Skip to main content

Overlapping-Generations Model of Economic Growth

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Economic Growth and Development

Part of the book series: Springer Texts in Business and Economics ((STBE))

  • 1188 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter introduces the one-sector neoclassical growth model with overlapping generations. The primary focus of the chapter is growth via private physical capital accumulation. We think of private physical capital as manmade durable inputs to the production process. For our purposes, private capital can be primarily thought of as plant and equipment that is produced in one period and then used in production in the following period. To model production, we introduce firms, economic institutions that combine physical capital and labor to produce goods and services. Later in the chapter, we introduce human capital, the knowledge and skills embodied in workers. Chapter 3 adds public capital, the economy’s infrastructure created by the government, such as roads, laws, and utilities.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 69.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Definitions of physical capital will vary depending on the purpose at hand. In some cases physical capital is defined to include inventories, software, land, and other inputs that extend beyond plant and equipment. Public capital is often lumped together with private capital as if they are close substitutes. Chapter 3 argues that it makes more sense to treat them as complementary inputs.

  2. 2.

    You can think of the value of rt as actually determined in period t−1. In that period households make their saving decision based on the firms’ commitments to rent capital in period t and pay the rental rate rt. In other words, rt is determined in period t−1 based on the savings behavior of households and the planned investment demands of firms.

  3. 3.

    The economy never literally reaches the steady state, although it will get arbitrarily close.

  4. 4.

    The weakening effect of the capital-labor ratio on wages, stems from the diminishing marginal product of capital. As capital accumulates relative to labor, the effect of further capital accumulation on output and wages gets smaller. Formally, note that the effect of an increase in k on the marginal product of labor is (1 − α)αAkα−1 = (1 − αmarginal product of capital.

  5. 5.

    There are differences of opinion about what qualifies as an appropriate target. Some believe that calibration should not involve previous econometric estimation. According to this view, all parameters within a model should be set to match particular data points or statistical moments of a data set (sample means, variances, and covariances), but not to match econometric estimates found in the literature. Others broaden the targets to include previous statistical estimates of the model’s parameters and behavioral responses, even if the model used in the estimation is not the same as the one used in the calibration . We are comfortable with either approach. The important point from our perspective is that all quantitative models, however calibrated, should be tested by comparing their predictions against observations or statistics not used in the calibration process. The fact that these “tests” or comparisons are not as formal and refined as traditional hypothesis testing in statistics does not particularly concern us. At this stage in the profession’s understanding of macroeconomics, models that even roughly approximate reality are difficult to find. Hopefully, as our approximations become more refined, we will need to worry about more formal testing procedure.

  6. 6.

    For a further discussion of the issues associated with quantifying overlapping generations models see Appendix B.

  7. 7.

    One can think of the financing of public school expenditures as coming from a tax on capital or capital income (similar to the property tax used to finance schooling in the U.S.). When σ = 1, as with our log preferences, a capital tax has no effect on saving and the transition equation.

  8. 8.

    Note that the acquisition of financial assets occurs in the first period of adulthood and the financial transfers are made in the second period of adulthood. Thus, the transfers are made when both generations are alive. Transfers of this type are called inter vivos transfers, as opposed to bequests that are transferred at death. In our model, where we assume (i) perfect certainty, (ii) perfect life-cycle credit markets, and (iii) no strategic interactions between generations, the timing of financial transfers is irrelevant. However, the timing of transfers can matter when these conditions are not met (see for example, Bernheim et al. (1985) and Cox 1987).

  9. 9.

    In microeconomics, the maximum attainable utility function is called an indirect utility function. In the pure life cycle version of our model, with no altruism , an indirect utility function is easily obtained. Take the optimal consumption choices of the household (5) and substitute them back into the CES utility function. For example, if we do this for the case of σ = 1, we get the very simple indirect utility function \( {U}_t^{\ast }=\beta \ln \beta +\left(1+\beta \right)\ln \frac{1}{1+\beta }+\left(1+\beta \right)\ln {w}_t+\beta \ln {R}_t \). With altruism, things are not nearly so simple. This is because generation-t’s utility depends on generation-t+1’s utility, which depends on generation-t + 2’s utility, and so on. As we shall see, in this case Vt cannot be found directly. Instead it is implicitly defined by a difference equation in the function Vt— what is known as a Bellman equation . In this case, Vt is called a value function and solving for this function is tricky business. Stokey and Lucas (1989) provide a general discussion of the conditions under which the value function exists, is unique, and is differentiable with respect to initial wealth.

  10. 10.

    Often, when the focus of the analysis is on intergenerational transfers, the life-cycle feature of the model is dropped. Households are modeled as living only a single period of adulthood in which they consume and make transfers to their children. We will see examples of these models in future chapters.

References

  • Abel A (1985) Precautionary saving and accidental bequests. American economic review 75(4):777–791.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D (2009) Introduction to modern economic growth. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey.

    Google Scholar 

  • Altonji J, Hayshi F, Kotlikoff L (1997) Parental altruism and inter vivos transfers: Theory and evidence. Journal of political economy 105(6):1121–1166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach A, Kotlikoff L (1998) Macroeconomics: An integrated approach. MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

    Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach A, Kotlikoff L, Skinner J (1983) The efficiency gains from dynamic tax reform. International economic review 24(1):81–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azariadis C (1993) Intertemporal macroeconomics. Blackwell, Oxford, UK.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro R (1974) Are government bonds net wealth? Journal of political economy 82(6):1095–1118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro R (1997) Macroeconomics. MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker G (1974) A theory of social interactions. Journal of political economy 82(6):1063–1094.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker G (1981) A treatise on the family. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker G (1988) Family economics and macro behavior. American economic review 78(1):1–13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim D, Shleifer A, Summers L (1985) The strategic bequest motive. Journal of political economy 93(6):1045–1076.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Córdoba J, Ripoll M (2013) What explains schooling differences across countries? Journal of monetary economics 60(2):184–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox D (1987) Motives for private income transfers. Journal of political economy 95(3):508–546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davies J (1981) Uncertain lifetime, consumption and dissaving in retirement. Journal of political economy 89(3):561–577.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Croix D, MP (2002) A theory of economic growth. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond P (1965) National debt in a neoclassical growth model. American economic review 55(5):1126–1150.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drazen A (1978) Government debt, human capital, and bequests in a life-cycle model. Journal of political economy 86(3):505–516.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farmer K, Schelnast M (2013) Growth and international trade: An introduction to the overlapping generations approach. Springer-Verlag, Berlin.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gollin D (2002) Getting income shares right. Journal of political economy 110(2): 458–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen L, Heckman J (1996) The empirical foundations of calibration. Journal of economic perspectives 10(1):87–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J, Cunha F (2007) The technology of skill formation. American economic review 97(2):31–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hurd M (1989) Mortality risk and bequests. Econometrica 57(4):779–813.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King R, Rebelo S (1993) Transitional dynamics and economic growth in the neoclassical growth model. American economic review 83:908–931.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kocherlakota N (1996) The equity premium: It’s still a puzzle. Journal of economic literature 34(1):42–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kydland F, Prescott E (1982) Time to build and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 50(6): 1345–1370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kydland F, Prescott E (1996) The computational experiment: An econometric tool. Journal of economic perspectives 10(1):69–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lord W (2001) Household dynamics, policies, and economic growth. Oxford University Press, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lord W, Rangazas P (2006) Fertility and development: The roles of schooling and family production. Journal of economic growth 11(3):229–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manuelli R, Seshadri A (2014) Human capital and the wealth of nations. American economic review 104 (9):2736–2762.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mourmouras A, Rangazas P (2009) Reconciling Kuznets and Habbakuk in a unified growth model. Journal of economic growth 14(2):149–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parente S, Prescott E (2000) Barriers to riches. MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rangazas P (2000) Schooling and economic growth: A King-Rebelo experiment with human capital. Journal of monetary economics 46(2):397–416.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rangazas P (2002) The quantity and quality of schooling and U.S. labor productivity growth (1870–2000). Review of economic dynamics 5(4): 932–964.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer D (2001) Advanced macroeconomics. McGraw-Hill, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stokey N, Lucas R (1989) Recursive methods in economic dynamics. Harvard University Press, Cambridge Mass.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Stokey N, Rebelo S (1995) Growth effects of flat-rate taxes. Journal of political economy 103(3):519–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Summers L (1981) Capital taxation and capital accumulation in a life-cycle growth model. American economic review 71(4):533–544.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallis J (2000) American government finance in the long-run: 1790 to 1990. Journal of economic perspectives 14(1):61–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilhelm M (1996) Bequest behavior and the effect of heirs’ earnings: Testing the altruistic model of bequests. American economic review 86(4):874–92.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A—Derivative of the Value Function

Substituting (2.22a, 2.22b) back into Ut gives

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}{U}_t=\frac{{\left[{\Psi}_{1t}\left({W}_t-n\left({x}_t+{b}_{t+1}\right)\right)\right]}^{1-1/\sigma }}{1-1/\sigma }+\beta \frac{{\left[{\left(\beta {R}_t\right)}^{\sigma }{\Psi}_{1t}\left({W}_t-n\left({x}_t+{b}_{t+1}\right)\right)\right]}^{1-1/\sigma }}{1-1/\sigma}\\ {}={\Psi}_{1t}^{-1/\sigma}\frac{{\left({W}_t-n\left({x}_t+{b}_{t+1}\right)\right)}^{1-1/\sigma }}{1-1/\sigma }.\end{array}} $$

Next, denote the optimal choices of the intergenerational transfers with an asterisk so that we can write

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{ll}{V}_t\left({W}_t\right)=& {\Psi}_{1t}^{-1/\sigma}\frac{{\left({W}_t-n\left({x}_t^{\ast }+{b}_{t+1}^{\ast}\right)\right)}^{1-1/\sigma }}{1-1/\sigma}\\ {}& +\beta {V}_{t+1}\left({W}_{t+1}H\left({x}_t^{\ast}\right)+\left(1+{r}_{t+1}\right){b}_{t+1}^{\ast}\right).\end{array}} $$

Note that the optimal intergenerational transfers are in general functions of Wt (in the constrained-case, financial transfers are zero and thus do not depend on Wt). However, because the derivative of the right-hand-side with respect to these choices is zero, then we may ignore these indirect effects of Wt when differentiating Vt with respect to Wt (in the constrained-case, the derivative is taken only with respect to human capital investments). Thus, the derivative of the value function with respect to Wt includes only the direct effect, working through Ut in the first expression above. This result is a general one, and is known as the envelope theorem. Equation (2.24) is the envelope theorem applied to Vt+1(Wt+1).

1.2 B—Many-Period Models

In models that extend beyond two periods, it is easier to proceed by thinking of the equilibrium or market clearing condition in terms of goods rather than capital. The two ways of thinking about things are actually equivalent, but the exposition is easier if we conduct the discussion in terms of goods (see Problem 23). This is especially true if one wants to contrast the infinitely-lived agent approach with the overlapping generations’ approach. To reduce notation, we will limit the discussion to the simple model of physical capital accumulation with no human capital or technical progress . In addition, the key points can be made for the case with σ = 1.

As shown in Problem 23, using the goods market approach allows the transition equation for the economy to be written as

$$ {nk}_{t+1}={Ak}_t^{\alpha }-\left(1-\delta \right){k}_t-\frac{C_t}{M_t}. $$

In the overlapping-generations model with two period lifetimes, this equation reduces nicely to a first-order difference equation (Problem 23). This is because the right-hand-side can be reduced to the consumption behavior of a single generation whose consumption depends only on period-t wages and thus only on kt. The old generation consumes all its income. As a result, their income and their consumption are equal and cancel from the right-hand-side of the transition equation.

However, with more periods of life there will be more generations on the right-hand-side, whose income is less than their consumption, i.e. who save by purchasing capital. The consumption behavior of these generations will depend on wages earned before period-t. For example, think of a model with five periods of life—four working periods and one retirement period. The aggregate consumption behavior on the right-side sums over five different generations. In general, it is only the generation who is retired that will “cancel out.” The saving of other generations will generally not be zero, so all variables that affect their consumption behavior will appear in the transition equation.

Consider the next oldest generation, who is in the last period of its working life. This generation’s working life began three periods ago. Their consumption behavior in period-t will depend on the wages they earned in each of those periods. Thus, wages as far back at period t−3 will appear in the transition equation. The wages in each period are determined by the capital-labor ratio from that period. This implies that the transition equation will be a fifth-order difference equation, including the variables, kt+1, kt, kt−1, kt−2, kt−3. The important point is that the state variables, here the capital-labor ratios, characterizing the economy increase as the number of periods of the life-cycle increase. This curse of dimensionality raises the computational complexity of the model when the number of periods in the life-cycle is large.

In contrast, if one assumes that the generations are linked by intergenerational financial transfers, the transition equation of the economy is a second order difference equation , no matter how many periods in the life-cycle are included. To see this, first note that as long as financial intergenerational transfers link the generations together, then we can write Ct = κNt c1t (see Problem 21). As periods in the life-cycle are added, only the value of κ changes. For example, κ = 2, with two periods of life, and κ = 5, if there are five periods of life.

Next, solve for c1t using the goods-market version of the transition equation to get

$$ {c}_{1t}=\frac{M_t}{N_t\kappa}\left[{Ak}_t^{\alpha }-\left(1-\delta \right){k}_t-{nk}_{t+1}\right]. $$

Now substitute into (2.25b) to get

$$ \left[{Ak}_{t+1}^{\alpha }-\left(1-\delta \right){k}_{t+1}-{nk}_{t+2}\right]=\left[\frac{\beta \left(1+\alpha {Ak}_{t+1}^{\alpha -1}-\delta \right)}{n}\right]\left[{Ak}_t^{\alpha }-\left(1-\delta \right){k}_t-{nk}_{t+1}\right], $$

This is a second-order difference equation in kt that is completely independent of the number of periods in the life-cycle. Thus, the infinitely-lived agent simplification is able to avoid the dreaded curse of dimensionality. A very nifty and useful result.

The lesson is that if you want to do computations, use the infinitely-lived agent approach whenever you can get away with it (e.g. business cycle analysis). Unfortunately, the evidence suggests that for the issues we examine in this book, those that directly focus on private intergenerational transfers and government policies that transfer resources across generations, one must stick with the overlapping generations approach.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer International Publishing AG, part of Springer Nature

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Das, S., Mourmouras, A., Rangazas, P. (2018). Overlapping-Generations Model of Economic Growth. In: Economic Growth and Development. Springer Texts in Business and Economics. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-89755-4_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics