence of adjudication errors see, for example, Mermer (2016).

  5. The assumption that \(p<\frac{1}{2}\) is without loss of generality and guarantees that, in every error setting and for every such p, there exists a unique equilibrium in mixed strategies.

  6. As we assume that bids are drawn from a distribution, we denote the generic bid in treatment T with boldface letter (\(\varvec{b}^T\)) to indicate that it is a random variable, and we use normal letters to denote its possible realizations.

  7. The random merit extension is contained in Appendix B of Baye et al. (2005). From their model we can easily obtain our adjudication error scenario by assuming that their parameter \(\pi\) that indicates the probability of the exogenous shock is equal to \(1-2p\), and that the litigation environment can be described as an all-pay auction where each party pays its litigation cost (i.e., \(\beta =\alpha =1\) in their model).

  8. It is immediate to verify that \(b=\pi\) solves Eq. :1 with \(F^{N}(\pi)=1\).

  9. Notice that for the equilibrium distribution functions in the scenarios with errors we cannot determine the upper bound of their supports. Yet, an inequality relation that holds for all positive bids between any two distribution functions implies a clear ranking of their upper bounds, and allows us to establish a first-order stochastic dominance relation between the two distributions (see for example proof of Proposition 1 in Online Appendix A).

  10. This can be verified by comparing the denominators of the two distribution functions (see Eqs. 2 and 3). The winning utility under exclusion error falls, relative to no error, by the quantity \(p[u(w+\pi -b)+u(w-b)]\) due to the possibility of not obtaining the prize. The losing utility under inclusion error rises by the same quantity, due to the possibility of being awarded the prize.

  11. Notice that receiving the reward in the penalty scheme (i.e., not receiving the penalty) determines the payoff \(w'\), which is equal by construction to the payoff from receiving the reward in the prize scheme (\(w+\pi\)); not receiving the reward in the penalty scheme (i.e., receiving the penalty) determines the payoff \(w'-\pi\), which is equal to the payoff from not receiving the reward in the prize scheme (w).

  12. To see this, it is enough to multiply by \((1-p)\) both the numerator and the denominator of the expression of \(G^N(b)\) and observe that the denominator coincides with that of \(G^I(b)\) while the numerator is smaller.

  13. Under exclusion error, the winning utility is reduced by the quantity \(p[u(\pi -b)+\lambda u(b)]\), as the higher bidder may obtain a loss instead of a sure gain. Under inclusion error, the losing utility increases by the quantity \(p[u(\pi -b)+\lambda u(b)]\), as the lower bidder may obtain a gain instead of a sure loss.

  14. Notice that whether the bid opportunity cost is larger in the exclusion than in the inclusion error depends on whether it holds that \(\lambda u(b) \geqslant u(\pi )-u(\pi -b)\).

  15. Notice that, for non-linear PT preferences, \(L^{N}\) may differ from \(F^N\), the equilibrium distribution function of bids in a prize scheme with EUT bidders obtained from Eq. 1.

  16. Notice that for a linear u(x), instead, the two equilibrium distributions coincide and thus exclusion and inclusion errors are predicted to have the same effects on equilibrium bids.

  17. Notice that this result does not hold for bidders who are risk loving in the gain domain, as for such bidders \(u(b)< u(\pi +b)-u(b)\), and thus the bid opportunity cost is larger under exclusion error.

  18. The occurrence of an error is determined by two coin tosses. Subjects are informed about the realization of the coin tosses after their bidding decision.

  19. Notice that in order to predict and interpret subjects’ behavior in the experiment, we adopt the population interpretation for mixed strategies and do not assume that each subject actually randomizes. In fact, we do not provide subjects with any randomization device that they could use to pick a bid in the support. Thus, individual i’s bid in the support [0, 1000] has to be interpreted as part of a continuous mixed strategy played by the sub-population from which i is drawn.

  20. Payment of a single randomly selected period was chosen in order to avoid wealth and portfolio effects (see Charness et al., 2016; Azrieli et al., 2018).

  21. The task in Dave et al. (2010) measures risk aversion on the basis of a lottery choice within a menu of six lotteries. The risk-aversion indicator takes values from 1 to 6 depending on the choice made in the risk task. The task in Gächter et al. (2022) measures loss aversion on the basis of the gain-loss ratio in risky choices involving mixed gain-loss prospects. The loss-aversion indicator takes values from 1 to 7 depending on the lottery switching point, with higher values corresponding to rejecting lotteries with smaller losses (subjects who made inconsistent choices were excluded). Further details on the tasks and the distributions of risk and loss indicators in our experiment are reported in Online Appendix B.

  22. Notice that we use the indicator of risk aversion as a proxy for decreasing marginal utility in gains of loss-averse bidders, which is appropriate under the assumption that the payoff obtained in the experiment is not taken as a reference point for the lottery choice task.

  23. As in Dave et al. (2010), we classify as risk neutral subjects with a risk-aversion indicator equal to 2. The results in Table 9 are robust to the inclusion of subjects with an indicator equal to 3, which is below the median.

  24. The existence of a cap on bids is one of the arguments provided by Potters et al. (1998) to explain why they do not find strong evidence of overbidding in an all-pay auction setting that shares some key features with ours: number of bidders, matching protocol, and large number of rounds. In every round, subjects receive an endowment that is slightly above the prize value, and this cap may exert a stronger pressure on average bids with respect to Gneezy and Smorodinsky (2006), making Potters et al. (1998) results more similar to ours.

  25. In contrast, in a different context Levitt et al. (2016) find that the framing of educational incentives as gains or losses does not significantly affect effort. Another notable exception is the study of De Quidt et al. (2017).

References

  • Amegashie, J. A. (2006). A contest success function with a tractable noise parameter. Public Choice, 126(135), 135–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armantier, O., & Boly, A. (2015). Framing of incentives and effort provision. International Economic Review, 56(3), 917–938.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azrieli, Y., Chambers, C., & Healy, P. J. (2018). Incentives in experiments: A theoretical analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 126(4), 1472–1503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balart, P., Chowdhury, S. M., & Troumpounis, O. (2017). Linking individual and collective contests through noise level and sharing rules. Economics Letters, 155, 126–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baye, M. R., Kovenock, D., & de Vries, C. G. (1996). The all-pay auction with complete information. Economic Theory, 8(2), 291–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baye, M. R., Kovenock, D., & de Vries, C. G. (2005). Comparative analysis of litigation aystems: an auction-theoretic approach. The Economic Journal, 115(505), 583–601.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brooks, R. R. W., Stremitzer, A., & Tontrup, S. (2012). Framing contracts: Why loss framing increases effort. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 168(1), 62–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brooks, P., & Zank, H. (2005). Loss averse behavior. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 31(3), 301–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cason, T. N., Masters, W. A., & Sheremeta, R. M. (2020). Winner-take-all and proportional-prize contests: Theory and experimental results. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 175, 314–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charness, G., Gneezy, U., & Halladay, B. (2016). Experimental methods: Pay one or pay all. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 131(A), 141–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chowdhury, S. M., Jeon, J. Y., & Ramalingam, A. (2017). Property rights and loss aversion in contests. Economic Inquiry, 56(3), 1492–1511.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corazzini, L., Faravelli, M., & Stanca, L. (2010). A prize to give for: An experiment on public good funding mechanisms. The Economic Journal, 120, 944–967.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corchón, L. C. (2007). The theory of contests: A survey. Review of Economic Design, 11(2), 69–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corchón, L. C., & Serena, M. (2018). Contest theory. In L. C. Corchón & M. A. Marini (Eds.), Handbook of Game Theory and Industrial Organization (pp. 125–146). Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dave, C., Eckel, C. C., Johnson, A. A., & Rojas, C. (2010). Eliciting risk preferences: When is simple better? Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 41(3), 219–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, D., & Reilly, R. J. (1998). Do too many cooks always spoil the stew? An experimental analysis of rent-seeking and the role of a strategic buyer. Public Choice, 35, 89–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Quidt, J., Fallucchi, F., Köllec, F., Nosenzo, D., & Quercia, S. (2017). Bonus versus penalty: How robust are the effects of contract framing? Journal of the Economic Science Association, 3, 174–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delfgaauw, J., Dur, R., Non, A., & Verbeke, W. (2015). The effects of prize spread and noise in elimination tournaments: A natural field experiment. Journal of Labour Economics, 33(3), 521–569.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dickinson, D. L. (2001). The carrot vs the stick in work team motivation. Journal of Experimental economics, 4(1), 107–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drugov, M., & Ryvkin, D. (2020). How noise affects effort in tournaments. Journal of Economic Theory, 188(2), 105065.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ernst, C., & Thöni, C. (2013). Bimodal bidding in experimental all-pay auctions. Games, 4(4), 608–623.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckel, C., & Grossman, P. (2002). Sex Differences and statistical stereotyping in attitudes toward financial risk. Evolution and Human behavior, 23(4), 281–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckel, C., & Grossman, P. (2008). Forecasting risk attitudes: An experimental study using actual and forecast gamble choices. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 68, 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckel, C., & Grossman, P. (2008). Men, women and risk aversion: Experimental evidence. Handbook of Experimental Economics Results, 1(113), 1061–1073.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faravelli, M., & Stanca, L. (2012). Single versus multiple prize contests to finance public goods: Theory and experimental evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 81, 677–688.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fryer, R. G., Levitt, S. D., List, J., & Sadoff, S. (2012). Enhancing the efficacy of teacher incentives through loss aversion: A field experiment. NBER Working, 252, 18237.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gächter, S., Johnson, E. J., & Herrmann, A. (2021). Individual-level loss aversion in riskless and risky choices. Theory and Decision, 92, 599–624.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gächter, S., Orzen, S., Renner, E., & Starmer, C. (2009). Are experimental economists prone to framing effects? A natural field experiment. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 70(3), 443–446.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gneezy, U., & Smorodinsky, R. (2006). All-pay auctions: An experimental study. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 61, 255–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greiner, B. (2004). The online recruitment system ORSEE 2.0: A guide for the organization of experiments in economics. Working Paper Series in Economics 10, University of Cologne.

  • Hammond, K. R. (1996). Human Judgment and Social Policy. Irreducible Uncertainty Inevitable Error Unavoidable Injustice Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, G. W., Lau, M. I., & Rutström, E. E. (2007). Estimating risk attitudes in denmark: A field experiment. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 109(2), 341–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A., & Riley, J. G. (1989). Politically contestable rents and transfers. Economics and Politics, 1, 17–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. The American Economic Review, 92(5), 1644–1655.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong, F., Hossain, T., & List, J. A. (2015). Framing manipulations in contests: A natural field experiment. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 128, 372–382.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hossain, T., & List, J. A. (2012). The behavioralists visits the factory: Increasing productivity using simple framing manipulations. Management Science, 58(12), 2151–2167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Imas, A., Sadoff, A., & Samek, A. (2017). Do people anticipate loss aversion? Management Science, 63(5), 1271–1284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jia, H. (2008). A stochastic derivation of the ratio form of contest success functions. Public Choice, 135(3), 125–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jia, H., Skaperdas, S., & Vaidya, S. (2013). Contest functions: Theoretical foundations and issues in estimation. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 31(3), 211–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplow, L., & Shavell, S. (1994). Accuracy in the determination of liability. Journal of Law and Economics, 37, 1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klose, B., & Kovenock, D. (2015). The all-pay Auction with complete information and identity-dependent externalities. Economic Theory, 59(1), 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konrad, K. (2009). Strategy and Dynamics in Contests. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lazear, E. P., & Rosen, S. (1981). Rank and order tournament: An optimal labor contract. Journal of Political Economy, 89(5), 841–864.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, S. D., List, J. A., Neckermann, S., & Sadoff, S. (2016). The behavioralist goes to school: Leveraging behavioral economics to improve educational performance. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 8(4), 183–219.

    Google Scholar 

  • List, J. A., Van Soest, D., Stoop, J., & Zhou, H. (2020). On the role of group size in tournaments: Theory and evidence from lab and field experiments. Management Science, 66(10), 4359–4377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lugovskyy, V., Puzzello, D., & Tucker, S. (2010). An experimental investigation of overdissipation in the all-pay auction. European Economic Review, 54(8), 974–997.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mermer, A. G. (2016). Over-workers and drop-outs in competitions: Contests with expectations-based loss-averse agents. Mimeo.

  • Millner, E. L., & Pratt, M. D. (1989). An experimental investigation of efficient rent-seeking. Public Choice, 62(2), 139–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ong, D., & Chen, Z. (2012). Tiger women: An all-Pay auction experiment on the gender heuristic of the desire to win. Working Paper.

  • Png, Ivan P. L. (1986). Optimal subsidies and damages in the presence of judicial error. International Review of Law and Economics, 6, 101–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polinsky, A. M., & Shavell, S. (2009). Public Enforcement of Law (Vol. 3). Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Potters, J., de Vries, C., & van Winden, F. (1998). An experimental investigation of rational rent seeking. European Journal of Political Economy, 14(4), 783–800.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Price, C., & Sheremeta, R. (2015). Endowment origin, demographic effects and individual preferences in contests. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 24, 597–619.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rizzolli, M., & Stanca, L. (2012). Judicial errors and crime deterrence: Theory and experimental evidence. Journal of Law and Economics, 55(2), 311–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt, U., & Traub, S. (2002). An experimental test of loss aversion. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 25(3), 233–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sheremeta, R. (2013). Overbidding and heterogeneous behavior in contest experiments. Journal of Economic Surveys, 27, 491–514.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sheremeta, R., & Zhang, J. (2010). Can groups solve the problem of over-bidding in contests? Social Choice and Welfare, 35, 175–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thorngate, W., & Carroll, B. (1990). Tests versus contests: A theory of adjudication. Recent Research in Psychology, 65, 431–438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thorngate, W., Dawes, R. M., & Foddy, M. (2009). Judging Merit. Psychology Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient Rent-seeking. In J. M. Buchanan, R. D. Tollison, & G. Tullock (Eds.), Toward a Theory of the Rent-seeking Society, 97–112. Texas A &M University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance (EIEF). We thank for their useful comments Pierpaolo Battigalli, Lorenzo Cappellari, Marco Faravelli, Marco Mantovani, Elena Manzoni, Matteo Rizzolli, seminar participants at the SAET conference, held in Ischia, at the conference Contests: Theory and Evidence held at the University of East Anglia, at the IMEBESS conference, held at LUISS, and two anonymous referees. Any remaining errors are our responsability.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Astrid Gamba.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The replication material for the study is available at https://doi.org/10.3886/E182901V3.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file 1 (pdf 1158 KB)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gamba, A., Stanca, L. Mis-judging merit: the effects of adjudication errors in contests. Exp Econ 26, 550–587 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-022-09785-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-022-09785-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation