Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Land conversion pace under uncertainty and irreversibility: too fast or too slow?

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper stochastic dynamic programming is used to investigate land conversion decisions taken by a multitude of landholders under uncertainty about the value of environmental services and irreversible development. We study land conversion under competition on the market for agricultural products when voluntary and mandatory measures are combined by the Government to induce habitat conservation. We show that land conversion can be delayed by paying landholders for the provision of environmental services and by limiting the individual extent of developable land. It is found, instead, that the presence of ceilings on aggregate conversion may lead to runs which rapidly exhaust the targeted amount of land. We study the impact of uncertainty on the optimal conversion policy and discuss conversion dynamics under different policy scenarios on the basis of the relative long-run expected rate of deforestation. Interestingly, we show that uncertainty, even if it induces conversion postponement in the short-run, increases the average rate of deforestation and reduces expected time for total conversion in the long run. Finally, we illustrate our findings through some numerical simulations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. On the economics of tropical deforestation and land use a theme issue can be found in Land Economics (Barbier and Burgess 2001).

  2. The idea of a social planner implementing the social optimum by simply commanding the constitution of protected areas, is far from reality. Since the majority of remaining ecosystems are on land privately owned, the economic and political cost of such intervention makes the adoption of command mechanisms by Governments unlikely (Langpap and Wu 2004; Sierra and Russman 2006).

  3. In Australia, the Productivity Commission reports evidence of pre-emptive clearing due to the introduction of clearing restrictions (Productivity Commission 2004). On unintended impacts of public policy see for instance Stavins and Jaffe (1990) showing that, despite an explicit federal conservation policy, 30 % of forested wetland conversion in the Mississippi Valley has been induced by federal flood-control projects. In this respect, see also Mæstad (2001) showing how timber trade restrictions may induce an increase in logging.

  4. A similar effect has been firstly noted by Bartolini (1993). In this paper, the author studies decentralized investment decision in a market where a limit on aggregate investment is present.

  5. Among them, see for instance Conrad (1980), Clarke and Reed (1989), Reed (1993), Conrad (1997), Conrad (2000), and Kassar and Lasserre (2004).

  6. In US the Conservation Reserve Program (CRP) is a voluntary program rewarding agricultural producers using environmentally sensitive land for the provision of conservation benefits (Farm Services Agency (FSA) 2012).

  7. PES schemes have become increasingly common in both developed and developing countries. See e.g. Ferraro (2001), Ferraro and Kiss (2002), Ferraro and Simpson (2005) and Ferraro (2008). Following Wunder (2005, p. 3), a PES is “(1) a voluntary transaction where (2) a well-defined ES (or a land-use likely to secure that service) (3) is being “bought” by a (minimum one) ES buyer (4) from a (minimum one) ES provider (5) if and only if the ES provider secures ES provision (conditionality)”. See Pagiola (2008) on the PES program in Costa Rica and Wunder et al. (2008) for a comparative analysis of PES programs in developed and developing countries.

  8. Note that in this case in line with Leahy (1993) the timing of conversion under competition would be equal to the timing of conversion set by a sole agent.

  9. As in Bulte et al. (2002) \(A_{0}\) may represent the best land which has been already converted to agriculture.

  10. For the sake of generality we simply refer to landholders. In our model in fact, as quite common in a developing country scenario, the appropriability of values attached to land is not conditional on the existence of a legal entitlement. See Gregersen et al. (2010).

  11. None of our results relies on this assumption. In fact, provided that no single agent has significant market power, we can obtain identical results by allowing each agent to own more than one unit of land. See e.g. Baldursson (1998) and Grenadier (2002).

  12. They may include biodiversity conservation, carbon sequestration, watershed control, provision of scenic beauty for recreational activities and ecotourism, timber and non-timber forest products. See e.g. Conrad (1997), Conrad (2000), Clarke and Reed (1989), Reed (1993), and Bulte et al. (2002).

  13. The Brownian motion in (2) is a reasonable approximation for conservation benefits and we share this assumption with most of the existing literature. (Conrad (1997), p. 98) considers a geometric Brownian motion for the amenity value as a plausible assumption to capture uncertainty over individual preferences for amenity. Bulte et al. (2002, p.152) point out that “ parameter\(\alpha \) can be positive (e.g., reflecting an increasingly important carbon sink function as atmospheric CO\(_2\) concentration rises), but it may also be negative (say, due to improvements in combinatorial chemistry that lead to a reduced need for primary genetic material)”. However, this assumption neglects the direct feedback effect that conversion decisions may have on the stochastic process illustrating the dynamic of conservation benefits. See Leroux et al. (2009) for a model where such effect is accounted by letting conservation benefits follow a controlled diffusion process with both drift and volatility depending on the conversion path.

  14. In the following, “landholder” refers to an agent conserving land and “farmer” to an agent cultivating it.

  15. Note in fact that with the simultaneous inclusion of two stochastic variables, the problem has no closed form solution and must be solved numerically. However, this characterization would not impact significantly on our main results.

  16. In Brazil, for instance, according to the legal reserve regulation a private owner must keep the 20 % (80 % in the Amazon) of the surface in the property covered by forest or its native vegetation (Alston and Mueller 2007). The choice of \(\lambda \) may account for considerations related to habitat fragmentation, critical ecological thresholds, enforcement and transaction costs for the program implementation, etc. Finally, note that our analysis is general enough to include also the case where \(\lambda \) is not imposed but is endogenously set by each landholder. In fact, due for instance to financial constraints limiting the extent of the development project, the landholders may find optimal not to convert the entire plot (Pattanayak et al. 2010).

  17. A lower payment rate can be justified on the basis of a less valuable ES provision due to the disturbance, implicitly produced by developing the plot, to the previously intact natural habitat. For instance, one may assume that an unique payment rate \(\eta \) is fixed but that once the plot is developed the per-unit ES value, \(B(t),\) is lowered by some \(k\in [0,1)\). It is straightforward to see that by simply setting \(\eta _{2}=k\eta _{1}\) our results would still hold.

  18. As pointed out by Engel et al. (2008), by internalizing external non-market values from conservation, PES schemes have attracted increasing interest as mechanisms to induce the provision of ES. Consistently, the payment rates, \(\eta _{1}\) and \(\eta _{2}\), may be interpreted as the levels of appropriability that the society is willing to guarantee on the value generated by conserving, i.e. \(B(t)\) and \(\lambda B(t)\) respectively. Finally, note that as \(\eta _{1}\) and \(\eta _{2}\) are constant then payments also follow a geometric Brownian motion [easily derivable from (2)]. However, this is different from the way payments are modelled in Isik and Yang (2004) where they also depend on the fluctuations in the conservation cost opportunity (profit from agriculture, changes in environmental policy, etc.).

  19. On ecosystem resilience, threshold effects and conservation policies see Perrings and Pearce (1994). Note that the quality of our results would not change if one characterized \(\bar{A}\) as the expected surface at which the Government will impede further land conversion.

  20. See for instance Hansen and Rotella (2002) and Hansen and DeFries (2007).

  21. This could be the case for an area covered by a tropical forest (Bulte et al. 2002; Leroux et al. 2009), or a protected area where farmers located next to the site may sustainably extract natural resources (Tisdell 1995; Wells et al. 1992).

  22. To consider infinitesimally small agents is a standard assumption in infinite horizon models investigating dynamic industry equilibrium under competition. See for instance Jovanovic (1982), Dixit (1989), Hopenhayn (1992), Lambson (1992), Dixit and Pindyck (1994, chp. 8), Bartolini (1993), Caballero and Pindyck (1992), Dosi and Moretto (1997) and Moretto (2008).

  23. Note that we may use either \(N(t)\) or \(A(t)\) when evaluating the individual decision process.

  24. Note that the expected value must be taken accounting for \(A(t)\) increasing over time as land is cleared. See Harrison (1985, p. 44).

  25. Bulte et al. (2002, p. 152) define \(c\) as “the marginal land conversion cost”. It “may be negative if there is a positive one-time net benefit from logging the site that exceeds the costs of preparing the harvested site for crop production”. We also assume, without loss of generality, that the conversion cost is proportional to the surface cleared.

  26. Note that, as shown in Di Corato et al. (2011), the problem can be equivalently solved considering a landholder evaluating the option to develop.

  27. In the following we will drop the time subscript for notational convenience.

  28. In our setting the (competitive) equilibrium bounding the profit process for each farmer can be constructed as a symmetric Nash equilibrium in entry strategies. By the infinite divisibility of \(F\), the equilibrium can be determined by simply looking at the single landholder clearing policy which is defined ignoring the competitors’ entry decisions (see Leahy 1993).

  29. See Appendix A.1.

  30. This means the \(A^{+}th\) is the last landholder for whom \( V_{B}(A^{+},B^{*}(A^{+});\bar{A})=0.\)

  31. In Bartolini (1993) a similar result is obtained. Under linear adjustment costs and stochastic returns, investment cost is constant up to the investment limit where it becomes infinite. As a reaction to this external effect, recurrent runs may occur under competition as aggregate investment approaches the ceiling. See also Moretto (2008).

  32. Figures 4 and 5 are obtained using the calibration adopted for the numerical exercise developed in Sect. 6.

  33. This result is in line with Ferraro (2001, p. 997) where the author states that conservation practitioners “may also find that they do not need to make payments for an entire targeted ecosystem to achieve their objectives. They need to include only “just enough” of the ecosystem to make it unlikely, given current economic conditions, infrastructure, and enforcement levels, that anyone would convert the remaining area to other uses”.

  34. In other words, a competitive equilibrium evolves as maximizing solution for the expected present value of social welfare in the form of consumer surplus (Lucas and Prescott 1971; (Dixit and Pindyck 1994, ch.9)).

  35. Although most of the PES programs in developing countries were introduced as quid pro quo for legal restrictions on land clearing, there are no specific contract conditions preventing the landholder from clearing the area enrolled under the program ((Pagiola 2008, p. 717)). In principle, sanctions may apply. For instance, in the PSA (Pagos por Servicios Ambientales) program in Costa Rica, payments received plus interest should be returned by the landholders exiting the scheme (FONAFIFO 2007). However, in a developing country context, economic and political costs may reduce the enforcement of such sanction.

  36. On compensation and land taking see Adler (2008).

  37. See also Di Corato et al. (2012) for an application concerning the derivation of the long-run average growth rate of capital.

  38. Note in fact that in general we may have long periods of inaction when \(\xi <\hat{\xi }\) followed by short periods of rapid bursts of land conversion whenever \(\xi \) reaches \(\hat{\xi }\). In the first case, no entries in the market occur and the average rate of deforestation is null. In contrast, in the second case, since entry in the market is instantaneous then the rate of deforestation is infinite (see Harrison 1985; Dixit 1993).

  39. This is also consistent with results obtained by Dixit and Pindyck (1994, pp. 372–373) and Hartman and Hendrickson (2002) when studying the long-run average growth rate of invested capital.

  40. We show in Appendix A.4 that to a higher \(\sigma \) corresponds a higher probability of hitting \(\hat{\xi }\) and thus a higher long run average deforestation rate.

  41. Further details are available at http://www.acto.go.cr/general_info.php and http://www.sinac.go.cr/areassilvestres.php.

  42. The total forested area includes 100,000 ha under protection and 48,000 ha without.

  43. We simply subtract from 355,375 ha the surface of 148,000 ha that, up to Calvo (2009, p. 11), is still forested.

  44. See Bulte et al. (2002, pp. 154–155).

  45. To model the decreasing marginal benefits of deforestation Bulte et al. (2002, pp. 153–154) adopts a linear programming model. The model allows for three types of land quality, nine crop and five pasture activities, and several different farm management practices.

  46. Bulte et al. (2002) and Leroux et al. 2009 use \(c=0\) assuming that the revenue from timber sales offsets the clearing costs.

  47. Our findings seem in contrast with the calibration used in Leroux et al. (2009) where the authors assume a deforestation rate equal to 2.5 with \( \alpha =0.05\) and \(\sigma =0.1\). In fact, we show that for those values the deforestation rate should be null. A \(2.5~\%\) deforestation rate would be justified only for lower \(\alpha \) and higher \(\sigma .\)

  48. Numerical results under other scenarios are available upon request.

  49. Tables illustrating scenarios with land conversion run for \(\widetilde{B} =200 \) and without land conversion run (\(\bar{A}\ge \hat{A}\)) are available in the Appendix.

  50. Note that having assumed \(\eta _{1}\ge \eta _{2}\), we have \(\eta _{1}>\lambda \eta _{2}.\) This implies that only a fall in \(B\) can induce conversion. Di Corato et al. (2010) show that by relaxing such assumption also an increase in \(B\) may induce land conversion.

  51. The total surface cultivated, \(A\), is constant over the time interval \(dt\) and the farmer can be seen as holding an asset (his plot) paying \(\Delta \pi (A,B;\bar{A})~dt\) as cash flow and \(E[dV(A,B;\bar{A})]\) as capital gain.

  52. The solution for the homogeneous part of (15) is \(V(A,B;\bar{A})= Z_{1}(A)B^{^{\beta _{1}}}+Z_{2}(A)B^{^{\beta _{2}}}\) where \(\beta _{1}>1\) and \(\beta _{2}<0\) are the roots of \(Q(\beta )=0\) and \(Z_{1}(A)\) and \( Z_{2}(A)\) are two constants to be determined. However, as \(B\) increases, the value of the option to develop land should vanish, i.e., \(\lim _{B\rightarrow \infty }\) \(V(A,B;\bar{A})=0\). Hence, we must drop the first term by setting \( Z_{1}(A)=0\).

References

  • Adler JH (2008) Money or nothing: the adverse environmental consequences of uncompensated land-use controls. Boston Coll Law Rev 49(2):301–366

    Google Scholar 

  • Alston LJ, Mueller B (2007) Legal reserve requirements in Brazilian forests: path dependent evolution of de facto legislation. ANPEC Revista Econ 8(4):25–53

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow KJ, Fisher AC (1974) Environmental preservation, uncertainty, and irreversibility. Q J Econ 88:312–319

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartolini L (1993) Competitive runs, the case of a ceiling on aggregate investment. Eur Econ Rev 37:921–948

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldursson FM (1998) Irreversible investment under uncertainty in oligopoly. J Econ Dyn Control 22:627–644

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bulte E, van Soest DP, van Kooten GC, Schipper RA (2002) Forest conservation in Costa Rica when nonuse benefits are uncertain but rising. Am J Agric Econ 84(1):150–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barbier EB, Burgess JC (eds) (2001) Tropical deforestation and land use. Land Econ 77(2):155–314

  • Bowman MS, Soares-Filho BS, Merry FD, Nepstad DC, Rodrigues H, Almeida OT (2012) Persistence of cattle ranching in the Brazilian Amazon: a spatial analysis of the rationale for beef production. Land Use Policy 29(3):558–568

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero R, Pindyck RS (1992) Uncertainty, investment and industry evolution. NBER working Paper No. 4160

  • Clarke HR, Reed WJ (1989) The tree-cutting problem in a stochastic environment. J Econ Dyn Control 13:569–595

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo J (2009) Bosque, cobertura y recursos forestales 2008. Ponencia preparada para el Decimoquinto Informe Estado de la Nación. San José, Programa Estado de la Nación. http://www.estadonacion.or.cr/images/stories/informes/015/docs/Armonia/Calvo_2009.pdf (Accessed 21 July 2012)

  • Conrad JM (1980) Quasi-option value and the expected value of information. Q J Econ 95:813–820

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conrad JM (1997) On the option value of old-growth forest. Ecol Econ 22:97–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conrad JM (2000) Wilderness: options to preserve, extract, or develop. Resour Energy Econ 22(3):205–219

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Corato L, Moretto M, Vergalli S (2012) Long-run average growth rate of capital: an analytical approximation. University of Padua, Mimeo

  • Di Corato L, Moretto M, Vergalli S (2011) Land conversion pace under uncertainty and irreversibility: too fast or too slow? FEEM Nota di Lavoro 84.2011

  • Di Corato L, Moretto M, Vergalli S (2010) An equilibrium model of habitat conservation under uncertainty and irreversibility. FEEM Nota di Lavoro 160.2010

  • Dixit AK (1989) Entry and exit decisions under uncertainty. J Polit Econ 97:620–638

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit AK (1993) The art of smooth pasting. Harwood Academic Publishers, Switzerland

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit AK, Pindyck RS (1994) Investment under uncertainty. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi C, Moretto M (1997) Pollution accumulation and firm incentives to promote irreversible technological change under uncertain private benefits. Environ Resour Econ 10:285–300

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engel S, Palmer C, Taschini L, Urech S (2012) Cost-effective payments for reducing emissions from deforestation under uncertainty. Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy Working Paper No. 82

  • Engel S, Pagiola S (2008) Designing payments for environmental services in theory and practice: an overview of the issues. Ecol Econ 65:663–674

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferraro PJ (2001) Global habitat protection: limitations of development interventions and a role for conservation performance payments. Conserv Biol 15:990–1000

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferraro PJ, Kiss A (2002) Direct payments to conserve biodiversity. Science 298:1718–1719

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferraro PJ, Simpson RD (2005) Protecting forests and biodiversity: are investments in eco-friendly production activities the best way to protect endangered ecosystems and enhance rural livelihoods? Forests Trees Livelihoods 15:167–181

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferraro PJ (2008) Asymmetric information and contract design for payments for environmental services. Ecol Econ 65(4):810–821

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • FONAFIFO (2007) Manual de Procedimientos para el pago de Servicios Ambientales. Gaceta, 51. http://www.fonafifo.com/text_files/servicios_ambientales/Manuales/MPPSA_2007.pdf (Accessed 21 July 2012)

  • Farm Services Agency (FSA) (2012) Conservation reserve program, general sign-Up 43. Fact sheet: February 2012. http://www.fsa.usda.gov/Internet/FSA_File/gs43factsheet.pdf (Accessed 21 July 2012)

  • Gregersen H, El Lakany H, Karsenty A (2010) Does the opportunity cost approach indicate the real cost of REDD+? Rights and realities of paying for REDD+. Rights and Resources Initiative, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Grenadier SR (2002) Option exercise games: an application to the equilibrium investment strategies of firms. Rev Fin Stud 15:691–721

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen AJ, Rotella JJ (2002) Biophysical factors, land use, and species viability in and around nature reserves. Conserv Biol 16(4):1112–1122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen AJ, DeFries R (2007) Ecological mechanisms linking protected areas to surrounding lands. Ecol Appl 17(4):974–988

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison JM (1985) Brownian motion and stochastic flow systems. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Hartman R, Hendrickson M (2002) Optimal partially reversible investment. J Econ Dyn Control 26:483–508

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henry C (1974) Investment decisions under uncertainty: the “Irreversibility Effect”. Am Econ Rev 64(6):1006–1012

    Google Scholar 

  • Hopenhayn H (1992) Entry, exit and firm dynamics in long run equilibrium. Econometrica 60:1127–1150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Isik M, Yang W (2004) An analysis of the effects of uncertainty and irreversibility on farmer participation in the conservation reserve program. J Agric Resour Econ 29(2):242–259

    Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic B (1982) Selection and the evolution of industry. Econometrica 50:649–670

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kassar I, Lasserre P (2004) Species preservation and biodiversity value: a real options approach. J Environ Econ Manage 48(2):857–879

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lambson VE (1992) Competitive profits in the long run. Rev Econ Stud 59:125–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langpap C, Wu J (2004) Voluntary conservation of endangered species: when does no regulatory assurance mean no conservation? J Environ Econ Manage 47:435–457

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leahy JV (1993) Investment in competitive equilibrium: the optimality of myopic behavior. Q J Econ 108(4):1105–1133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leroux AD, Martin VL (2009) Optimal conservation, extinction debt, and the augmented quasi-option value. J Environ Econ Manage 58:43–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas RE Jr, Prescott EC (1971) Investment under uncertainty. Econometrica 39:659–681

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mæstad O (2001) Timber trade restrictions and tropical deforestation: a forest mining approach. Resour Energy Econ 23(2):111–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moretto M (2008) Competition and irreversible investment under uncertainty. Inf Econ Policy 20(1):75–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pagiola S (2008) Payments for environmental services in Costa Rica. Ecol Econ 65(4):712–724

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pattanayak S, Wunder S (2010) Show me the money: do payments supply environmental services in developing countries? Rev Environ Econ Policy 4(2):254–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perrings C, Pearce D (1994) Threshold effects and incentives for conservation of biodiversity. Environ Resour Econ 4:13–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Productivity Commission (2004) Impacts of native vegetation and biodiversity regulations. Productivity Commission Working Paper No. 29. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=600970

  • Reed WJ (1993) The decision to conserve or harvest old-growth forest. Ecol Econ 8:45–69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schatzki T (2003) Options, uncertainty and sunk costs: an empirical analysis of land use change. J Environ Econ Manage 46(1):86–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Segerson K, Miceli TJ (1998) Voluntary environmental agreements: good or bad news for environmental protection. J Environ Econ Manage 36:109–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sierra R, Russman E (2006) On the efficiency of environmental service payments: a forest conservation assessment in the Osa Peninsula, Costa Rica. Ecol Econ 59:131–141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stavins RN, Jaffe AB (1990) Unintended impacts of public investments on private decisions: the depletion of forested wetlands. Am Econ Rev 80(3):337–352

    Google Scholar 

  • Tisdell CA (1995) Issues in biodiversity conservation including the role of local communities. Environ Conserv 22:216–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wells M, Brandon KE, Hannsh L (1992) People and parks: linking procteded area management with local communities. The World Bank, WWF, and USAID, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Wunder S, Engel S, Pagiola S (2008) Taking stock: a comparative analysis of payments for environmental services programs in developed and developing countries. Ecol Econ 65:834–853

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wunder S (2005) Payments for environmental services: some nuts and bolts. CIFOR Occasional paper 42. Center for International Forestry Research, Bogor

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sergio Vergalli.

Additional information

We wish to thank Guido Candela, Yishay Maoz and Peter Kort for helpful comments. We are also grateful for comments and suggestions to participants at the 12th International BIOECON conference; the 51st SIE conference; the 18th Annual EAERE Conference; the 8th workshop of the International Society of Dynamic Games; the 16th Real Options Conference; and to seminar participants at FEEM and IEFE, Bocconi University, University of Stirling, CERE, Umeå University, University of Brescia. The usual disclaimer applies.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A.1 Proof of Proposition 1

Let \(V(A,B;\bar{A})\) be twice-differentiable in \(B\) and consider a short interval \(dt\) where no conversion takes place.Footnote 50 So, by applying a standard dynamic programming approach, the farmer’s value function in (5) can be rewritten as follows:Footnote 51

$$\begin{aligned} rV(A,B;\bar{A})~dt=\Delta \pi (A,B;\bar{A})~dt+E_{0}[dV(A,B;\bar{A})] \end{aligned}$$
(14)

Expanding \(dV(A,B;\bar{A})\) using Ito’s Lemma, the solution to (14) must solve the following differential equation:

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}B^{2}V_{BB}(A,B;\bar{A})+\alpha BV_{B}(A,B;\bar{A})-rV(A,B;\bar{A}) \nonumber \\&\quad +\left[ (1-\lambda )\delta A^{-\gamma }+(\lambda \eta _{2}-\eta _{1})B\right] =0 \end{aligned}$$
(15)

Using standard arguments the solution of (15) is (see Dixit and Pindyck 1994):Footnote 52

$$\begin{aligned} V(A,B;\bar{A})=Z(A)B^{\beta }+(1-\lambda )\frac{\delta A^{-\gamma }}{r} +(\lambda \eta _{2}-\eta _{1})\frac{B}{r-\alpha } \end{aligned}$$
(16)

where \(\beta \) is the negative root of the characteristic equation \(Q(\beta )=\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}\beta (\beta -1)+\alpha \beta -r=0\) and \(Z(A)\) is a constant to be determined.

To determine \(Z(A)\) and \(B^{*}(A)\) some suitable boundary conditions on (16) are required. First, further land development, by increasing the number of competing farmers in the market, keeps the value of being an active farmer below \((1-\lambda )c\) (value-matching condition). Formally, this is equivalent to impose:

$$\begin{aligned} Z(A)B^{*}(A)^{^{\beta }}+\frac{(1-\lambda )\delta }{r}A^{-\gamma }+(\lambda \eta _{2}-\eta _{1})\frac{B^{*}(A)}{r-\alpha }=(1-\lambda )c \end{aligned}$$
(17a)

Second, by differentiating the value-matching condition (17a) totally with respect to \(A\), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial V(A,B^{*}(A);\bar{A})}{\partial A}=V_{A}(A,B^{*}(A); \bar{A})+V_{B}(A,B^{*}(A);\bar{A})\frac{{\small dB}^{*}{\small (A)}}{ dA}=0\qquad \quad \end{aligned}$$
(17b)

Now, let’s recall that marginal rents for an active farmer must be null at \(B^{*}(A)\) (see e.g. Proposition 1 in Bartolini (1993) and Grenadier (2002, p. 699) i.e.:

$$\begin{aligned} V_{A}(A,B^{*}(A);\bar{A})=Z^{\prime }(A)B^{*}(A)^{\beta }-(1-\lambda )\frac{\delta \gamma A^{-(\gamma +1)}}{r}=0 \end{aligned}$$
(17c)

Substituting (17c) into (17b) yields the following condition (extended smooth-pasting condition):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial V(A,B^{*}(A);\bar{A})}{\partial A}=V_{B}(A,B^{*}(A); \bar{A})\frac{{\small dB}^{*}{\small (A)}}{dA}=0 \end{aligned}$$
(17d)

where \(V_{B}(A,B^{*}(A);\bar{A})=\beta Z\left( A\right) B^{*}(A)^{\beta -1}+\frac{\lambda \eta _{2}-\eta _{1}}{r-\alpha }\).

Third, considering the limit on conversion, \(\bar{A}\), imposed by the Government, the last boundary condition to be considered is:

$$\begin{aligned} Z(\bar{A})=0 \end{aligned}$$
(18)

Note that condition (17d) plays the same role of a complementary-slackness condition in standard programming. That is, it must hold whenever control takes place.

Assume for the moment that (17d) holds over the interval \([A_{0},\bar{A}]\) with \(\frac{{\small dB}^{*}{\small (A)}}{dA}\ne 0\). This implies that \(V_{B}(A,B^{*}(A);\bar{A})=\beta Z(A)B^{*}(A)^{^{\beta -1}}+\frac{ \lambda \eta _{2}-\eta _{1}}{r-\alpha }=0\). Note that since \(\frac{\lambda \eta _{2}-\eta _{1}}{r-\alpha }<0\), then, as conjectured, \(Z(A)<0\). Hence, each landholder exercises the option to convert at the level of \(B^{*}(A) \) where the value, \(V(A,B^{*}(A);\bar{A})\) is tangent to the conversion cost, \(\left( 1-\lambda \right) c\). This critical threshold is given by the solution of the system including equations (17a) and \( V_{B}(A,B^{*}(A);\bar{A})=0\). Solving it, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} B^{*}(A)=\frac{\beta }{\beta -1}\left( r-\alpha \right) \frac{1-\lambda }{\eta _{1}-\lambda \eta _{2}}\left[ \left( \frac{\hat{A}}{A}\right) ^{\gamma }-1\right] c, \end{aligned}$$
(19)

which, as one can easily verify, is a continuous decreasing function of \(A\).

Now, consider a landholder following the smooth-pasting policy in (19) and suppose he is the last able to convert his plot. By using (16) and (18) it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} V(\bar{A},B^{*}(\bar{A});\bar{A})-\lim _{B\rightarrow B^{*}(\bar{A} )}V(A,B;\bar{A})>0 \end{aligned}$$
(20)

where \(V(\bar{A},B^{*}(\bar{A});\bar{A})=(1-\lambda )\frac{\delta \bar{A} ^{-\gamma }}{r}+(\lambda \eta _{2}-\eta _{1})\frac{B^{*}(\bar{A})}{ r-\alpha }\)

Note that the inequality (20) holds due the presence of the term, \(Z(A)B^{\beta }\), accounting for future market entries. The upward jump in value in (20) contradicts the optimality of \(B^{*}(A)\) by violating the smooth-pasting condition \(V_{B}(A,B^{*}(A);\bar{A})=0\). Note in fact that in this case \(V_{B}(\bar{A},B^{*}(\bar{A});\bar{A})=\frac{\lambda \eta _{2}-\eta _{1}}{r-\alpha }<0\). Hence, by using (17a), at \(A=\bar{A}\) the optimal conversion threshold is given by

$$\begin{aligned} B^{*}(\bar{A})=\left( r-\alpha \right) \frac{1-\lambda }{\eta _{1}-\lambda \eta _{2}}\left[ \left( \frac{\hat{A}}{\bar{A}}\right) ^{\gamma }-1\right] c \end{aligned}$$
(21)

Furthermore, as all landholders are equal, all expect such upward jump in value occurring at \(B=B^{*}(\bar{A})\). Therefore, as \(B^{*}(A)\) is decreasing in \(A,\) by starting at \(\bar{A}\) each landholder would maximizes the value of his conversion option by pre-empting the entry of others. By playing backward, pre-emption is then a (perfect) Nash equilibrium strategy up to a certain \(A=A^{+}\) where \(V(A^{+},B^{*}(A^{+});\bar{A})-\lim _{B\rightarrow B^{*}(A^{+})}V(A,B;\bar{A})=0\). Note that this implies that: (a) the candidate policy in the interval \([A^{+}, \bar{A}]\) is to impose \(\frac{dB^{*}(A)}{dA}=0\); (b) the optimal conversion threshold for all the discrete amount of conversion in the interval \([A^{+},\bar{A}]\) is the value-maximizer \(B^{*}(\bar{A})\); (c) at \(A^{+}\) the necessary condition for optimality, \(V_{B}(A,B^{*}(A); \bar{A})=0,\) holds again.

Finally, to determine \(A^{+}\) consider that \(A^{+}\) splits the interval \( [A_{0},\bar{A}]\) into an interval where landholders rush and a run takes place and an interval where landholders follows a “smooth-pasting” conversion policy. This means that \(A^{+}\) must satisfy both (19) and (21), i.e., \(B^{*}(A^{+})=B^{*}(\bar{A})\).

Substituting and solving for \(A^{+}\), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} A^{+}=\left[ \frac{(\beta -1)\bar{A}^{-\gamma }+\hat{A}^{-\gamma }}{\beta }\right] ^{-\frac{1}{\gamma }} \end{aligned}$$
(22a)

Finally, let’s consider the following two scenarios: \(\hat{A}\le \bar{A}\) and \(\hat{A}>\bar{A}\). From (22a) it follows that:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\beta }{\beta -1}\left[ \left( \frac{\hat{A}}{A^{+}}\right) ^{\gamma }-1\right] =\left( \frac{\hat{A}}{\bar{A}}\right) ^{\gamma }-1 \end{aligned}$$
(22b)

Studying (22b) we can state that since \(\frac{\beta }{\beta -1}>0\):

  • if \(\hat{A}\le \bar{A}\) then it must be \(\bar{A}\le A^{+}\). This implies that there is no run taking place. Land will be converted smoothly according to (19) up to \(\hat{A}\) since \(\frac{\delta }{r} A^{-\gamma }\le c\) for \(A\ge \hat{A}\);

  • if \(\hat{A}>\bar{A}\) then it must be \(A^{+}<\bar{A}\). In this case, land is converted smoothly up to \(A^{+}\) where landholders start a run to convert land up to \(\bar{A}\).

1.2 A.2 Long-run distributions

Let \(h\) be a linear Brownian motion with parameters \(\mu \) and \(\sigma \) that evolves according to \(dh=\mu dt+\sigma dw\). Following Harrison (1985, pp. 90–91); see also Dixit (1993, pp. 58–68)] the long-run density function for \(h\) fluctuating between a lower reflecting barrier, \(a\in (-\infty ,\infty )\), and an upper reflecting barrier, \(b\in (-\infty ,\infty )\), is represented by the following truncated exponential distribution:

$$\begin{aligned} f\left( h\right) =\left\{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} \frac{2\mu }{\sigma ^{2}}\frac{e^{\frac{2\mu }{\sigma ^{2}}h}}{e^{\frac{ 2\mu }{\sigma ^{2}}b}-e^{\frac{2\mu }{\sigma ^{2}}a}} &{} \quad \mu \ne 0, \\ \frac{1}{b-a} &{} \quad \mu =0. \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(23)

We are interested to the limit case where \(a\rightarrow -\infty .\) In this case, from (23) a limiting argument gives:

$$\begin{aligned} f\left( h\right) =\left\{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} \frac{2\mu }{\sigma ^{2}}e^{-\frac{2\mu }{\sigma ^{2}}\left( b-h\right) } &{} \mu >0, \\ 0 &{} \mu \le 0. \end{array}\right. \quad \text{ for } -\!\infty <h<b \end{aligned}$$
(24)

Hence, the long-run average of \(h\) can be evaluated as \(E\left[ h\right] =\int _{\Phi }hf\left( h\right) ~dh\), where \(\Phi \) depends on the distribution assumed. In the steady-state this yields:

$$\begin{aligned} E\left[ h\right] \!=\!\int _{-\infty }^{b}hf\left( h\right) ~dh\!=\!\int _{-\infty }^{b}h\frac{2\mu }{\sigma ^{2}}e^{-\frac{2\mu }{\sigma ^{2}}\left( b-h\right) }~dh\!=\!\frac{2\mu }{\sigma ^{2}}e^{-\frac{2\mu }{\sigma ^{2}} b}\int _{-\infty }^{b}he^{\frac{2\mu }{\sigma ^{2}}h}~dh\!=\!b\!-\!\frac{2\mu }{\sigma ^{2}}\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(25)

1.3 A.3 Proof of Proposition 3

Taking the logarithm of (11) we get:

$$\begin{aligned} \ln \xi&= \ln \left[ \frac{\beta }{\beta -1}\left( 1-\lambda \right) \frac{P_{A}\left( A\right) }{r}-\frac{\eta _{1}-\lambda \eta _{2}}{ r-\alpha }B\right] \nonumber \\&= \ln \left[ \frac{\eta _{1}-\lambda \eta _{2}}{r-\alpha }\right] +\ln \left[ J-B\right] \end{aligned}$$
(26)

where \(J\mathbf = \frac{\beta }{\beta -1}\left( r-\alpha \right) \Psi \frac{ P_{A}\left( A\right) }{r},\,\Psi =\frac{1-\lambda }{\eta _{1}-\lambda \eta _{2}}\) and \(J>B\). Rewriting \(\ln \left[ J-B\right] \) as \(\ln \left[ e^{\ln J}-e^{\ln B}\right] \) and expanding it by Taylor’s theorem around the point ( \(\widetilde{\ln J},\widetilde{\ln B}\)) yields:

$$\begin{aligned} \ln \left[ J-B\right] \simeq v_{0}+v_{1}\ln J+v_{2}\ln B \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} v_{0}&= \ln \left[ e^{\widetilde{\ln J}}-e^{\widetilde{\ln B}}\right] - \left[ \frac{\widetilde{\ln J}}{1-e^{\widetilde{\ln B}-\widetilde{\ln J}}}+ \frac{\widetilde{\ln B}}{1-e^{-(\widetilde{\ln B}-\widetilde{\ln J})}}\right] \\ v_{1}&= \frac{1}{1-e^{\widetilde{\ln B}-\widetilde{\ln J}}}, v_{2}= \frac{1}{1-e^{-(\widetilde{\ln B}-\widetilde{\ln J})}},\,\frac{v_{2}}{v_{1}}= \frac{1-v_{1}}{v_{1}}<0 \end{aligned}$$

By substituting the approximation into (26) it follows that:

$$\begin{aligned} \ln \xi \simeq \ln \frac{\eta _{1}-\lambda \eta _{2}}{r-\alpha } +v_{0}+v_{1}\ln J+v_{2}\ln B \end{aligned}$$
(27)

Now, by Ito’s lemma and the considerations discussed in the paper on the competitive equilibrium, \(\ln \xi \) evolves according to \(d\ln \xi =v_{2}d\ln B=v_{2}[(\alpha -\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2})~dt+\sigma dw]\) with \(\ln \hat{\xi }\) as upper reflecting barrier. Setting \(h=\ln \xi \), the random variable \(\ln \xi \) follows a linear Brownian motion with parameter \(\mu =v_{2}(\alpha -\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2})>0\) and has a long-run distribution with (24) as density function.

Solving (27) with respect to \(\ln A\) we obtain the long-run optimal stock of deforested land, i.e.:

$$\begin{aligned} \ln A\simeq \frac{\ln \left[ \frac{\eta _{1}-\lambda \eta _{2}}{r-\alpha } \right] +v_{0}+v_{1}\ln \left[ \frac{\beta }{\beta -1}\left( r-\alpha \right) \Psi \frac{\delta }{r}\right] +v_{2}\ln B-h}{\gamma v_{1}} \end{aligned}$$
(28)

From (28) by some manipulations we can show that at \(\xi (\tilde{ B},\tilde{A})=\hat{\xi }\)

$$\begin{aligned} 1&= \exp \left( \frac{v_{0}}{v_{1}}\right) \left( \frac{\frac{\eta _{1}-\lambda \eta _{2}}{ r-\alpha }}{\hat{\xi }}\right) ^{\frac{1}{v_{1}}}\left[ \frac{\beta }{\beta -1} \left( r-\alpha \right) \Psi \frac{\delta }{r}\right] A^{-\gamma }B^{\frac{ v_{2}}{v_{1}}} \\&= \exp \left( \frac{v_{0}}{v_{1}}\right) \left[ \frac{\beta }{\beta -1}\left( r-\alpha \right) \Psi \right] ^{-\frac{v_{2}}{v_{1}}}\frac{\delta }{r}c^{-\frac{1}{ v_{1}}}A^{-\gamma }B^{\frac{v_{2}}{v_{1}}} \\&= \exp \left( \frac{v_{0}}{v_{1}}\right) \left( \frac{J}{\frac{\delta }{r}A^{-\gamma }}\right) ^{- \frac{v_{2}}{v_{1}}}\frac{\delta }{r}c^{-\frac{1}{v_{1}}}A^{-\gamma }B^{ \frac{v_{2}}{v_{1}}} \\&= \exp \left( \frac{v_{0}}{v_{1}}\right) J^{-\frac{v_{2}}{v_{1}}}\left( \frac{\delta }{rc} A^{-\gamma }\right) ^{\frac{1}{v_{1}}}B^{\frac{v_{2}}{v_{1}}} \\&= \exp (v_{0})J^{-v_{2}}\left( \frac{\hat{A}}{A}\right) ^{\gamma }B^{v_{2}} \\&= \frac{\widetilde{J}-\widetilde{B}}{\widetilde{J}^{v_{1}}\widetilde{B} ^{v_{2}}}J^{-v_{2}}\left( \frac{\hat{A}}{A}\right) ^{\gamma }B^{v_{2}} \\&= \left( \frac{\tilde{A}}{A}\right) \left( \frac{B}{\widetilde{B}}\right) ^{-\frac{1}{\gamma }[1-\left( \frac{\tilde{A}}{\hat{A}}\right) ^{\gamma }]} \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{A}{\tilde{A}}=\left( \frac{B}{\widetilde{B}}\right) ^{-\frac{1}{\gamma }[1-\left( \frac{ \tilde{A}}{\hat{A}}\right) ^{\gamma }]} \end{aligned}$$

Note that since \(\tilde{A}<\hat{A}\) then \(-\frac{1}{\gamma }[ 1-(\frac{ \tilde{A}}{\hat{A}})^{\gamma }] <0\).

Taking the expected value on both sides of (28) leads to:

$$\begin{aligned} E\left[ \ln A\right] \simeq \frac{\ln \left[ \frac{\eta _{1}\!-\!\lambda \eta _{2}}{r\!-\!\alpha }\right] \!+\!v_{0}\!+\!v_{1}\ln \left[ \frac{\beta }{\beta \!-\!1}\left( r\!-\!\alpha \right) \Psi \frac{\delta }{r}\right] \!+\!v_{2}\left[ B_{0}\!+\!\left( \alpha \!-\! \frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}\right) t\right] \!-\!E\left[ h\right] }{\gamma v_{1}} \end{aligned}$$

Since by (25) \(E(h)\) is independent on \(t\), differentiating with respect to \(t\), we obtain the expected long-run rate of deforestation:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{dt}E\left[ d\ln A\right] \simeq \frac{\alpha -\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2} }{\gamma }\frac{v_{2}}{v_{1}}=-\frac{\alpha -\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}}{\gamma } e^{\widetilde{\ln B}-\widetilde{\ln J}} \quad \text{ for } \alpha <\frac{1}{2} \sigma ^{2} \end{aligned}$$

By the monotonicity property of the logarithm, \(\widetilde{B} \)must exists such that \(\ln \widetilde{B}=\widetilde{\ln B}\). Furthermore, by plugging \(\widetilde{B}\) into (7), we can always find a surface \(\tilde{A}\) and \( \widetilde{J}=\frac{\beta }{\beta -1}\left( r-\alpha \right) \Psi \frac{ P_{A}( \tilde{A}) }{r}\) such that a linearization along (\(\widetilde{\ln B},\widetilde{\ln J}\)) is equivalent to a linearization along (\(\ln \widetilde{B},\ln \widetilde{J}\)), where \(\widetilde{\ln J}=\ln \widetilde{J}\). This implies that by setting \((\widetilde{B},\tilde{A})\), the long-run average rate of deforestation can be written as:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{dt}E\left[ d\ln A\right]&= -\frac{\alpha -\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}}{ \gamma }\frac{\widetilde{B}}{\widetilde{J}}=-\frac{\alpha -\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}}{\gamma }\frac{1}{1+\frac{\beta }{\beta -1}( r-\alpha ) \Psi \frac{c}{\widetilde{B}}} \\&= -\frac{\alpha -\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}}{\gamma }\frac{\frac{P_{A}(\tilde{A}) }{r}-c}{\frac{P_{A}(\tilde{A}) }{r}}=-\frac{ \alpha -\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}}{\gamma }\Bigg (1-\frac{c}{\frac{\delta }{r}\tilde{A }^{-\gamma }}\Bigg ) \end{aligned}$$

where \(\frac{P_{A}(\tilde{A}) }{r}=\frac{\widetilde{B} }{\frac{\beta }{\beta -1} ( r-\alpha ) \Psi }+c\) and \(\tilde{A}< \hat{A}\).

1.4 A.4 The impact of uncertainty on the distribution of \(\xi \)

Rearranging (27) yields

$$\begin{aligned} \ln \xi \simeq U_{\xi }+v_{2}\ln B \end{aligned}$$
(29)

where \(U_{\xi }=\ln \frac{\eta _{1}-\lambda \eta _{2}}{r-\alpha } +v_{0}+v_{1}\ln J.\)

By some manipulations:

$$\begin{aligned} e^{\ln \xi }&= e^{U_{\xi }+v_{2}\ln B} \nonumber \\ \xi&= e^{U_{\xi }}B^{v_{2}} \end{aligned}$$
(30)

Using Ito’s lemma

$$\begin{aligned} d\xi&= e^{U_{\xi }}\left[ v_{2}B^{v_{2}-1}dB+\frac{1}{2} v_{2}(v_{2}-1)B^{v_{2}-2}(dB)^{2}\right] \\&= e^{U_{\xi }}B^{v_{2}}v_{2}\left\{ \left[ \alpha +\frac{1}{2} (v_{2}-1)\sigma ^{2}\right] ~dt+\sigma dw\right\} \\&= \xi v_{2}\left\{ \left[ \alpha +\frac{1}{2}(v_{2}-1)\sigma ^{2}\right] ~dt+\sigma ~dw\right\} \end{aligned}$$

Calculating first, second moment and variance for \(\xi \) we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} E(\xi )&= \xi (0)e^{v_{2}[\alpha +\frac{1}{2}(v_{2}-1)\sigma ^{2}]t} \\ E(\xi ^{2})&= \xi ^{2}(0)e^{2v_{2}[\alpha +(v_{2}-\frac{1}{2})\sigma ^{2}]t} \\ Var(\xi )&= \xi ^{2}(0)e^{2v_{2}\left[ \alpha +\frac{1}{2}(v_{2}-1)\sigma ^{2}\right] t}(e^{v_{2}^{2}\sigma ^{2}t}-1) \end{aligned}$$

Note that since \(\alpha +\frac{1}{2}(v_{2}-1)\sigma ^{2}<0\) and \(v_{2}<0\) then \(E(\xi )\) is increasing in \(t\). Finally, by deriving \(Var(\xi )\) with respect to \(\sigma \) it is easy to check that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\small \partial Var(\xi )}}{{\small \partial \sigma }}{\small =2v}_{2} {\small \sigma te}^{2v_{2}\left[ \alpha +\frac{1}{2}(v_{2}-1)\sigma ^{2} \right] t}{\small \xi }^{2}{\small (0)}\left[ {\small (v}_{2}{\small -1)(e} ^{v_{2}^{2}\sigma ^{2}t}{\small -1)+v}_{2}{\small e}^{v_{2}^{2}\sigma ^{2}t} \right] {\small >0} \end{aligned}$$

That is, as \(\sigma \) soars \(Var(\xi )\) increases and so does the probability of hitting \(\hat{\xi }\) which in turn implies an increase in the long run average deforestation rate.

1.5 A.5 Additional tables

With land conversion run (Table 7).

Table 7 Optimal forest stock and long-run average rate of deforestation under second-best with \(B=200\) and \(c=500\)

Without land conversion run (Tables 8 and 9)

Table 8 Optimal forest stock and long-run average rate of deforestation under second-best with \(B=75\) and \(c=1500\)
Table 9 Optimal forest stock and long-run average rate of deforestation under second-best with \(B=200\) and \(c=1{,}500\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Di Corato, L., Moretto, M. & Vergalli, S. Land conversion pace under uncertainty and irreversibility: too fast or too slow?. J Econ 110, 45–82 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-013-0348-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-013-0348-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation