Keywords

In this chapter, we discuss the institutions that the previous literature identifies as the most relevant for nurturing the activities of entrepreneurs and other actors in the ecosystem’s skill structure. The starting point for this discussion can be labeled the first-best perspective, according to which some institutions or institutional forms are simply the most propitious for entrepreneurship and economic growth. This perspective has rightfully been criticized as too simplistic (Rodrik 2008). McCloskey (2016) quips that it essentially amounts to the idea that one should “add institutions and stir”. Hence, we recognize the need to complement it with insights offered by the EOE and the VoC perspectives discussed in the previous chapter.

Previous research suggests that (innovation-based and high-impact) entrepreneurship has numerous important prerequisites, such as an educated workforce (Béchard and Grégoire 2005; Kuratko 2005), a well-functioning labor market (Poschke 2013), and a tax system that favors work, investment and entrepreneurial effort (Cullen and Gordon 2007). Giving a complete overview of the large empirical literature that identifies the effect of various institutions and policies on the rate of entrepreneurial activity is beyond the scope of this chapter. However, it is important to make several points clarifying the extent to which policies and institutions (both formal and informal) interact with and reinforce one another. In what follows, we will highlight what we consider to be the most pertinent institutions and policies that determine the extent to which a productive entrepreneurial economy is fostered.

3.1 The Rule of Law and Protection of Property Rights

3.1.1 Preamble

The legal principle that a polity should not be governed by arbitrary decisions made by autocratic rulers or government officials is central to any country striving for prosperity. Likewise, private property rights—the existence of legal titles to hold property and the protection thereof—is arguably the most fundamental of all economic institutions (North and Weingast 1989; Libecap 1993; Acemoglu et al. 2001; Baumol 2002; Rodrik et al. 2004; Acemoglu and Johnson 2005; Besley and Ghatak 2010) and relevant for all actors in the ecosystem’s skill structure. Secure property rights ensure that physical objects can be turned into capital (De Soto 2000), a transformation that requires judgment, imagination, and innovation. Without control over assets and their returns, a potential entrepreneur will lack the incentive to innovate, but what matters is de facto control; formal property rights which do not offer control rights in practice are useless, while the absence of formal property rights need not be prohibitive if control rights are sufficiently strong (Rodrik 2007). However, entrepreneurs in countries with weak property rights are generally discouraged from (re)investing (retained) earnings in their ventures; see Johnson et al. (2002). The division and specialization of labor are also hampered, which narrows the range of potential entrepreneurial discoveries.

If the protection of property rights is too weak, destructive entrepreneurship, such as extortion and corruption, is likely to flourish. Organized crime syndicates such as the mafia are often innovative in their response to shortcomings in the legal enforcement framework and pursue entrepreneurship as a substitute for absent or maladaptive public institutions.Footnote 1 There are also instances in which innovativeness and entrepreneurship may suffer from overly strong property rights protections (Gans and Persson 2013). An important contemporary example is intellectual property rights protection, which has been strengthened in recent years in ways that are arguably too protective, most notably in the United States, increasing both the cost and risk associated with innovative activity (Jaffe and Lerner 2004; Cohen 2005; Acs and Sanders 2012).

In practice, one must strike a difficult compromise within the legal system. On the one hand, if protection is too weak or can be circumvented too easily (through unproductive or destructive entrepreneurship), there is no incentive to introduce innovations in the first place (Merrill et al. 2004; Acs and Szerb 2007; Baumol et al. 2007; Kauffman Foundation 2007). On the other hand, if protection is overly strong—if its time frame is too long or if it is too easy to obtain even for inventions that are not truly novel—the original innovator will be able to extract excessive monopoly rents, making the economy less competitive and less innovative.

3.1.2 Reform Agenda

Although no country in the world can pride itself on having perfected the rule of law, cross-country differences are substantial. As presented in column 1 of Table 3.1, this is also true among EU countries. The former Soviet-bloc countries score especially low on the rule of law, but this is also true for Greece and Italy and, to a slightly lesser extent, for Spain and Portugal. The top countries are the Nordic, Anglo-Saxon and Benelux nations. These are also the wealthiest EU countries. The second column of the table reveals large differences in terms of the security of property rights as well, and the order of countries is quite similar to the order for the rule of law.

Table 3.1 The rule of law and the quality of government: four indicators for the EU member countries and the United States

For citizens and economic agents to reap the full benefits of the rule of law, the laws and regulations in question must be of high quality, and the government must be sufficiently effective in maintaining the rule of law. The third and fourth indicators in Table 3.1 show that the differences across EU countries are large in these respects as well. However, it is noteworthy that the quality of the laws and regulations in the laggard countries tend to be higher than the government’s effectiveness at enforcing compliance. Arguably, this is not surprising. Adopting the right laws is easier than enforcing them effectively. Furthermore, EU law compels countries to do the former but has far less clout to enforce or ensure the latter.

Regarding the rule of law, the efficiency of government, and the protection of property rights we see no alternative for the laggard countries but to do their utmost to converge towards the level of the best-performing countries. Deficiencies in these factors negatively impact all agents in the ecosystem’s skill structure and induce people to conduct activities and keep their capital in the shadow economy. Even the poorest EU member countries are higher medium-income countries, and neither the VoC literature nor arguments à la Rodrik (2008) provide any support for the view that these countries can compensate for these deficiencies through other institutional measures.

3.2 Taxation

3.2.1 Preamble

The design of the tax system affects the net return to entrepreneurship both directly and indirectly; it also affects the prevalence and activities of the other actors in the ecosystem’s skill structure. The tax system determines a potential entrepreneur’s risk-reward profile and, consequently, his or her incentives for undertaking entrepreneurial activities. The literature has consistently found that the self-employed are more responsive to taxes than employees (e.g., Carroll et al. 2000; Rosen 2005; Heim 2010; Chetty et al. 2011; Harju and Kosonen 2013; Alstadsæter et al. 2014; Kleven and Schultz 2014). The elasticity of taxable income is far higher for the self-employed than for employees, which implies that higher taxes reduce the supply of taxable income due to a combination of real effects and tax reporting. However, the effects are often complex and sometimes counterintuitive. From a theoretical point of view, we will focus on two main ways in which the tax system affects entrepreneurial activity.Footnote 2

The first is an absolute effect that influences the supply and effort of potential entrepreneurs in the economy, as an absolute increase in the taxation of entrepreneurs lowers the (expected) after-tax reward. It also makes expansion financed by retained earnings more difficult and negatively affects the liquidity position of entrepreneurs. In sum, the absolute effect serves to frustrate entrepreneurial activities and impedes the emergence of new startups and the expansion of firms. The second is a relative effect that influences an individual’s choice of occupation and organizational form by altering the relative returns for different activities if the tax favors one form of economic activity over another; thus, a higher tax rate may encourage income shifting and may positively influence (some forms of) entrepreneurship in the economy. A relative effect also occurs if the tax system favors certain forms of savings and investments. To the extent that the optimal financing and ownership structures differ across industries, firm type and firm age, such non-neutralities affect incentives for entrepreneurship.Footnote 3

While analyzing taxes on entrepreneurial income directly would be preferable, such an analysis is complicated by the fact that no specific tax on income from entrepreneurial effort exists in practice. Rather, this income is taxed in several different forms, notably as labor income, business income, current capital income (dividends and interest), or capital gains. These taxes may affect entrepreneurial activities differently. A thorough analysis of the effects of taxation on entrepreneurship must disentangle these effects, and we do so by enumerating and discussing what we deem to be the key characteristics of a tax system favoring innovative entrepreneurship and the ecosystem’s skill structure.

Regarding corporate taxation, a high tax rate on business profits discourages equity financing and encourages debt financing if interest costs are tax-deductible (Desai et al. 2003; Huizinga et al. 2008). To the extent that debt financing is less costly and more readily available to larger firms, high corporate tax rates coupled with tax-deductible interest payments disadvantage smaller firms and potential entrepreneurs (Davis and Henrekson 1999). Taxing corporate profits also reduces the retained earnings that can be used to expand the existing venture. Consequently, taxing profits in small firms often leads to lower growth rates (Michaelas et al. 1999).

A high tax rate on dividends encourages a reliance on retained earnings to finance expansion. Such a tax rate punishes new ventures, locks in retained earnings, and traps capital in incumbent firms. Therefore, a high tax rate on dividends obstructs the flow of capital to the most promising projects because it favors incumbent ventures (Chetty and Saez 2005). Most of the economic return from successful high-impact entrepreneurial firms accrues to owners in the form of a dramatically increased value of their shares rather than as dividends or large interest payments to the owners. Thus, the taxation of capital gains on stock holdings greatly affects the incentives of potential high-impact entrepreneurs and their (equity) financiers (Cumming 2005; Da Rin et al. 2006).

Employee stock options are the equivalent of promises of future ownership stakes in the firm, which will be realized if the firm develops according to plan and manages to achieve the prescribed objectives for value creation. The granting of stock options can also be substituted for high wages to moderate costs at the beginning of the lifecycle (Gompers and Lerner 2001; Bengtsson and Hand 2013). Stock options can thus be used to encourage and reward individuals who supply key competencies to a firm—the competent employees in the ecosystem’s skill structure. In ideal circumstances, stock options provide incentives that closely mimic direct ownership, but their productivity greatly depends on the tax code. If gains on stock options are taxed as wage income, some of the incentive effect is lost—particularly if the gains are subject to (uncapped) social security contributions and the marginal tax rate on wage income is high. The situation changes dramatically if an employee with stock options can defer the tax liability until the stocks are eventually sold. The effectiveness of these stock options is further reinforced if the employee suffers no tax consequences from the granting or exercise of the option, and if the employee is taxed at a low capital gains rate when the acquired stock is sold (Gilson and Schizer 2003).

The level and progressivity of labor taxation (including mandatory social security contributions) also affect employees directly by determining the incentives for work effort, labor supply (on the extensive and intensive margin), occupational choice, career aspirations, and the propensity to upgrade and learn new skills (Rosen 1983). Most obviously, high and progressive labor taxes lower the rate of return on highly productive skills, and are therefore likely to impair the supply of skilled workers.Footnote 4 They also slow restructuring and the reallocation of people across firms since it becomes costlier to achieve the net wage differential necessary to induce a person to leave their current employment. Hence, high taxation of labor income affects several of the categories in the skill structure, especially competent employees and entrepreneurs. Of course, the supply of competent employees is also affected by the tax incentives to acquire an adequate education, a question to which we will return in Sect. 3.8.Footnote 5

Regarding the role of venture capitalists in the ecosystem’s skill structure, we should note that the tax systems of many countries evolved before the emergence of complicated ownership structures involving private equity financing, such as venture capital (VC) and buyout firms.Footnote 6 Sophisticated mechanisms were initially needed to provide high-powered incentives for many actors in addition to the final equity holders. In fact, the modern VC industry in the U.S. could not evolve until the tax system was changed in key respects. Sharp reductions in the capital gains tax and legislation pertaining to stock options around 1980 allowed the tax liability to be deferred until stocks were sold rather than when the options were exercised. Additionally, new legislation in 1979 allowed pension funds to invest in high-risk securities that were issued by small or new companies and VC funds (Misher 1984; Fenn et al. 1995).

We should emphasize here that important complementarities exist between different tax rates. For example, the low effective taxation of gains on employee stock options appears to be necessary to develop a large VC sector. In addition, when channeling institutional capital into the entrepreneurial startup sector, finding efficient substitutes for VC firms is difficult. Overall, to calculate the total effect of taxation, one must consider the specific rules for depreciation and valuation in corporate taxation and the taxation of interest income, dividends, capital gains, and wealth. The effective total tax rate also depends on the ownership category. In many developed countries, business ownership stakes that are directly held by individuals and families have been taxed more heavily than other ownership stakes. The wave of tax reforms that swept the OECD in the 1980s reduced many of these differences, but those that remain provoke an endogenous response in the ownership structure of the business sector to the tax-favored owner categories (Rydqvist et al. 2014). If individual stock holdings are disfavored relative to institutional holdings and if institutional investors are less willing to invest in small and new entrepreneurial projects, entrepreneurial activity will be discouraged.

3.2.2 Reform Agenda

In line with the general argument articulated in Sect. 2.2, our contention is that the tax system should strive for as much simplicity as possible rather than addressing shortcomings by granting exceptions and tax breaks for specific ownership types or industries. Tax breaks are often instituted for good reasons, and they may very well appear justified when analyzed in isolation. However, they create complexities with numerous drawbacks. First, they are vulnerable to tax-driven business models that are legal but not in line with the spirit of the concession in question. Moreover, highly complex systems lack in salience. For example, if economic actors can realize a lower effective taxation than the statutory one, it becomes more difficult to achieve the behavioral effects that policymakers would like to see (Chetty et al. 2009).

3.2.2.1 Taxation of Labor Income

As shown in the first column of Table 3.2, the highest marginal tax rates differ greatly across the European Union—spanning from 16% in Hungary to 57% in Sweden. However, the highest marginal tax rate is not necessarily the most relevant measure. One should also examine the total marginal tax wedge, which is defined as the share of total labor cost at the margin and consists of the sum of mandatory social security contributions paid by the employer and/or the employee and the marginal income tax rate. This is performed for different relevant family constellations in columns 2–4 of Table 3.2. In a country like Belgium, as much as two-thirds of total labor cost consists of income taxes and social security contributions, while the share in Poland is only about half as large.

Table 3.2 Top marginal tax rate on labor income, and marginal rate of income tax plus employee and employer contributions less cash benefits (tax wedge), 2015

Institutional complementarity can enable a country to tax labor income more heavily without suffering from increased distortionary effects. Most importantly, high labor taxation has less detrimental effects if access to valuable subsidies in cash or in-kind (e.g., child care and pension rights) is tied to employment and if each spouse’s income is taxed separately rather than jointly (Lindbeck 1982). The importance of the latter effect becomes obvious when comparing the third and fourth columns in Table 3.2 for Belgium and Sweden.

In fact, as mentioned (and as shown in Fig. 2.2 in Sect. 2.1), Sweden has the highest employment rate in the entire EU, but this does not mean that its excessive taxation of high incomes is costless. In fact, a reform to remove taxations of the highest income levels in Sweden would probably more than finance itself (Sørensen 2010). As it stands, these taxes can be expected to have deleterious effects, particularly in the most advanced parts of the economy. In all likelihood, Sweden is successful in employment terms despite rather than because of its high labor taxes, which can only be borne because of the overall quality of the institutional environment. Countries with poorer institutional quality should therefore not see Sweden as a role model in this respect. Poor countries that would like to increase their tax revenue must begin by improving the quality of their basic institutions.

Labor income is taxed at low rates in most Eastern European countries. Nonetheless, these countries have large underground economies, while the employment rate is low, as is the rate of improvement-driven opportunity entrepreneurship. This strongly suggests that factors other than high taxes on labor are binding constraints for this cluster of countries. The situation is different for several of the Mediterranean countries; they also suffer from low employment and entrepreneurship, whereas the underground economy tends to be large. In these countries, as well as in Belgium and France, labor taxation is a clear impediment. Reform is therefore needed to combine lower labor taxes with a stricter coupling of subsidies, such as child care and pension rights, to employment. The latter issues will be addressed in Sect. 3.4.

3.2.2.2 Taxation of Corporate Income

As shown in Fig. 3.1, there are large differences across EU countries in the statutory corporate tax rate, ranging from 34% in France to 12.5% in Ireland. In the case of corporate taxation, we see no reason for the European Union to strive for convergence across EU countries. In this case, healthy institutional competition among member countries is preferred.

Fig. 3.1
figure 1

The statutory corporate tax rate in EU countries and the U.S., 2016. Source OECD and Eurostat.

This does not preclude an important role for the European Union. First, the Union must be adamant about ending blatant institutional arbitrage and sweetheart deals negotiated between national governments and large multinational corporations. Additionally, the Union should strive to reduce and ideally remove the discrepancies in member countries between statutory and effective corporate income tax rates, which may result from tax-reducing depreciation rules, inventory valuation rules or other more ad hoc country- or industry-specific tax reductions. Their removal would create transparency and contribute to leveling the playing field for all firms regardless of their size, industry or nationality. Competition among member states is good, but it should be competition on corporate tax rates and not on complex, opaque fiscal deals and schemes. Member states should treat all firms equally.

3.2.2.3 Taxation of Dividends and Capital Gains

The return on entrepreneurship largely accrues in the form of dividends and capital gains from ownership stakes in the firm. The standard tax rates on dividends and capital gains among EU countries and the United States are given in Appendix Table A.1 and reveal major differences. More importantly, there are country-specific, highly idiosyncratic divergences from these standard rates. These divergences depend on factors such as the holding period, the size of the firm, whether the firm is private or public (i.e., traded on a stock exchange), whether a person is an active or passive owner, whether the firm and/or the investor qualifies for inclusion in a tax-favored scheme (e.g., a scheme geared towards encouraging innovative startup activity), and the tax status of the body (a physical or a juridical person, etc.) receiving the capital income.

As exemplified by Grant (2016), such differences can be huge and vary substantially across countries. In Sweden, the dividend and capital gains tax rates can vary between 20 and 60% for physical persons depending on circumstances, whereas the Irish dividend tax rate varies between 20 and 40% and the Irish capital gains tax rate can be reduced from 33% to zero under certain conditions.Footnote 7 On the other hand, the variation is small in the Netherlands, Poland, and Estonia; in the latter country, dividends are taxed at 0% and capital gains at 20%.

The complexities should be removed when possible. Instead, countries should aim for dividend and capital gains tax rates with few exceptions and few (opaque) concessionary schemes. Here, the Eastern European countries, such as Poland and Estonia, have exemplary models in which the tax rates are at reasonable levels and the effective tax rate is largely independent of other circumstances. Arguably, the reason for this clarity is that the design of these systems date back no further than 1989. A radical redesign from the ground up is probably not feasible in older member states, but they should nevertheless strive for similar improvements to simplicity and transparency.

3.2.2.4 Taxation of Stock Options

Observations from the history of the American VC sector indicates that stock options are widely used when they are advantageous from a tax perspective. The contractual design of financial instruments constitutes a good fit for the issues facing the VC-funded entrepreneurial sector. Therefore, the effective tax treatment of option contracts may in itself be a major determinant to the size of the VC-funded entrepreneurial sector. Henrekson and Sanandaji (2016a) calculate the effective tax rate on stock options in various countries given a typical scenario. The tax rates for the EU countries included in their study as well as those for the United States and Hong Kong are presented in Table 3.3, revealing a large variation in tax rates. The VC sector is extremely small in most countries where the tax rate is very high, as will become clear in the next section (see Table 3.4, in particular), while the low-tax countries (Hong Kong and the United States) have a large and highly dynamic VC sector.

Table 3.3 Effective tax rate on stock options in selected European countries, the U.S., and Hong Kong, 2012
Table 3.4 Venture capital investments as a share of GDP, and the ease of getting credit in EU countries and the U.S., 2015

Lowered taxation of gains on employee stock options in the startup sector is likely to be necessary in many countries, both to lure talented people away from traditional careers in incumbent firms and to channel institutional capital into the entrepreneurial sector, which should be mediated by a professional VC sector. This policy would narrowly target the entrepreneurial sector rather than entail broad tax cuts (Gilson and Schizer 2003) if designed to apply only to startups receiving VC-funding, a small but strategic sector of the economy. The policy lowers the effective taxation of startups that are screened by venture capitalists willing to invest their own funds without requiring the government to determine which firms are entrepreneurial. Innovative startups can then be favored without needing broad capital gains tax cuts.Footnote 8 A tax break that targets human capital in this segment would promote innovative entrepreneurship without the high fiscal cost of broad capital gains tax cuts. Moreover, broad-based capital gains tax cuts do not shift capital from passive investments to private equity, unlike tax breaks on stock options and other instruments used by the VC sector.

3.3 Regulations Governing Savings, Capital and Finance

3.3.1 Preamble

A high savings rate in a country does not guarantee the availability of financing for innovative and growth-oriented entrepreneurship, especially not in the early, precarious phase of the firm’s lifecycle. In fact, some of the countries with the highest savings rates are the least entrepreneurial, whereas the United States has a notoriously low savings rate and a vibrant entrepreneurial sector. The composition of savings—not just its volume—also sways potential entrepreneurship activity in the economy. As we have already demonstrated, entrepreneurial activity hinges on accessing and raising the right kind of capital.

Numerous studies reveal that a lack of access to capital is the most significant obstacle for many business ventures (e.g., van Auken 1999 and Parker 2009). In the EU, entrepreneurs and SMEs rank financing as their second most important concern after administrative burdens (European Commission 2008), and the highly developed financial system of the United States has indeed been cited as a central reason for the emergence of its successful entrepreneurial economy (Kauffman Foundation 2007, p. 34). However, many startups do not require much capital, and financial constraints are therefore not much of a problem (Hurst and Lusardi 2004; Shane 2008, p. 79). Advances in ICT have reduced minimum capital requirements in many markets (Baumol et al. 2007, p. 236). As it stands, capital tends to constrain high-growth firms more than other firms because they often require sizable infusions of external equity to sustain growth (Baumol et al. 2007, p. 205).

Notably, the success of a startup relies on its access to equity financing, a reliance which increases (relative to debt) with the degree of risk. Ceteris paribus, small and newly established firms are more dependent on equity financing than large, well-established firms since it is more difficult for outside financiers to assess the viability and profitability of the venture. Therefore, entrepreneurial startups usually struggle to raise funds from large financial institutions and are forced to rely on insider and internal funding in their infancy. Any arrangement that channels savings and asset control to large institutional investors is therefore likely to hamper the supply of financial capital to potential entrepreneurs.

By contrast, research strongly suggests that incentives for individual wealth accumulation would likely increase entrepreneurial activity (Nykvist 2008; Parker 2009). Wealth-constrained would-be entrepreneurs are unable to forcibly signal their project’s worth to outside investors by means of making sizeable equity infusions of their own. More private savings would lessen the inherent problem caused by such asymmetric information, and, if needed, enable entrepreneurs to fully finance the firm until organic growth based on retained earnings is possible. Furthermore, informal investors, such as business angels, may fill the gap between internal funding and formal VC financing (to varying degrees in different countries). Research shows that the presence of these informal investors is crucial in overcoming liquidity constraints (Ho and Wong 2007). The United Kingdom in particular has used tax relief and generous deductions to encourage business angel investments; see, e.g., Boyns et al. (2003) and Mason (2006).

Although the importance of the formal VC industry has increased over time, its presence is still rather modest in the EU (Bygrave and Hunt 2004; Lerner and Tåg 2013) with many entrepreneurial firms being too small for VC funding. However, venture capital is important for high-performing and high-growth entrepreneurial firms (Cumming 2012). It is often superior to bank finance since it also provides key expertise and access to networks that are important to entrepreneurial high-risk firms (Keuschnigg and Nielsen 2004a; Ho and Wong 2007). In this respect, it is troubling that the VC industry is less developed in Europe than in the U.S. (Bottazzi and Da Rin 2002; Da Rin et al. 2006), possibly because European business owners are less prone to accept a loss of control, which is a normal consequence of venture capital support (OECD 1998). It may be for this reason that U.S. firms grow faster than their European counterparts (Scarpetta et al. 2002; Henrekson and Sanandaji 2016a).

Appreciating the role of the VC industry in the entrepreneurial ecosystem also explains why governmental attempts to compensate for deficient private financing of innovative entrepreneurship—especially of the early-stage variety—are unlikely to be successful.Footnote 9 Any such support system must contain elements of rationing and selection in order to avoid the moral hazard problems of unmanageable proportions, and as emphasized in the discussion of targeted support in Sect. 2.2, no recipe exists that dictates how to “pick the winners” and support the right investments. By contrast, the process of evaluation in the private VC industry is highly complex and often includes tacit judgments. Granted, industry actors, despite their specialization, are at best moderately successful in picking the winners among high-risk projects (Gompers and Lerner 2004; Birch 2006; Svensson 2008; Gompers et al. 2009), but there is little empirical evidence to suggest that politically controlled organizations are better placed in this respect (Baumol et al. 2007, p. 220). Instead, such organizations might—directly or indirectly, openly or furtively, partly or completely—base their decisions on political rather than commercial criteria and therefore underperform.Footnote 10

Moreover, decision making by business angels and VC investors is often also a matter of judgment in which the criteria are largely tacit. To have public agencies use similar criteria does not mesh with the requirement of treating all citizens equally under the law. Finally, failure is an inherent part of entrepreneurship, and private investors consciously assume such risk. It is more difficult for elected politicians who handle taxpayers’ money to motivate such risk-taking and the inevitable losses in numerous projects.

3.3.2 Reform Agenda

As a long-term solution, the best way to ensure the financing of entrepreneurial firms is likely to be the pursuit of policies that encourage private wealth accumulation in forms that do not preclude the assets from being used as equity in entrepreneurial ventures.Footnote 11 However, there is currently a strong tendency to introduce or increase the use of funded pension systems both in the private and public sectors, and there is little reason to believe that this trend will be reversed. In Sweden, for example, collectively agreed supplementary pension schemes cover virtually all tenured employees with payments into those systems amounting to approximately 10% of taxable labor income (Riksbanken 2014; Svensk Försäkring 2015).Footnote 12 Total assets amount to some two-thirds of Swedish GDP and 130% of household disposable income. Aggregate pension fund assets as a share of GDP are especially large in the United Kingdom and the Netherlands, but they are also high in Ireland, Finland and Denmark, while they are still small in the Eastern European countries and in Germany, France and Italy (OECD 2015b).

Since a progressively larger share of savings goes into pension funds,Footnote 13 there is a growing need for at least part of these assets to be invested in entrepreneurial firms and not just in real estate, public stocks and high-rated bonds. Since large financial institutions can rarely invest directly in small and new firms, a bridging intermediating role must be provided by a professional VC sector, as discussed in Sect. 3.3.1. As revealed in the first column of Table 3.4,Footnote 14 the differences here are substantial across Europe, with Denmark and Luxembourg clearly leading, whereas the Eastern European and the Mediterranean countries for which there are data are located at the bottom.

Here, policymakers could be inspired by the U.S. experience of the 1970s and 1980s, and adopt a broad-based policy approach: an encouraging legal framework that combines tax cuts in capital gains with legislation allowing pension funds to invest in high-risk securities issued by small and new firms as well as VC funds (Gompers and Lerner 1999; cf. Keuschnigg and Nielsen 2004a, b). Additionally, as discussed in Sect. 3.2, effective tax treatments of options contracts are necessary to enable VC firms and other actors in the entrepreneurial ecosystem to design the appropriate incentive contracts for founders and other key personnel needed to build innovative firms (Henrekson and Rosenberg 2001). Without such opportunities, a sizeable and efficient VC sector cannot develop.

By contrast, debt financing is unlikely to be a viable alternative to external equity investments in the early entrepreneurial phase since such financing presupposes positive cash flows and low risk ventures—meaning that innovative entrepreneurship is not favored compared to activities with low risk and assets that can be collateralized. A comparison of the first and second column of Table 3.4 reveals that many of the countries with low scores on the size of external equity investment activity rank highly regarding the ease of getting credit (e.g., Romania, Hungary and Bulgaria). While some economies have traditionally been characterized as bank-centered—Germany being the archetypical case—this has changed profoundly over the last two decades. Bank lending is no longer a viable option for financing high-risk innovative entrepreneurship that does not occur within the boundaries of large firms. Thus, bank financing and monitoring is not a viable alternative to institutional reform that would pave the way for external equity investment.

Moreover, it is important to recognize that venture capitalists and other early-phase equity investors only are ownership specialists up to a certain point in the entrepreneurial ecosystem, since a highly successful entrepreneurial firm will reach a point at which it may be appropriate to sell the firm. That said, the existence of a viable market for corporate control later in the firm lifecycle matters for early-stage entrepreneurs, since this market affects the expected future value of embarking on an entrepreneurial venture (Norbäck and Persson 2009, 2012).

There are three principal ways in which an entrepreneurial exit can be done. The first is through a trade sale, i.e., being acquired by an incumbent firm that wants to gain access to new technologies and innovation (or just eliminate a future competitor), which is quite common in countries such as the Netherlands. The second way is by going public through an IPO, which is possible if there is a sizeable public stock market. The third way is by turning to buyout firms (the secondary market equivalent of VC firms). This option is contingent on the existence of a buyout sector through which pension savings can be channeled to the business sector in the form of equity investment. As shown in Table 3.5, there are large cross-country differences in the size of public stock markets and buyout sectors. These sectors are generally small in countries with small VC sectors and vice versa. Hence, they are quite large in the Anglo-Saxon countries, the Nordic countries, and the Netherlands, but small in Eastern Europe and the Mediterranean countries. This hints at strong complementarities between the early- and late-stage vehicles for corporate control and prompts us to look for underlying causes of the absence of these markets.

Table 3.5 Buyout investment and market capitalization as a percentage of GDP in EU countries and the U.S., 2015

One likely reason for small public stock markets is the weak protection of minority investors, but a more fundamental reason for underdevelopment in each of these areas is probably weak property rights protection, discussed in Sect. 3.1 (Levine 2005). Without such protection, no actors are likely to have sufficient incentives to take the risks required for successful corporate control and guidance at any stage of the firm lifecycle unless that agent has total control and owns 100% of the equity. Under such circumstances, pension savings and other institutional capital would be barred from access to ownership stakes in the corporate sector.

3.4 The Organization of Labor Markets and Social Insurance Systems

3.4.1 Preamble

Legislation and regulations pertaining to labor markets and wage setting influence incentives for entrepreneurship since contracting freedom becomes constrained. It therefore curtails possible combinations of factors of production and the best use of the various functions in the skill structure, notably those related to competent employees. Labor security mandates fall more heavily on younger, smaller, and less capital-intensive employers—categories in which entrepreneurial firms are overrepresented. Severance pay and strict regulations governing the order of dismissal in the case of redundancy are factors that keep entrepreneurs from adjusting their workforce in response to market fluctuations and changes in required skills, thereby increasing the risk of their projects (Audretsch et al. 2002). Such lack of flexibility may become detrimental to the overall economy, making it less adaptable to changes. In addition, labor market regulation can influence entrepreneurial activity by affecting the relative advantage of being an employee; far-reaching employment protection legislation increases an employee’s opportunity cost of changing employers or leaving a secure salaried job to become self-employed (Ho and Wong 2007; van Stel et al. 2007).

Less stringent legislation for temporary employment contracts would enable an important channel for job creation. However, from the ecosystem perspective, this is a second-best solution since staff on temporary contracts will be less motivated to invest in firm-specific skills and commit less strongly to the firm than employees on permanent contracts.Footnote 15 Thus, it becomes less likely that the firm will be able to attract workers who have highly valued skills or are inclined to develop such skills. Hence, a large discrepancy in the degree of protection between permanent and temporary contracts offers a comparative advantage to low-skill industries in which employees are highly substitutable. Such industries tend to be less innovative and have lower productivity.

Research has found that labor market regulations shape the level of nascent entrepreneurship more than differences in entry regulations, with the result that entrepreneurship is higher in countries in which hiring and dismissing employees is relatively easy and inexpensive (Niehof 1999; OECD 2003; van Stel et al. 2007). In addition, labor market deregulation can and has stimulated entrepreneurial activity in many OECD countries (OECD 1998, 2000). Europe’s stricter employment protection legislation may partly explain its lower frequency of new, rapidly growing firms relative to the United States (Baumol et al. 2007, p. 210 and 222).Footnote 16

The social security system is closely linked to the regime governing the labor market. Public income insurance systems in combination with strict labor security legislation tend to penalize individuals who assume entrepreneurial risk (Ilmakunnas and Kanniainen 2001). This is because these systems confer a relative advantage on employees with many social security benefits—such as disability, sickness, unemployment and pension benefits—being explicitly linked to formal employment. These benefits further increase the opportunity cost of leaving a tenured position as an employee and thus reduce the incentives for entrepreneurship (Audretsch et al. 2002).

Many are unwilling to forgo a large part of their social protection in exchange for an uncertain and volatile entrepreneurial income. Making parts of social insurance benefits “portable”—e.g., by decoupling health insurance—between jobs and between regular employment and self-employment would mitigate this effect. However, even if it were possible to “generalize” the social security system, the self-employed and owners/managers of small entrepreneurial firms would still be unable to make practical use of the full extent of the system’s benefits, such as those related to parental or sick leave.

Generous unemployment benefits naturally discourage the unemployed from becoming self-employed, and in countries in which the unemployed receive a high proportion of their former wage, the rate of new firm formation is lower (Nickell 1997; Delmar et al. 2005; Koellinger and Minniti 2009). However, as already noted in Sect. 2.1, going from unemployment to self-employment is oftentimes a form of necessity entrepreneurship, which is unlikely to have many positive economic effects.

3.4.2 Reform Agenda

3.4.2.1 Employment Protection Legislation

Figure 3.2 shows the stringency of employment protection legislation (EPL) in the EU countries and in the United States for temporary contracts (y-axis) and permanent contracts (x-axis). The two measures reveal considerable positive correlation (r = 0.46). The Anglo-Saxon countries stand out as having the least stringent EPL by far, even though most other countries have liberalized their legislation for permanent employment in recent decades (Skedinger 2010; Martin and Scarpetta 2012). For temporary contracts, Sweden and Germany stand out for their substantial liberalization over the past 20 years; notably, these are two of the top-performing EU countries in terms of employment (see Fig. 2.2). They also rank among the countries with the highest share of temporary employment. In Sweden, as much as 56% of employed 15–24-year-olds were on temporary contracts in 2015 (OECD 2016).

Fig. 3.2
figure 2

Stringency of employment protection legislation for workers on permanent and temporary contracts in EU countries and the U.S., 2013. Note The scale of the index is 0–6, where 6 represents the most stringent regulation. 2013 is the latest available year. The index for permanent employment is the index for individual and permanent dismissals. Source OECD/IAB Employment Protection Database, 2013 update

The Mediterranean countries (Portugal, Italy, Spain and Greece) have also liberalized their temporary employment legislation, and even though it remains comparatively stringent, the share of employed 15–24-year olds on temporary contracts is above 50% in all those nations except Greece (OECD 2016). By contrast, all Eastern European countries have increased the stringency of their legislation related to temporary contracts, which is noteworthy given their generally weak employment performance. Overall, legislation with respect to both types of contracts remains quite strict in most Mediterranean and Continental European countries.

Policymakers in several European countries are aware that the EPL may be too stringent; to mitigate the negative effect, they have instituted firm-size thresholds below which labor regulations are less onerous. Again, such a policy of exceptions can be criticized on neutrality grounds since, in practice, this is the equivalent of a tax on firm growth. Indeed, it has been revealed that firms are reluctant to grow beyond the size threshold in Germany (Autio et al. 2007), France (Garicano et al. 2016), Portugal (Braguinsky et al. 2011), and Italy (Schivardi and Torrini 2008).Footnote 17 Thus, firms are incentivized to remain small, and many entrepreneurs will never discover that they could have become high-impact entrepreneurs because they do not even try. That said, stringent employment regulations may create strong incentives for actors in the skill structure to devise arrangements to circumvent the regulations. Important symptoms of such attempts to create flexibility in several European countries include increased self-employment, the emergence of an underground economy in which the government does not or cannot enforce regulations, and an increased reliance on temporary employment. Additionally, firms may remain small to avoid unionization and the obligation to sign collective agreements, thus benefitting from greater freedom of contracting.

Importantly, neither spontaneously evolved evasive measures nor policy measures enacted to ease the negative effect of an overly stringent EPL (either through a reliance on thresholds or temporary contracts) are likely to improve the workings of the ecosystem’s skill structure or the likelihood of the type of high-productivity structural transformation necessary to enhance social welfare. Instead, these measures tend to create a system in which many small firms without the ability or aspiration for high growth exist side by side with large firms and government-owned firms that are better equipped to handle a stringent EPL. Outsiders remain outsiders and insiders are locked up in “gilded cages”. This dual labor market is unlikely to be inclusive for entrants, or conducive to innovation and high-skill entrepreneurial venturing. This is illustrated in Fig. 3.3, which shows a negative relationship between the overall strictness of EPL and the rate of high-growth expectation early-stage entrepreneurship. There are two clear outliers, Lithuania and Latvia, which may suggest that EPL is less binding in practice in these countries because of mitigating complementary institutions.Footnote 18

Fig. 3.3
figure 3

The strictness of employment protection and high-growth expectation early-stage entrepreneurial activity, 2010–13. Note Both variables are averaged over the four years 2010–13. Permanent EPL is given a weight of 2/3 and temporary EPL a weight of 1/3. Source Global Entrepreneurship Monitor and OECD/IAB Employment Protection Database, 2013 update

If the goal is to make the European Union more inclusive, innovative and entrepreneurial, it is highly advisable that the most regulated countries reduce the stringency of their EPL for permanent contracts. A competently implemented liberalization will reduce job security but increase employment security for workers, as labor demand will increase and more opportunities will be created in the labor market. That said, the impact and strictness of employment protection legislation depends on a complex combination of components, such as grounds for individual dismissal, redundancy procedures, mandated periods of advanced notice, severance payments, special requirements for collective dismissals, rules favoring disadvantaged groups, and so forth. For liberalization to have the desired results, countries must develop their own strategies to avoid jeopardizing the process, ideally by considering and possibly emulating the paths already taken by similar countries. This also presupposes the implementation of complementary social insurance institutions.

3.4.2.2 Social Insurance Systems

In principle, providing insurance for unfavorable outcomes can encourage individuals to pursue entrepreneurial endeavors by making the burden of uncertainty less costly, e.g., through an extensive and generous public social insurance system that also includes generous unemployment benefits (Fig. 3.4). This is a valid theoretical point shown formally by Sinn (1996), but it is an open question as to whether it is empirically important. Furthermore, the point no longer holds in labor markets in which job security is closely linked to job tenure; ultimately, what matters is the opportunity cost, i.e., how much an employee must sacrifice in terms of income and security if he or she transfers to self-employment or a risky job in an entrepreneurial firm.

Fig. 3.4
figure 4

The net replacement rate of unemployment benefits in EU countries and the U.S., 2014. Source OECD

For a tenured employee with a low-risk employer, the opportunity cost is high in many countries in which important benefits are tied to employment. Company-specific health insurance is an obvious example of such a benefit; another is accumulated pension assets, which may be difficult to transfer when switching employer and/or industry. To the extent that this is true, the mobility of (especially older) workers across firms is hampered, and the hiring of the elderly unemployed is discouraged.Footnote 19 Decoupling these and other benefits from employment would increase labor flexibility and lessen the risk that workers and potential entrepreneurs become “trapped” in large companies by reducing fears of losing adequate health insurance and other important employment benefits. In addition, supplementary pension plans should be made fully actuarial and portable. Making social security more portable and tied to the individual would also improve the low geographical mobility of workers in Europe, since being tied to a job in a firm also implies being tied to a specific location.

In this manner, public welfare systems can also reduce the need for stringent and costly employment protection legislation by replacing mandated security at the firm level, something which would arguably increase the acceptance of labor market liberalizations in many EU countries. An important role model in this respect is the flexicurity system of Denmark in which generous welfare protection and opportunities for retraining are combined with weak job security mandates (Andersen 2005). By contrast, a Swedish employee who voluntarily gives up a tenured position for self-employment may ultimately have no more security than what is provided by (means-tested) social welfare; in effect, the public income insurance systems and the employment security legislation tend to penalize individuals who assume entrepreneurial risk. Thus, the opportunity cost of giving up a tenured position in Denmark is substantially lower than in Sweden.

While the specifics can and will vary, we can infer that an important component of a policy that makes society more innovative and entrepreneurial involves making the individual’s social insurances as portable as possible when changing jobs and moving between salaried employment and self-employment. This should be the case regardless of whether the insurance is public, paid by the individual herself, or paid by the employer based on individual or collective (union) agreement. One example of how to achieve this portability is the Austrian reform of 2003, which converted uncertain firing costs for employers into a system of individual savings accounts, funded by an employer-paid payroll tax (Hofer 2007). This system guarantees the employer certainty about the cost of any future dismissal when a person is first hired, while workers do not lose their entitlement to severance pay should they quit to take a new job.

At the same time, an efficient flexicurity model must encourage the retraining of redundant workers, possibly in the dual sense that training should be supplied and that people should be obliged to accept it to draw unemployment benefits. Yet for the model to function properly, unemployment benefits cannot be so high that they reduce incentives for future job search for workers who become unemployed. Figure 3.4 reveals considerable variation in the net replacement rate of unemployment benefits across European countries. The incentive effects of a certain replacement rate depend on other complementary rules and institutions, particularly the maximum number of days during which benefits can be received, the scope for declining job offers and retraining programs, and whether the recipient can be obligated to accept a job offer even if that entails moving to another location or commuting long distances.

3.4.2.3 Conclusions on the Organization of Labor Markets

The most important channel by which labor market institutions affect entrepreneurship is through their influence on the supply of skilled workers. Given the large worker flows required in a dynamic entrepreneurial ecosystem, institutions should facilitate the recruitment of workers with the necessary competencies. Here, as we have seen, several institutional complementarities come into play. Importantly, this requires the removal of onerous employment protection legislation, as this discourages potential high-growth firms from expanding. Furthermore, social security institutions should enable the portability of tenure rights and pension plans, as well as a full decoupling of health insurance from the current employer. It should be stressed that to be as efficient as possible, these reforms should not be made in isolation but as part of a comprehensive reform package that also includes other areas, especially tax policy and competition policy, as discussed in Sects. 3.2 and 3.5.

3.5 Regulation of Goods and Service Markets

3.5.1 Preamble

Natural entry barriers such as scale economies and capital requirements affect the workings of the actors in the ecosystem’s skill structure, but artificial barriers created by governments are also important factors when considering the ease of starting a business (Begley et al. 2005; Dana 1990; Djankov and Murrell 2002). While environmental, health and safety regulations are often well motivated, competition policies that rely on excessive rules and procedures may discourage potential entrepreneurs (Dana 1990; Gnyawali and Fogel 1994; Djankov et al. 2003; Begley et al. 2005) and hamper the process of creative destruction (La Porta et al. 1997; Caballero and Hammour 2000; Desai et al. 2003).

Arguably, most damaging are restrictions and prohibitions against entry into certain sectors of the economy (such as health care) as well as administrative costs and regulatory burdens imposed on new and/or existing firms. Granted, some governmental entry barriers can be justified as consumer protection against fraudulent or incompetent business owners, and few would support a system in which anybody could work as a doctor, surgeon, or psychologist (OECD 2007). However, occupational licensing becomes problematic when it results in unjustified profit opportunities for license holders rather than consumer protection. Consequently, licensing and other overly extensive regulations may curb the rate of innovation and hamper productive entrepreneurship (Kleiner 2006). Today, Europe has over 5,000 regulated professions involving over 50 million people, and according to the European Commission (2015, p. 7): “many of these regulations are now disproportionate and create unnecessary regulatory obstacles to the mobility of professionals, lowering productivity” (cf. Erixon and Weigel 2016).

In recent decades, governments of developed countries have deregulated product markets with the aim of increasing market contestability and providing more opportunities for private entrepreneurship within sectors such as telecommunications, energy production, transportation, and financial services. The scope for new high-impact entrepreneurship has thus increased dramatically. Furthermore, welfare states increasingly recognize that ensuring access to health care and other social goods and services does not necessarily require the government to produce such goods. The Dutch example reveals that it may even be possible to eschew public financing: In the Netherlands, health care insurance is fully privatized in the sense that all private suppliers are forced to offer a standardized policy at a (competitive) price, while all citizens are forced to buy such a policy (Schäfer et al. 2010).

Overall, governments are increasingly utilizing market-type mechanismsFootnote 20 that combine private provision and public financing of these services, such as outsourcing, vouchers and public–private partnerships. In many instances, opening previously monopolized markets to private providers has led to impressive entrepreneurial performances, hinting at a largely untapped productive potential in sectors such as health care, education, and care of children and the elderly. As examples, consider the voucher system for school choice that was introduced in Sweden in the early 1990s and the (contemporaneous) outsourcing of health care by many local and regional governments, which paved the way for several high-growth firms, some of which have since become multinationals.Footnote 21 Andersson and Jordahl (2013) survey the empirical literature on the effect of outsourcing public services and conclude that it generally reduces costs without hurting quality. This is clearly the case for “perfectly contractible services” such as garbage collection, but outsourcing also often seems to work reasonably well for services with more difficult contracting problems, e.g., fire protection and prisons. However, outsourcing seems to be more problematic for credence goods, that is, goods for which buyers have a hard time determining the total cost and benefit even after purchase and use (Emons 1997), which is the case for many social services, such as education and medical treatments.Footnote 22

Welfare services are complex and difficult to procure regardless of the source of financing. When under the public domain, complexities arise from several additional sources: formalized procurement processes are likely to favor large actors and curb competition; producers cannot charge extra for quality improvements; costly excess capacity may arise; a lack of information makes rational decision making difficult for users; evaluations and compliance control are skill- and resource-intensive; segregating forces exist; and individual users and suppliers do not consider how society is affected.

In these sensitive areas, considerations of public interest should move firms beyond what the law demands and towards what is really in their long-term interest. The challenge is to create what Kay (2004) calls “embedded markets” in which governments participate without controlling, financial incentives exist but do not dominate, pluralist structures can evolve based on experimentation, and social norms continue to play a key role in maintaining compliance with a system that inspires pride in the inhabitants. Of course, this necessitates that the agents involved “take upon themselves a wider set of responsibilities” (Kay 2004, p. 344).

Market regulations incentivizing actors in the skill structure to innovate and experiment to the greatest possible extent are essential for a well-functioning entrepreneurial ecosystem. Market-leading incumbents should not be allowed to unduly exploit their dominant market positions, and all markets should be as contestable as possible. However, drafting appropriately balanced regulations is easier said than done; examples abound of the regulatory framework favoring a certain interest group rather than the general public interest (Stigler 1971; Wagner 2014), giving rise to large fixed costs that effectively bar smaller actors from entering the market (Begley et al. 2005) or falling short of its objectives in other ways. Technological change may also turn regulations into obsolete constraints at best and barriers to new entrants at worst, rendering adaptations to changing conditions more difficult.

The fact that a certain market is formally deregulated does not guarantee contestability. There can still be artificial barriers created by governments and excessive rules and procedures that discourage entrepreneurial entrants from challenging incumbents,Footnote 23 which hampers the process of structural change and creative destruction. Thus, for market competition to work efficiently, it must be easy to start a business.

3.5.2 Reform Agenda

Figure 3.5 reveals how the EU countries compare with respect to the ease of starting a business relative to the United States and New Zealand, which is the leading country. Countries such as Germany, Austria and Malta show considerable room for improvement, while the western EU countries have high overall scores on this measure. Apart from Poland and the Czech Republic, this is also the case for the Eastern European countries.

Fig. 3.5
figure 5

Ease of starting a business in EU countries, the U.S., and the leading country (New Zealand), 2015. Note The ranking of economies on the ease of starting a business is determined based on their distance to frontier scores for starting a business. These scores are the simple average of the distance to frontier scores for each of the component indicators. Source World Bank, Ease of Doing Business Index 2016

The picture that emerges from Fig. 3.5 appears fairly bright. Part of the explanation can be traced to the wave of product market deregulation that began in the United States around 1980 and then quickly spread to other countries, rekindling innovation and entrepreneurship after a decade of stagflation and recurrent structural crises (Audretsch and Thurik 2000). Product market reform is also a prime ingredient of the European integration effort; having similar product market regulations in all EU countries is considered necessary by European policymakers to fulfill the vision of transforming the European Union into one single market.

Nevertheless, as seen in Fig. 3.6, which presents the strictness of product and service market regulations in the EU and the United States, countries still exhibit large differences in the extent of their product market regulations in the European Union despite several rounds of product market deregulations. The differences are even larger in regard to service sector regulations (measured on the vertical axis), and the two measures are strongly correlated; countries with highly regulated product markets tend to have strictly regulated service markets and vice versa (r = 0.70). Furthermore, Western European countries generally score better than Eastern European and Mediterranean countries.

Fig. 3.6
figure 6

Strictness of product and service market regulations in EU countries and the U.S., 2013. Note The scale of the index is 0–6, where a larger number means a more stringent regulation. 2013 is the latest available year. The product market regulation index is OECD’s aggregate indicator; the service sector index is the arithmetic average of the OECD indices for professional services, retail trade and the network sectors (transportation, energy, telecom and mail). The indices are based on responses of national governments to the OECD Regulatory Indicator Questionnaires. Source OECD, Product Market Regulation Database

Interestingly, however, no similar correspondence can be observed between these two indices and the measure of the ease of starting a business (Table 3.6). This suggests that complementarities with factors besides regulations of these markets could affect the perceived possibility of starting a business. For example, the fact that Austria and Germany score poorly in terms of the ease of starting a business despite their relaxed product and service market regulations could be because a great deal more is involved in setting up a firm than just product market regulations, including taxes, red tape, and conditions for financing.

Table 3.6 The correlations between the ease of starting a business and the strictness of product (PMR) and service market regulations (SMR)

Service sectors are particularly important for the future of the entrepreneurial ecosystem for multiple reasons. First, they have a highly income-elastic demand and hold possibly the greatest future potential for entrepreneurship. If onerous regulations limit that potential, the consequence can be highly detrimental for the economy as a whole.Footnote 24 Second, as already noted, it is becoming increasingly clear that ensuring access to health care and other social goods and services does not necessarily require government production of such goods, and as the Dutch case shows, it may not even require direct public financing (although that is likely to remain the default option in most EU countries for historical reasons). Hence, deregulation of services promises to open entirely new arenas for private innovation and entrepreneurial venturing.

Perhaps most importantly, to tap the potential and handle the challenge of this combination of public financing and private production, novel institutional arrangements and experimentation are necessary to address the challenging fact that consumers do not pay producers directly. Manipulation and a wasteful use of resources are more likely to occur when the state acts as intermediary for an anonymous and absent third party (the taxpayers) and finances transactions between the producer and the consumer even if there is freedom of choice and competition.Footnote 25 Providers typically have limited options to offer and charge for extra quality added to what is granted through the tax-financed system. Consequently, customers will be barred from buying their preferred qualities and quantities of services from their preferred providers, and there will not be any signaling from spending decisions by demanding customers.

Unless governments experiment and innovate regarding the design of the regulatory framework governing activities characterized by a mixture of private production and public financing, the full benefits of innovation and entrepreneurial initiatives cannot be reaped, and the ecosystem’s skill structure will remain incomplete. Allowing private for-profit firms in these areas is also the most important channel through which pension savings (to a considerable extent via private equity firms) can be used to innovate and build capacity in the primarily tax-financed social service sectors.

3.6 Bankruptcy Law and Insolvency Regulation

3.6.1 Preamble

The entrepreneurial ecosystem is experimental at its core. Failure is therefore a signal of paramount importance to the actors in the skill structure. If the economy is to evolve and develop, unsuccessful and unproductive entrepreneurial ventures must close down, so that their resources can be redirected to more productive uses. All failed projects should not be considered a waste of resources, and bankruptcies are neither unproductive nor destructive; instead, the failure of a firm provides valuable information to other economic agents about whether an endeavor is profitable. Moreover, the knowledge from failed projects and ideas can often be recycled and improved either in a restructured venture with new management or in a different firm. Past failure can thereby be part of the foundation for future success. The restriction or delay of this process by stringent bankruptcy regulation harms knowledge generation and development (Holbrook et al. 2000; Gilbert et al. 2004; Armour and Cummings 2008).

Psychological costs often accompany bankruptcies, and in many countries, the public exhibits negative attitudes towards business failures (OECD 1998; Eberhart et al. 2017), which are stigmas that may unnecessarily discourage people from entrepreneurial activities. Some countries, such as the United States, look more favorably upon failed business projects (Audretsch et al. 2002), and it is important that the business culture gives failed entrepreneurs a “second chance” and allows them to start anew. Empirical research also shows that so-called habitual or serial entrepreneurs are more successful (Ucbasaran et al. 2008)—re-starters often possess valuable experience and business connections that increase their probability of success in the future. It is imperative that formal and informal institutions do not inhibit failed entrepreneurs’ willingness to try new projects.

Meanwhile, from the perspective of the potential entrepreneur, stringent bankruptcy laws are discouraging because they add to the perceived cost of starting a business. Any new business can fail, and processes of business formation, selection, and destruction often include a positive information and knowledge externality that the potential entrepreneur does not consider when starting a business. Relatively generous bankruptcy laws and insolvency regulations therefore seem reasonable with provision for discharge clauses, the postponement of debt service and repayment, and the possibility of restructuring.

3.6.2 Reform Agenda

An efficient handling of ailing firms calls for a well-designed and effective bankruptcy law and insolvency regulation to do the following: (i) minimize the time and costs to society in phasing out unprofitable and inefficient firms such that resources can be reallocated to more efficient uses, and (ii) minimize the damages for other parties involved, such as creditors, customers, suppliers, employees and the government. However, not all insolvent firms should be closed. A firm is insolvent when the value of its assets is less than its debt and when it is unable to repay its outstanding debt, but a firm may simply be experiencing temporary financial difficulties. If so, the best solution for both the firm and its creditors is normally firm restructuring and debt reduction (a “haircut”) through negotiations with the firm’s creditors.

On the one hand, it should not be too easy to file for bankruptcy. If writing off debt and starting anew is too convenient a resort for failing entrepreneurs, it may encourage exploitation and destructive entrepreneurship, harming creditors and the rest of society (OECD 1998; Audretsch et al. 2002). On the other hand, a person who goes bankrupt because of a failed venture should not automatically be stigmatized and forever ostracized from future entrepreneurship.

In essence, the insolvency regulation should strive to protect inherently healthy and promising ventures. If they are too hastily shut down, with their remaining assets shifted out to creditors, the result may very well be excessive value destruction. If the operation itself is healthy, it is often sufficient that the current owners lose all their equity, that the debt is restructured and that the consortium of debtors find a new controlling owner after restructuring (Becker and Josephson 2016).

As shown in Fig. 3.7, there are substantial differences among the EU countries with regard to the ease of resolving insolvency. Finland and Germany are thought to have the best regulatory framework in this respect—even better than that of the United States—and the rest of Western Europe also scores high except for Luxembourg. Meanwhile, the Eastern European and Mediterranean countries rank low with Portugal, Slovenia and Cyprus as interesting exceptions.

Fig. 3.7
figure 7

Ease of resolving insolvency in EU countries and the U.S., 2015. Note The ranking of economies on the ease of resolving insolvency is determined based on their distance to frontier scores for resolving insolvency. These scores are the simple average of the distance to frontier scores for the recovery rate and the strength of insolvency framework index. Finland is also the most highly ranked country in the world. Source World Bank, Doing Business 2016

While laggard countries must improve their insolvency regulation in order to become more innovative and entrepreneurial, this cannot be done in isolation. Reforms in this direction have to be combined with a strengthening of the rule of law and the security of property rights; otherwise, the reforms may prove ineffective or even facilitate abuse and fraudulence. An insolvency regulation such as the one in Finland (which is good at striking a balance between protecting and restructuring inherently healthy firms, discouraging rent seeking, and still encouraging entrepreneurial risk taking) is only feasible when countries also rank highly on the rule of law, government effectiveness and the security of property rights.

Certainly, this is no easy undertaking. Portugal and Slovenia provide what may be seen as a second-best solution in this respect. Given their apparent success, it is probably a wise, low-risk strategy for countries with similar institutional configurations to undertake reforms akin to theirs, so as not to base their reform strategy on high-quality legal institutions that are in fact absent.

3.7 R&D, Commercialization and Knowledge Spillovers

3.7.1 Preamble

The successful exploitation of research and inventions combined with the transfer and spillover of the related knowledge stimulates growth and prosperity in a modern economy (e.g., Acs et al. 2009 and Baumol 2010). Entrepreneurs play an important role in this respect in both new and established ventures, by virtue of their ability to recognize unexploited opportunities in the market and to spread innovations by imitation and incremental improvements of existing technologies (Baumol 2002). An important objective of entrepreneurship policy must be to promote this process of production and commercialization of knowledge.

In the early phase of industrialization in the West, leading innovators were mostly people with little formal education whose innovations emanated from practical experience in workshops and production plants. This gradually changed when specialized engineering schools were formed in the late 19th century both in Europe and the United States, followed by the formation of R&D departments in the large engineering firms (Rosenberg and Birdzell 1986, Chap. 8; Mowery and Rosenberg 1998). However, even today, the common idea that more R&D spending is the tool that will promote innovation reveals an overly mechanical view of how the entrepreneurial ecosystem works. New knowledge and inventions are only the first step in an innovation and commercialization process. For increased R&D to translate into economic growth, entrepreneurs must exploit the inventions by introducing new methods of production or new products in the marketplace (Bhidé 2008; Michelacci 2003).

Neither Bill Gates nor Henry Ford invented the technologies used in their ventures, but in their role as entrepreneurs, they were needed to successfully exploit inventions that someone else had created. The EOE perspective illustrates this forcefully through its emphasis on the need for a number of different actors and competencies to fully realize the benefits of innovation. Limiting the focus to inventions and R&D misses the bulk of the story, and although high R&D spending can be a necessary component of a successful economy, it is far from sufficient. Increased R&D will not automatically bring forth entrepreneurs—perhaps it is even the other way around; in an economic system that rewards productive entrepreneurship, a great deal of R&D is undertaken because the results flowing from R&D are demanded (Holcombe 2007).

The knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship offers a complimentary view (Acs et al. 2009; Braunerhjelm et al. 2010), which is important for several reasons. First, and in the vein of Schumpeter (1934), it distinguishes between knowledge in general and economic knowledge (i.e., knowledge that is economically exploitable) and conjectures that more knowledge (more R&D) does not automatically translate into more economic knowledge. Second, this theory rejects the assumption that (economic) knowledge automatically spills over and induces growth. Rather, the theory highlights the importance of the entrepreneur in enabling these crucial transformations. The entrepreneur is the actor who transforms knowledge into economic knowledge through the commercialization of inventions, and the one who brings about knowledge spillovers throughout the economy.

Knowledge is often tacit, sticky and uncertain, making it costly and difficult to transmit and evaluate (Arrow 1962). As the innovative process is shrouded in uncertainty, the expected value and variance of an innovation will differ across individuals—a discrepancy that creates high profit opportunities for entrepreneurial firms or spinoffs in instances when incumbent firms do not recognize or realize a profit opportunity.

Furthermore, innovation and entrepreneurship are largely localized phenomena, and innovation capabilities originate from the interplay between generic knowledge and learning processes that are embedded in regional knowledge and market environments (Zucker et al. 1998). A critical mass seems to be required for a dynamic innovation environment to emerge since there are many benefits for firms located close to other firms in dense, knowledge-intensive areas (Feldman 1994; Feldman and Audretsch 1999; Paci and Usai 1999; Ejermo 2009; Delgado et al. 2014).

Such dense environments are characterized by distinct wage and productivity premiums—strong centripetal forces that attract both individuals and firms (Puga 2010). Glaeser and Mare (2001), for example, report a wage premium in the U.S. of 33% between the largest metropolitan areas and non-urban locations. Such effects are also reported for European countries (Di Addario and Patacchini 2008; Andersson et al. 2014; D’Costa and Overman 2014). The evidence also suggests that the existence of strong clusters in a region enhances growth opportunities in other industries and clusters (Delgado et al. 2014).

3.7.2 Reform Agenda

Table 3.7 reveals that expenditure on R&D currently constitutes a sizable share of GDP in rich countries. In the EU, the total R&D spending ranges from roughly 3% of GDP in the Nordic countries, Germany and Austria (slightly higher than the U.S. level) to below 1% in most Eastern European and Mediterranean countries (column 1). Importantly, among top spenders, as much as 70% of total R&D spending is made by firms; the rest is spent by the government, primarily through the funding of academic research (columns 2 and 3). Furthermore, the business sector share of R&D is substantially lower in countries that have a low overall spending on R&D with the government share normally exceeding 50%. The ranking of countries is thus highly similar when comparing R&D spending by business enterprises.

Table 3.7 Total gross expenditure on R&D and business R&D spending (BERD) as a share of GDP (2014), number of researchers per million population (2014), number of patent families relative to GDP (2012), and direct and indirect (tax incentives) government support of business R&D (2013)

The variation across Europe is further accentuated when considering that the number of researchers engaged in R&D per million inhabitants is almost ten times higher in Denmark at the top compared to Cyprus at the bottom (column 4). Nevertheless, as argued above, R&D spending and the number of researchers per capita are input measures. Output from the R&D sector is economically valuable knowledge and innovations. One such measure consists of the number of patents per capita (column 5). Indeed, we can see a strong cross-country correlation between R&D spending and the rate of patenting.Footnote 26

Increased R&D spending can thus be associated with an increased production of economically valuable knowledge, as measured by the rate of patenting. However, this does not imply that a policy of increased government R&D spending will automatically result in more economically valuable knowledge. First, patents are not the only way of measuring new economic knowledge; when Da Rin et al. (2006) examined 14 European countries in a panel between 1988 and 2001, they did not find any positive relationship between public R&D spending and the rate of innovation, which they defined as the share of high-tech and early-stage venture capital investments. Furthermore, as shown in the last column of Table 3.7, the share of R&D in the business sector that is directly or indirectly funded by the government is lowest in countries with the highest R&D spending by business enterprises (see Appendix Table A.2 for a more detailed overview).

In line with our previous discussion, this suggests that higher spending on R&D does not automatically produce more innovations or more entrepreneurial activity. Instead, if a well-functioning entrepreneurial ecosystem is not already in place, the full potential from increased R&D cannot be reaped. Therefore, quantitative R&D goals risk becoming a waste of resources, as focus and resources are directed towards factors that would have found a better use elsewhere in the economy. Instead, in an economic system encouraging productive entrepreneurship, a great deal of R&D is undertaken because the results from R&D are demanded. Here, entrepreneurs and demanding customers in the ecology’s skill structure serve as particularly crucial sources of information regarding consumer needs and preferences (von Hippel et al. 2011).

Policymakers cannot hope to offset deficiencies in other policy areas by directly favoring R&D. In line with the argument in Sect. 2.2, the main role of the government should be to enable and facilitate rather than to subsidize certain industries or firms. Most importantly, governments should adhere to the late Steven Klepper’s (2016) persuasive findings that strong and highly dynamic industry clusters could emerge anywhere and gain momentum through entrepreneurial spinoffs from the leading firms. The implication is clear: it should be easy to start a business, and incentives for individuals to behave entrepreneurially and grow the new businesses should be strong. However, it is still important to avoid spoiling the strong tradition in many European countries of harboring innovations, even of a radical kind, inside large firms through intrapreneurship (Stam and Stenkula 2017).

Research also reveals that geographic proximity facilitates knowledge spillover and knowledge transfer, suggesting a potential role for the government in promoting networks, clusters and urbanization. Appendix Table A.3 shows the prevalence of clusters in European economies and the United States, revealing that clusters are considerably more common in Western European countries than in Eastern European and Mediterranean countries. If cluster policy enables more transfer of knowledge between businesses and organizations, entrepreneurship may be facilitated as a result (Moretti 2012; Moretti and Thulin 2013). For example, well-functioning housing markets, where the prices reflect scarcity and preferences, are necessary conditions for continued growth in dense areas (Glaeser 2008, 2011), as is an adequate infrastructure that allows for smooth transportation and commuting.

However, this form of support should not be directed to specific firms; instead, firms must self-select and not be “picked”. Policymakers would do well to remember that cluster formation is a long-term process that cannot be accelerated by means of a quick policy fix. By contrast, when different policies complement and reinforce one another, region-specific connections and institutions evolve and adapt over time in a complex interaction that often becomes a key component of a region’s competitive advantage (Gertler 2004; Wolfe and Gertler 2006).

3.8 Incentives for Human Capital Investment

3.8.1 Preamble

Economic growth and prosperity depend to a large extent on human capital—economically valuable knowledge tied to and inseparable from the individual (see, e.g., Barro 2001). Human capital can be acquired in many ways, such as through formal schooling, formal and informal on-the-job training, labor market programs and retraining, and informal experience and the cultivation of personal interest. There is little doubt that the incentives to invest in human capital are important for growth, a view strongly supported by the economic growth literature (Lucas 1988; Mankiw et al. 1992).

In particular, human capital of a mathematical and natural science orientation is deemed to be important for science-based entrepreneurship (Shavinina 2013). Successful entrepreneurial ventures are often highly dependent on academically trained and motivated individuals. People who engage in knowledge-based entrepreneurship can have many different backgrounds, such as university faculties, other firms, and the general pool of individuals with a graduate or an undergraduate degree.

According to human capital theory (Schultz 1960; Becker 1964), the decision to acquire and use human capital can be analyzed as an individual investment decision governed by the rate of return on human capital, often measured as the relative increase in the individual’s (discounted lifetime increase in) wage that can be attributed to an additional year of schooling. However, such an educational premium before tax is an imperfect measure of the true rate of return on education, which is also determined by factors such as the progressivity of the tax system, the availability of scholarships and subsidized loans,Footnote 27 tuition fees, the age at the time of graduation, and the continually changing risk of becoming unemployed.

Hence, government policy can influence the incentives and opportunities for individuals to acquire human capital in numerous ways. The most obvious measure is by directly allocating public funds to the educational system. Even more potent is the way policy incentivizes agents in the educational system itself, and how such activities and policies can complement or act as a substitute for the training provided by employers. In addition, as discussed in the previous sections, income taxes, wage differentials, and a well-designed social insurance system are important components in making it beneficial to acquire productive knowledge that is subsequently used intensively. Overall, it may be said that this incentivization requires substantial knowledge of the strategic choices individuals make over the course of their many years of human capital formation.

The first strategic choice occurs in high school when the individual decides whether to enter the labor market or to proceed to a university. If the individual enrolls in a university, he or she faces a choice between science- and technology-based disciplines (or STEM fields—science, technology, engineering, and math) and other areas. At graduation, the natural science graduates can again choose between employment and graduate studies with the objective of obtaining a Ph.D., but the quality of the educational system at the primary and secondary levels largely determines how much can be demanded from students at the tertiary level. If the quality of their previous education has been deficient, fewer students will be willing or able to choose more analytically demanding lines of study. Finally, after receiving a Ph.D., the individual faces yet another choice between a university career and other employment.

Obviously, all links must function efficiently for knowledge-based entrepreneurship to flourish. There must be sufficient incentives (i) to invest in human capital at the university level, (ii) to become involved in knowledge-based entrepreneurial ventures, and (iii) to adjust the university subject areas to bring them into line with business sector demand and to facilitate the transfer of knowledge from academia to the entrepreneurial sector. This third factor can be expected to have complex repercussions for the individual’s decisions at every stage. The incentives in the university system will directly influence the propensity of faculty members to become involved in entrepreneurial ventures while also affecting the educational choices of students.

If the rate of return on schooling is low, individuals can partly adjust by basing their educational choice more on what they enjoy to study than on what might be beneficial to them in their subsequent careers, seeing education more as a consumption good and less as an investment in human capital. This might include a lower willingness to opt for demanding lines of study that deprive students of leisure time or prevent them from working part-time. Hence, human capital investment may be endogenous in the sense that individuals adjust their actual investment in human capital (as opposed to the number of years of schooling) to the institutionally given rate of return.

Empirical research reveals a positive correlation between formal education and informal human capital investment in the form of on-the-job training (Mincer 1984; Heckman 2000). At the same time, strong incentives for such training may partially substitute for weak incentives for formal education, and the wage structure may also encourage intense and efficient use of the individual’s human capital.

In this respect, it is important to note that successful entrepreneurs in the United States tend to have advanced degrees.Footnote 28 Strong educational credentials are also common among European billionaire entrepreneurs. This is likely due to the causal effect of human capital and access to new ideas and to the fact that unusually talented individuals are selected into elite universities. Potential entrepreneurs face several educational and career choices, especially early in life. If the incentives to seek advanced education are distorted, individuals could make choices that make them less likely to acquire the type of knowledge that is valuable to entrepreneurial firms.

Moreover, entrepreneurial firms must be able to recruit highly competent people. The entrepreneurial sector in Silicon Valley has evolved in close cooperation with academic research at adjacent Stanford University. Europe’s lack of elite universities (outside of the United Kingdom) compared to the United States is likely to be a disadvantage for the European Union’s ability to develop Schumpeterian entrepreneurship.Footnote 29

In contrast to the university systems in most European countries, the American university system is decentralized and intensely competitive. American universities retain a high degree of autonomy; thus, they can pursue opportunities to solve their own problems and to build on their own unique strengths and aspirations. Competition occurs along several dimensions: (i) competition among universities for students and among professors for the best students at the graduate level; (ii) competition among universities for the best professors in a cultural and economic context in which mobility is high; and (iii) competition among professors for research support, giving them time away from teaching and access to complementary resources. That said, the European university systems do have some advantages relative to the U.S. system, especially because they have no or low tuition fees, which makes the best universities affordable regardless of one’s social background. The challenge for Europe is to retain its openness while increasing the quality of its universities.

3.8.2 Reform Agenda

The first column of Table 3.8 reveals surprisingly large differences in educational expenditures as a share of GDP across EU countries, where spending can differ by as much as a factor of three. The three Nordic countries are at the top, while the bottom is dominated by Eastern European countries and Italy. Yet high spending is not everything. The important thing to ask is, first, to what extent does high spending translate into more knowledge among students? Secondly, to what extent is this knowledge economic, i.e., useful in production?

Table 3.8 Expenditure on education as a share of GDP in EU countries and the U.S., 2012, and PISA results (in reading, mathematics, and science) in EU countries and the U.S., 2012

Arguably, the best source available for answering these questions comes from OECD’s Programme for International Student Assessment (PISA). The most comprehensive study to date finds a strong and statistically robust relationship between national economic performance and the level of knowledge as measured in internationally comparable tests, such as PISA and TIMSS (Hanushek and Woessman (2015).Footnote 30 PISA test results in mathematics, science and reading for the year 2012 are presented in columns 2–4 in Table 3.8.

Table 3.8 makes clear that high educational spending can be associated with top results (Finland) as well as weak results (Sweden). Conversely, pupils in Poland and Estonia have excellent results despite relatively low educational spending, while Romania and Bulgaria spend little and do poorly. (In all three areas, Chinese pupils are outstanding.) In the United States, allegedly the most innovative and entrepreneurial of all countries, government spending on education is intermediate, but complementary private spending is substantial (2% of GDP compared to an EU average of 0.3% of GDP; see OECD 2015b, p. 207). Thus, despite high total spending, U.S. pupils perform below average in all three areas and poorly in mathematics.

Hence, it appears that even though educational expenditure can be potentially beneficial for the generation of economic knowledge, there is a great risk that the money is spent inefficiently. However, poorly performing countries clearly have plenty of room to learn how to organize “production” in the education sector more efficiently.

In this respect, it is notable that tertiary enrollment has exploded in recent decades, which is evident from the first column of Table 3.9. The enrolment rate is very high in many of the poorest EU countries, notably Greece, Bulgaria and the Baltic countries. However, high enrolment rates per se are no guarantee that university studies have a high social rate of return. The resources per student vary enormously across fields, countries and schools (van der Ploeg and Veugelers 2008), but the humanities and social sciences are generally far less costly than the STEM fields, and there is an obvious temptation for policymakers to expand inexpensive programs in order to boost university enrolment, since this is a relatively inexpensive way of giving the impression of investing a lot in human capital. Such actions would be illusory, and the damage would be exacerbated if such measures crowd out existing non-academic post-secondary education and vocational training at the upper secondary level. Traditionally, such education has been important in central European countries (see Appendix Fig. A.3).

Table 3.9 Tertiary enrolment and graduates in science and engineering in EU countries and the U.S., 2013

A high enrolment rate may also conceal the fact that many of those who enroll never manage to complete their studies, which, as mentioned, depends on whether previous education levels have equipped them with the ability and willingness to do so. In Slovenia and Sweden, a mere 47 and 53%, respectively, have completed their Bachelor’s program three years after scheduled graduation. The corresponding figures in the United Kingdom and the United States are 84 and 78%, respectively (see the rightmost column of Table 3.10). A deficient quality at lower levels of education may also cause fewer students to choose more analytically demanding disciplines (see the second column of Table 3.9).

Table 3.10 Before tax educational premiums and completion rates in EU countries and the U.S.

As mentioned, the decision to acquire and use economically valuable human capital is ultimately an individual investment decision governed to a considerable extent by the rate of return on human capital (Schultz 1960; Becker 1964). Table 3.10 presents two arguably imperfect measures of this rate of return. The first column demonstrates that the rate of return on schooling varies greatly across countries from the United States, Germany and Poland at the top to Denmark, Italy and Sweden at the bottom. Comparing the overall rate of return with the return on analytical/numerical ability in the second column underscores the vital importance of this type of knowledge.

These findings merit an additional discussion, notably related to the differences in the university systems in Europe compared to the United States, the features of which were briefly discussed in Sect. 3.8.1. The U.S. university system seems more responsive to the economic needs of society than the university systems in most European countries. High tuition fees mean that students expect a high degree of relevance from the offered curricula. Likewise, professors who are dependent on research grants are more likely to adjust their research to fields that have high economic value (Rosenberg 2000). Decentralization and competition in the American system also result in greater wage dispersion with salaries being more likely to reflect the economic relevance of a field and the professor’s achievements in research and teaching. Entirely new fields and major breakthroughs in established fields have been rapidly introduced to the curricula of leading U.S. universities over the years.

The challenge for Europe is to remain accessible to everyone regardless of social background while increasing the quality of its universities to establish more world-class universities in the EU (outside of the United Kingdom). To meet this challenge, it must first be recognized that most European university systems are highly centralized; universities tend to be government owned, and the entry of private universities is disallowed or highly restricted (Jongbloed 2010). The government typically grants charters to universities and determines the rules of admission and the university’s size (through budgetary allocations) as well as the size of specific fields of study. Such control makes individual institutions less flexible, for example when it comes to varying remuneration based on an individual professor’s research and teaching performances or according to the economic value of the professor’s field. A high degree of centralization also makes it more difficult for individual universities to adjust the allocation of research budgets across fields in response to changing demands outside of academia.

While it would be unrealistic to believe that European countries could mimic the U.S. university system, certain steps could be taken to level the playing field. Notably, the link between universities and external stakeholders could be strengthened (see Appendix Table A.4). Google and Netscape provide two interesting examples of innovations originating from university campuses (in both cases from a private university). Learning from such examples would facilitate the stimulation of academic entrepreneurship and accelerate the commercialization of university-developed innovations of great potential value (Goldfarb and Henrekson 2003; Kauffman Foundation 2007). For this to be successful, university faculty must encourage and stimulate entrepreneurial initiatives while incentives for university spinoffs remain strong. Some universities have a Technology Transfer Office (TTO), an in-house organization specializing in assisting academic entrepreneurs in commercializing their inventions. However, a TTO could also hinder the commercialization of useful technologies by making the process too bureaucratic and focusing on its own narrowly defined proprietary interests and key performance indicators (Baumol et al. 2007; Kauffman Foundation 2008). Given the U.S. evidence, we are hesitant to advocate this route.

In the Horizon 2020 initiative, the EU states:

By coupling research and innovation, Horizon 2020 is helping to achieve this with its emphasis on excellent science, industrial leadership and tackling societal challenges. The goal is to ensure Europe produces world-class science, removes barriers to innovation and makes it easier for the public and private sectors to work together in delivering innovation.Footnote 31

If the EU is serious about achieving this goal, universities and other public institutions of learning need to become more entrepreneurial, flexible and adaptive towards market demand. Again, the challenge is to find the right balance between quality and accessibility and to be sensitive to the more egalitarian educational tradition in Europe while making the system of higher learning more dynamic and responsive to the needs of the entrepreneurial ecosystem.

3.9 Informal Institutions

3.9.1 Preamble

Informal institutions are typically described as the customs, traditions, and norms that permeate society (Williamson 1998, 2000), and they are arguably of great relevance to entrepreneurship and innovation. This is partly because informal institutions affect the workings of formal institutions; they can function as substitutes for formal institutions in reducing transaction costs (Arrow 1972; Glaeser et al. 2002), and the law derives much of its value from the respect that it enjoys by being consistent with these informal institutions (Kasper et al. 2012; cf. Becker and Murphy 2000). The flipside of the coin is that reforms of formal institutions may prove counterproductive if undertaking them destroys the existing benefits of informal institutions (Berkowitz et al. 2003; Lundström and Stevenson 2005; Dixit 2009; Ebner 2009).

Informal institutions are also important to entrepreneurship in their own right. McCloskey (2016) argues that the norms regarding honorable and appropriate behavior have been important historically for entrepreneurship and economic development; when people promote and honor entrepreneurs and their virtues, the floodgates of economic development will open (cf. Goldstone 1987; Mokyr 1992). Other cultural factors, such as individualism, power distance, uncertainty avoidance, masculinity and self-expressive values, have also been revealed as drivers of innovation and entrepreneurship (Shane 2003; Hechavarria and Reynolds 2009; Taylor and Wilson 2012).

Furthermore, trust, already identified as a generally important determinant for enabling economic coordination, efficiency and growth (Knack and Keefer 1997; Zak and Knack 2001; Karlan 2005; Sabatini 2008; Pugno and Verme 2012), has become a variable of increasing interest for entrepreneurship scholars (Welter and Smallbone 2006; Welter 2012). High-trust environments are said to foster market entry, enterprise growth and productive entrepreneurship (Fukuyama 1996; cf. Welter and Smallbone 2006), and individual trust is believed to be of fundamental importance for supporting network relations (Jack et al. 2004; Kim and Aldrich 2005; Anderson et al. 2007). As a lubricant without which network activity could not be possible (Anderson and Jack 2002), trust is therefore immediately relevant for a better functioning entrepreneurial ecosystem of the kind envisioned in Chap. 2 with the potential to affect all nodes in the skill structure.

In summary, informal institutions affect the workings of formal institutions, but they are also important for the fostering of entrepreneurship in their own right. The social legitimacy of entrepreneurs is especially important in this respect.

3.9.2 Reform Agenda

Above, we identified trust as a fundamental informal institution for economic efficiency as well as entrepreneurship. In fact, it might arguably take precedence over other cultural factors, such as attitudes towards entrepreneurship, competition or individualism.Footnote 32 The point can perhaps best be illustrated by plotting the EU countries with respect to their level of trust and their attitude towards competition, which is done in Fig. 3.8.

Fig. 3.8
figure 8

Trust and attitudes toward competition in EU countries. Note The figure is based on V62 (share of people who claim that most people can be trusted), and V196 (mean on a scale from 1–10 with 1 meaning “Competition is good. It stimulates people to work hard and develop new ideas”, and 10 meaning “Competition is harmful. It brings out the worst in people.”) Source European Value Survey 2008

In terms of views towards competition, countries from Eastern Europe and the Mediterranean are among those that view it most favorably (Malta, Bulgaria, Romania and Slovakia) and least favorably (Spain and Cyprus). This suggests that the attitude towards competition is a poor determinant of innovation and entrepreneurship in and of itself. Meanwhile, whereas the Mediterranean countries and parts of Eastern Europe score low on trust, the Nordic countries and the Netherlands score exceptionally high. Of these high-trust countries, Sweden stands out as having the most positive attitude towards competition. High-trust countries are also more individualistic and less worried about uncertainty. With a generally high-trusting pattern, Western European countries exhibit high degrees of individualism and are better at dealing with (or worry less about) uncertainty, whereas Eastern European and Mediterranean countries exhibit more collectivism and worry more about uncertainty. These patterns can be seen in Figs. A.4–A.6 in the Appendix.

One way of interpreting these correlations is that promoting competition in a low-trust environment is likely to prove futile or even detrimental. Though it may lead to entrepreneurship, it is likely to be of an unproductive or even destructive nature (cf. Baumol 1990). By contrast, a more positive view of competition is likely to be beneficial for productive entrepreneurship in a high-trust environment.

Another question is whether trust can be promoted. A number of studies claim that trust can be improved by political means. Notably, the positive cross-country correlation between welfare-state size and trust is taken as evidence that certain types of welfare policies can produce trust and social capital (Barr 2004; Kumlin and Rothstein 2005; Uslaner and Rothstein 2005) or that more free market institutions can increase trust levels (Berggren and Jordahl 2006). Others argue that overall, causality should be reversed with historically high-trust populations being more likely and able to create and sustain large, universal welfare states of the Nordic type (Bergh and Bjørnskov 2011), while trust and trustworthiness can also substitute for government controls and regulations (Aghion et al. 2010). From this perspective, the development of a trust culture is characterized by path dependencies and spirals fueled by unique historical circumstances (Humphrey and Schmitz 1998; Nooteboom 2002), suggesting that the evolution of a trust culture can take generations (Williamson 2000). In sum, this suggests that it is unlikely that policy in the short- or medium-run can improve trust and other norms relevant to entrepreneurship.

Evidently, the challenge of changing informal institutions in Eastern Europe is the most urgent but also the most difficult. The informal institutions in these countries evolved in the Soviet-dominated system, which made low trust a necessity for the people. With the fall of the Eastern bloc, a rapid shift occurred towards a capitalist system, the functioning of which would have benefitted greatly from higher trust and a greater tolerance towards uncertainty. These cultural changes have yet to materialize. Hence, while increased trust levels would evidently improve the conditions for innovation and entrepreneurship, policy is unlikely to be able to induce that change.

3.10 Summary and Conclusions: Institutions Nurturing a More Entrepreneurial Europe

The discussion in the previous sections of this chapter is summarized in Table 3.11, assigning to each policy area the general prescription regarding the characteristics required for a regime fostering entrepreneurship and innovation.

Table 3.11 Institutions and policy measures that support an entrepreneurial economy