Skip to main content

Insurance Distribution

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Handbook of Insurance

Abstract

This chapter details the use of insurance distribution systems in practice, highlights the theoretical support for the presence of various distribution systems within the insurance marketplace, and discusses public policy and regulatory issues related to insurance distribution. Three important economic issues form the centerpiece of the discussion. The first is the economic rationale for the choice of distribution system and for the variety of distribution systems observed in the industry. The second is the nature of insurer–agent relationships and the role and consequences of alternative compensation methods for intermediaries. The third is the economics of regulatory oversight of insurance distribution. Both the US and international contexts are considered.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 469.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 599.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 599.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    A “systemically important” nonbank financial institution is one whose insolvency is likely to threaten the financial system as a whole. However, no measures have yet been proposed to define the characteristics of such an institution.

  2. 2.

    While outside the scope of this chapter, we recognize the importance of the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act of 2010 (more popularly known as President Obama’s Health Care Reform) for insurance distribution. Significant regulatory change in the health insurance industry will affect health insurance distribution and could have spill-over effects into other lines of insurance.

  3. 3.

    See, for example, the chapters on Japan and China in Cummins and Venard (2007).

  4. 4.

    The Gramm-Leach Bliley Act of 1999 allowed commercial banks, insurers, and investment banks to operate as conglomerates under a financial holding company structure.

  5. 5.

    For example, in the USA, regulations prohibited an insurance firm from selling both property-liability and life insurance until the 1940s (Huebner et al. 2000).

  6. 6.

    The classifications are taken from A.M. Best Company’s Best’s Insurance Reports.

  7. 7.

    Market share figures do not add to 100%, as there are small shares of premium volume written by firms using other primary distribution systems (general agents or mass marketing), which are not reported here.

  8. 8.

    Some banks in the USA have begun operating independent agencies, but our data do not allow us to identify this model’s penetration.

  9. 9.

    Statistics for China are from Sun et al. (2007); those for Malaysia and Singapore are from Wong et al. (2007).

  10. 10.

    This is probably due to the greater differences in organizational relationships between firms and agents under the property-liability systems. Moreover, the historical development of property-liability distribution systems in relation to the regulation of rates in this industry has made these differences starkly apparent.

  11. 11.

    See Braeutigam and Pauly (1986), for a critique of this methodology when insurance products are not homogeneous.

  12. 12.

    See Chapter 12 of this volume for an in-depth discussion of this methodology.

  13. 13.

    An earlier study by Cather et al. (1985) compared the mean accounting profitability levels of 68 insurance groups for each year in the time period 1975 to 1982 and also found little evidence of profitability differences across firms using different distribution systems.

  14. 14.

    Cultural distance, according to the authors, is an index reflecting the similarities and differences between the behaviors and business practices in the target market and the home market of the firm entering.

  15. 15.

    Venezia et al. (1999) develop a theoretical model which shows that tied and independent agency insurers may coexist in equilibrium when independent agents provide greater assistance in claims processing. Under the additional assumption that consumers have private information about their risk types, it is shown that higher risk consumers will choose independent agency insurers, which will in turn offer higher prices and lower deductibles in equilibrium.

  16. 16.

    Of course, if consumer complaints are made only when service fails to live up to expectations, there is the possibility that selection bias in the distribution system clienteles will affect these results. For example, if shopping with a particular distribution system is correlated with service expectations or innate tendencies to file complaints, the study results may be compromised.

  17. 17.

    We refer the reader to the prior edition of this book for a more complete literature review related to the market frictions case for persistence of high-cost distribution methods, especially with respect to regulation.

  18. 18.

    Seog (2005) nonetheless shows that equilibrium coexistence of independent and exclusive agency firms is possible even if independent agency firms are less efficient, if the fixed costs of exclusive agency are sufficiently high relative to the variable cost advantages of this distribution formKelly and Kleffner (2006) argue that high fixed costs coupled with small market size may be the reasons that independent agency firms dominate the personal lines insurance market in Canada.

  19. 19.

    See, for example, Pauly et al. (1986), Grabowski et al. (1989), and Gron (1995).

  20. 20.

    In the USA, bancassurance was prohibited until 1999; its slow growth since then is often attributed to cultural differences between banks and insurers rather than to regulatory barriers (Davis 2007).

  21. 21.

    Important early works taking this perspective include Alchian and Demsetz (1972), Jensen and Meckling (1976), Williamson (1979), and Fama (1980). See Holmström and Tirole (1990) for a complete review of the theoretical literature.

  22. 22.

    Independent agents and brokers are referred to as independent agents throughout the remainder of the chapter unless a clear distinction between them must be made for clarity.

  23. 23.

    See Anderson et al. (1998) for a discussion of the creation of more vertically integrated relationships between independent insurance agents and insurers.

  24. 24.

    The authors also find evidence consistent with the predictions of Marvel (1982) regarding differences in advertising intensity across distribution systems, and with those of Sass and Gisser (1989) regarding differences in firm size across distribution systems.

  25. 25.

    Regan and Tzeng (1999) provide additional evidence on the relationship between insurance distribution system and ownership form. This study explicitly treats the choice of distribution system and ownership structure as jointly determined to control for the fact that common exogenous factors may influence both choices. The findings confirm the view that stock ownership and independent agency distribution are likely to be observed together.

  26. 26.

    More recently, some direct carriers have used information from competitor rate filings to provide quotes for up to four competing carriers, even when the competitor has lower premiums. Progressive was an early adopter of this method. However, we are not aware of any studies to determine the accuracy of the quotes provided for other carriers. For example, the competing quotes may not take into account multi-line discounts that may be offered by competitors.

  27. 27.

    Grossman and Hart (1986) present evidence of specialization in term life insurance by independent agency insurers in the USA. However, their arguments regarding why independent agency is optimal for term life insurance rely on differences in client list ownership across the different distribution systems. In life insurance there are no such differences in the USA, with the insurance firm typically retaining ownership of policy renewals (Baranoff and Sager 2003).

  28. 28.

    Group insurance programs and individual whole life insurance were classified by the authors as relatively more complex than other products, such as individual term life or credit insurance.

  29. 29.

    Efficiency is measured using data envelopment techniques, which decompose cost efficiency into technical and allocative efficiency. The authors find that both independent agency and tied agency insurers are less technically efficient than mass marketing insurers.

  30. 30.

    Note that California and Florida allow rebating, which will be discussed later.

  31. 31.

    For details regarding the Spitzer lawsuit, see Chapter 9 in Masters (2006) and the conversation recorded in Cummins et al. (2006).

  32. 32.

    See People ex rel. Cuomo v. Liberty Mut. Ins. Co. 52 A.D. 3d 378, 861 N.Y.S.2nd 294 (June 19, 2008).

  33. 33.

    Both New York and Colorado have adopted laws to require commission disclosure in all cases, while six other states (RI, UT, CT, WA, IL, OR) now require disclosure when the producer receives compensation from the insurer and the insured.

  34. 34.

    Eastman et al. (1996) find that the professional ethics of insurance agents are lower than their personal ethics but do not study the relationship between compensation methods and ethical beliefs.

  35. 35.

    In Gravelle’s model, there is also no competition between agents. Consumers are contacted by at most one agent and cannot seek out advice from other agents.

  36. 36.

    These policies and regulations tend to be similar in intent to those directed toward marketing practices in other financial services industries.

  37. 37.

    The home country retains responsibility for solvency oversight of the insurer.

  38. 38.

    There is still widespread dissatisfaction with the variation in licensing requirements across states. In support of increasing uniformity, a revised version of the NARAB was introduced in the US House of Representatives in March, 2011, with broad bipartisan support. The bill has not yet made it to the US Senate as of this writing.

  39. 39.

    It has been argued that licensing of service providers acts as a barrier to entry and protects the market position of incumbents. There are several studies that test this hypothesis for the accounting industry (see, for example, Jacob and Murray 2006, and Carpenter and Stephenson 2006). These authors find s significant decrease in the number of candidates taking the CPA exam after the adoption of the requirement that undergraduate accounting majors take 150 university credit hours. Similarly, Adams et al. (2002) find a significant decrease in the number of practicing cosmetologists after state imposition of occupational licensing. To our knowledge though, there is no study that examines the impact of producer licensing on competition or market structure in the insurance industry.

  40. 40.

    The NIA refers to all insurance intermediaries as producers and we will follow that standard for the purposes of the discussion here.

  41. 41.

    Much of what follows here is from Regan (2007), The Optional Federal Charter: Implications for Life Insurance Producers, a study sponsored by the American Council of Life Insurers.

  42. 42.

    Source: Search of state insurance department websites as of May, 2007.

  43. 43.

    Source: The Producer Licensing Uniformity Survey, accessed May 31, 2007 at http://www.naic.org/documents/committees_d_plwg_uniform_licensing_survey.xls.

  44. 44.

    The Bureau of Labor statistics reports that 627,346 people were employed in insurance agencies and brokerages in 2002, the last year the data is reported. The author assumes a 2% growth rate that matches the US population growth, and that 85% are licensed producers and 15% are non-licensed support staff. This is consistent with Smith et al. (2000). Based on this, we calculate that there are 543,908 insurance producers.

  45. 45.

    Commission rebating is also prohibited in the Act.

  46. 46.

    Replacement of a policy with one that does not significantly increase insurance or other benefits is costly to the consumer because of the high levels of commission that go to agents at the time of sale. Other detrimental effects may include higher premium rates because the consumer is older, loss of cash value in the policy, and new incontestability and suicide clauses imposed in the new policy.

  47. 47.

    The value of the documentation, in particular, has been questioned by many. Heinrich et al. (2008) provide a case study suggesting that better documentation creates value for the insurer, however.

  48. 48.

    These issues are discussed extensively in Ippolito (1988).

  49. 49.

    At least as significant for consumers is the possibility that product quality may change after the purchase is made. Even if quality can be determined at the time of purchase, it may vary over time and hence continuous monitoring is required. This problem may be mitigated by solvency regulation and regulation of other insurer practices.

References

  • Adams AF, Jackson J, Ekelund R (2002) Occupational licensing in a “competitive” labor market: the case of cosmetology. J Labor Res 23:261–278

    Google Scholar 

  • Alchian AA, Demsetz H (1972) Production, information costs, and economic organization. Am Econ Rev 62:777–795

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson E (1985) The salesperson as outside agent or employee: a transaction cost analysis. Market Sci 4:234–254

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson E, Ross WT Jr, Barton W (1998) Commitment and its consequences in the American agency system of selling insurance. J Risk Insur 65:637–669

    Google Scholar 

  • Andre JE, Sodowsky R (1997) Considering the alternative market Best Rev/Prop-Casual Insur Ed 98:42

    Google Scholar 

  • Baranoff E, Sager T (2003) The relations among organizational and distribution forms and capital and asset risk structures in the life insurance industry. J Risk Insur 70:375–400

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrese J, Doerpinghaus HI, Nelson JM (1995) Do independent agent insurers provide superior service? The insurance marketing puzzle. J Risk Insur 62:297–308

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrese J, Nelson JM (1992) Independent and exclusive agency insurers: a reexamination of the cost differential. J Risk Insur 59:375–397

    Google Scholar 

  • Basu AK, Lal R, Srinivasan V, Staelin R (1985) Salesforce compensation plans: an agency theoretic perspective. Market Sci 4:267–291

    Google Scholar 

  • Benoist G (2002) Bancassurance: the new challenges. Gen Papers Risk Insur Issues Pract 27:295–303

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger AN, Cummins JD, Weiss MA (1997) The coexistence of multiple distribution systems for financial services: the case of property-liability insurance. J Bus 70:515–546

    Google Scholar 

  • Berry-Stölzle T, Eckles D (2010) The effect of contracting incentives on productivity and compensation of insurance salespersons. Unpublished manuscript, Risk Theory Society

    Google Scholar 

  • Braeutigam RR, Pauly MV (1986) Cost function estimation and quality bias: the regulated automobile insurance industry. RAND J Econ 17:606–617

    Google Scholar 

  • Brockett PL, Cooper WW, Golden LL, Rousseau JJ, Wang Y (2005) Financial intermediary versus production approach to efficiency of marketing distribution systems and organizational structure of insurance companies. J Risk Insur 72:393–412

    Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter C, Stephenson E (2006) The 150-hour rule as a barrier to entering public accountancy. J Labor Res 27: 115–126

    Google Scholar 

  • Carr RM (1997) Strategic choices, firm efficacy and competitiveness in the united states life insurance industry, Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Pennsylvania

    Google Scholar 

  • Carr RM, Cummins JD, Regan L (1999) Efficiency and competitiveness in the US life insurance industry: corporate, product, and distribution strategies. In: Cummins JD, Santomero AM (eds) Changes in the life insurance industry: efficiency, technology, and risk management. Kluwer Academic, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Carson JM, Dumm RE, Hoyt RE (2007) Incentive compensation and the use of contingent commissions: the case of smaller distribution channel members. J Insur Regul 23:53–68

    Google Scholar 

  • Cather DA, Gustavson SG, Trieschmann JS (1985) A profitability analysis of property-liability insurers using alternative distribution systems. J Risk Insur 52:321–332

    Google Scholar 

  • Caves RE (1986) Vertical restraints in manufacturer-distributor relations: incidence and economic effects. In: Grieson R (ed) Antitrust and regulation. Lexington Books, Lexington

    Google Scholar 

  • CEA (2010), CEA statistics no. 39: Insurance distribution channels in Europe, March (2010), Brussels. http://www.insuranceeurope.eu/uploads/Modules/Publications/cea-statistics-nr-39---distribution.pdf

  • CEA (2011), European insurance—key facts, Brussels, http://www.insuranceeurope.eu/uploads/Modules/Publications/key-facts-2011.pdf

  • Chang P-R, Peng J-L, Fan CK (2011) A comparison of bancassurance and traditional insurer sales channels. Gen Papers Risk Insur Issues Pract 36:76–93

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen MS, Chang PL (2010) Distribution channel strategy and efficiency performance of the life insurance industry in taiwan. J Finan Serv Market 15:62–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen Z, Li D, Liao L, Moshirian F, Szablocs C (2009) Expansion and consolidation of bancassurance in the 21st century. J Int Finan Markets Institut Money 19: 633–644

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheng J, Elyasiani E, Lin T-T (2010) Market reaction to regulatory action in the insurance industry: the case of contingent commission. J Risk Insur 77:347–368

    Google Scholar 

  • ComScore (2008) Internet captures market share from traditional agents in purchase of auto insurance policies. http://www.comscore.com/Press_Events/Press_Releases/2008/05/Auto_Insurance_Policies_Online. Accessed 15 Sept 2011

  • Conniff JS (1986) Insurance anti-rebate statutes and Dade County Consumer Advocates v. Department of Insurance: can a 19th century idea protect modern consumers? Univ Puget Sound Law Rev 9:499–537

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooper RW (2008) OFC: Is it really just overkill? J Insur Regul 26:5–30

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooper RW (2010) Banking regulation and proposed reforms: implications for insurance regulatory reform that includes an optional federal charter J Insur Regul 28:73–104

    Google Scholar 

  • Cummins JD, Doherty NA (2006) The economics of insurance intermediaries J Risk Insur 73:359–396

    Google Scholar 

  • Cummins JD, Doherty NA, Ray G, Vaughan T (2006) The insurance brokerage industry post-October 2004 Risk Manag Insur Rev 9:89–108

    Google Scholar 

  • Cummins JD, VanDerhei J (1979) A note on the relative efficiency of property-liability insurance distribution systems. Bell J Econom 10:709–719

    Google Scholar 

  • Cummins JD, Venard B (2007) Handbook of international insurance. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Cummins JD, Weisbart SN (1977) The impact of consumer services on independent insurance agency performance. IMA Education and Research Foundation, Glenmont

    Google Scholar 

  • D’Arcy SP, Doherty NA (1990) Adverse selection, private information, and lowballing in insurance markets. J Bus 63:145–164

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahlby B, West DS (1986) Price dispersion in an automobile insurance market. J Polit Econ 94:418–438

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis SI (2007) Bancassurance: the lessons of global experience in banking and insurance collaboration. http://www.vrl-financial-news.com/retail-banking/retail-banker-intl/reports/bancassurance.aspx. Accessed 15 Sept 2011

  • Doerpinghaus HI (1991) An analysis of complaint data in the automobile insurance industry. J Risk Insur 58: 120–127

    Google Scholar 

  • Eastman KL, Eastman JK, Eastman AD (1996) The ethics of insurance professionals: comparison of personal versus professional ethics. J Bus Ethics 15:951–962

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckardt M (2007) Insurance intermediation: an economic analysis of the information services market: contributions to economics. Physica-Verlag, Heidelberg

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckardt M, Räthke-Döppner S (2010) The quality of insurance intermediary services—empirical evidence for Germany. J Risk Insur 77:667–701

    Google Scholar 

  • Estrella A (2001) Mixing and matching: prospective financial sector mergers and market valuation. J Bank Finan 25:2367–2392

    Google Scholar 

  • Etgar M (1976) Service performance of insurance distributors. J Risk Insur 43:487–499

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF (1980) Agency problems and the theory of the firm. J Polit Econ 88:288–307

    Google Scholar 

  • Fields LP, Fraser DR, Kolari JW (2007) Is bancassurance a viable model for financial firms? J Risk Insur 74: 777–794

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiordelisi F, Ricci O (2010) Efficiency in the life insurance industry: what are the efficiency gains from bancassurance? EMFI Working Paper No. 2 - 2010. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1578721

  • Fitzpatrick SM (2006) The small laws: Eliot Spitzer and the way to insurance market reform. Fordham Law Rev 74:3041–3071

    Google Scholar 

  • Focht, U., Richter, A. and Schiller, J. (2012), Intermediation and (Mis-)Matching in Insurance Markets—Who Should Pay the Insurance Broker?. Journal of Risk and Insurance. doi: 10.1111/j.1539-6975.2012.01475.x

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh C, Hilliard JI (2012) The value of contingent commissions in the property-casualty insurance industry: evidence from stock market returns. J Risk Insur 79:165–191

    Google Scholar 

  • Grabowski H, Viscusi WK, Evans WN (1989) Price and availability tradeoffs of automobile insurance regulation. J Risk Insur 56:275–299

    Google Scholar 

  • Gravelle H (1993) Product price and advice quality: implications of the commission system in life assurance. Geneva Papers Risk Insur Theory 18:31–53

    Google Scholar 

  • Gravelle H (1994) Remunerating information providers: commissions versus fees in life insurance. J Risk Insur 61: 425–457

    Google Scholar 

  • Gron A (1995) Regulation and insurer competition: did insurers use rate regulation to reduce competition?. J Risk Uncertainty 11:87–111

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman SJ, Hart OD (1986) The costs and benefits of ownership: a theory of vertical and lateral integration. J Polit Econ 94:691–719

    Google Scholar 

  • Heinrich B, Kaiser M, Klier M (2008) Does the EU insurance mediation directive help to improve data quality?—a metric-based analysis, 16th European Conference on Information Systems (ECIS). http://aisel.aisnet.org/ecis2008/195

  • Hoesly ML (1996) Life insurance distribution: the future is not what it used to be. J Am Soc CLU ChFC 50:88–100

    Google Scholar 

  • Hofmann A, Nell M (2011) Information cost, broker compensation, and collusion in insurance markets. Schmalenbach Bus Rev (SBR) 63:287–307

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmström B, Tirole J (1990) The theory of the firm, in Handbook of industrial organization. Elsevier Science Publishers, Amsterdam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Howe V, Hoffman KD, Hardigree DW (1994) The relationship between ethical and customer-oriented service provider behaviors. J Bus Ethics 13:497–506

    Google Scholar 

  • Huebner SS, Black, K Jr, Webb BL (2000) Property and liability insurance. Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Hwang T, Gao SS (2006) An empirical study of cost efficiency in the Irish life insurance industry. Int J Account Audit Perform Eval 2:264–280

    Google Scholar 

  • Inderst R, Ottaviani M (2009) Misselling through agents. Am Econ Rev 99:883–908

    Google Scholar 

  • Insurance Information Institute (2012) Buying insurance: evolving distribution channels. http://www.iii.org/issues_updates/buying-insurance-evolving-distribution-channels.html

  • International Association of Insurance Supervisors (2011) Insurance laws database. International Association of Insurance Supervisors. Basel (Switzerland)

    Google Scholar 

  • Ippolito PM (1988), The economics of information in consumer markets: what do we know? What do we need to know?. In: Maynes ES (ed) The frontier of research in the consumer interest. American Council on Consumer Interests, Columbia, Missouri

    Google Scholar 

  • Ippolito PM, Overstreet TR Jr (1996) Resale price maintenance: an economic assessment of the Federal Trade Commission’s case against the Corning Glass Works. J Law Econ 39:285–328

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacob J, Murray D (2006) Supply-side effects of the 150-hour educational requirement for cpa licensure. J Regul Econ 30:159–178

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen MC, Meckling WH (1976) Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. J Finan Econ 3:305

    Google Scholar 

  • John G, Barton W (1989) Salesforce compensation: an empirical investigation of factors related to use of salary versus incentive compensation. J Market Res 26:1–14

    Google Scholar 

  • Joskow PL (1973) Cartels, competition and regulation in the property-liability insurance industry, Bell J Econ Manage Sci 4:375–427

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalra A (2011) Insurance in emerging markets: growth drivers and profitability. In: Wong C (ed) Sigma. Swiss Re, Zurich, Switzerland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz ML (1989) Vertical contractual relations. In: Schmalensee R, Willig RD (eds) Handbook of industrial organization. Elsevier Science Publishers, Amsterdam, p 1555

    Google Scholar 

  • Kelly M, Kleffner A (2006) The distribution of property/liability insurance in canada: costs and market structure. J Insur Issues 29:51–70

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim W-J, Mayers D, Smith CW Jr (1996) On the choice of insurance distribution systems. J Risk Insur 63: 207–227

    Google Scholar 

  • Klumpes PJM, Schuermann S (2011) Corporate, product and distribution strategies in the European life insurance industry. Gen Papers Risk Insur Issues Pract 36:50–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurland NB (1995) Ethics, incentives, and conflicts of interest: a practical solution. J Bus Ethics 14: 465–475

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurland NB (1996) Sales agents and clients: ethics, incentives, and a modified theory of planned behavior. Human Relat 49:51–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lefenfeld MS (1996) Fee-based compensation replaces shrinking income. Best Rev/Prop Casual Insur Ed 96:68

    Google Scholar 

  • Marvel HP (1982) Exclusive dealing. J Law Econ 25: 1–25

    Google Scholar 

  • Masters BA (2006) Spoiling for a fight: the rise of Eliot Spitzer. Times Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Mathewson GF, Winter RA (1983) The incentives for resale price maintenance under imperfect information. Econ Inq 21:337–348

    Google Scholar 

  • National Association of Insurance Commissioners (2009) Broker compensation (ex) task force. http://www.naic.org/committees_ex_broker_comp.htm.Aaccessed6Oct2011

  • Nuttney A (1995) The marketing and distribution of European insurance. Pearson Professional Ltd., London

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Brien J (2005) The politics of enforcement: Eliot Spitzer, state-federal relations, and the redesign of financial regulation. Publius 35:449–466.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parente R, Choi BP, Slangen AHL, Ketkar S (2010) Distribution system choice in a service industry: an analysis of international insurance firms operating in the united states. J Int Manag 16:275–287

    Google Scholar 

  • Pauly MV, Kleindorfer P, Kunreuther H (1986) The economics of insurance regulation: a cross-national study. St. Martin’s Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Posey LL, Tennyson S (1998) The coexistence of distribution systems under price search: theory and some evidence from insurance. J Econ Behav Organ 35: 95–115

    Google Scholar 

  • Posey LL, Yavaş A (1995) A search model of marketing systems in property-liability insurance. J Risk Insur 62:666–689

    Google Scholar 

  • Puelz R, Snow A (1991) Efficient contracting in a market for life insurance agents with asymmetric information. J Risk Insur 58:729–736

    Google Scholar 

  • PwCs Luxembourg (2011) Study of the impact of the revision of the insurance mediation directive. Luxembourg. http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/insurance/docs/mediation/imd_final_en.pdf

  • Regan L (1997) Vertical integration in the property-liability insurance industry: a transaction cost approach. J Risk Insur 64:41–62

    Google Scholar 

  • Regan L (1999) Expense ratios across insurance distribution systems: an analysis by lines of business. Risk Manag Insur Rev 2:44–59

    Google Scholar 

  • Regan L (2007) The optional federal charter: implications for life insurance producers. American Council of Life Insurers, Washington, D.C

    Google Scholar 

  • Regan L, Kleffner A (2011), The role of contingent commissions in property-liability insurer underwriting performance. Unpublished manuscript. Risk Theory Society

    Google Scholar 

  • Regan L, Tennyson S (1996) Agent discretion and the choice of insurance marketing system. J Law Econ 39:637

    Google Scholar 

  • Regan L, Tzeng LY (1999) Organizational form in the property-liability insurance industry. J Risk Insur 66:253–273

    Google Scholar 

  • Rejda GE (2011), Principles of risk management and insurance. Prentice Hall, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Russell DT (1997), An empirical analysis of life insurance policyholder surrender activity, Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Pennsylvania

    Google Scholar 

  • Sass TR, Gisser M (1989) Agency cost, firm size, and exclusive dealing. J Law Econ 32:381–400

    Google Scholar 

  • Seog SH (1999) The coexistence of distribution systems when consumers are not informed. Gen Papers Risk Insur Theory 24:173–192

    Google Scholar 

  • Seog SH (2005) Distribution systems and operating leverage. Asia-Pacific J Risk Insur 1:45–61

    Google Scholar 

  • Skipper HD (1998), International risk and insurance—an environmental-managerial approach. McGraw-Hill/Irwin, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith P, Isenberg KN, Fullerton CE (2000) The survey of producer opinion—United States.

    Google Scholar 

  • Staikouras SK (2006) Business opportunities and market realities in financial conglomerates. Gen Papers Risk Insur 31:124–148

    Google Scholar 

  • Stalson JO (1969), Marketing life insurance; its history in America. Published for McCahan Foundation by R. D. Irwin Homewood Ill, Bryn Mawr

    Google Scholar 

  • Sun Q, Suo L, Zheng W (2007), China’s insurance industry: developments and prospects. In: Cummins JD, Venard B (eds) Handbook of international insurance. Springer US, p 597–640

    Google Scholar 

  • Telser LG (1960) Why should manufacturers want fair trade?, J Law Econ 3:86–105

    Google Scholar 

  • Tennyson S (2011), Challenges and approaches to consumer protection in the insurance industry. In: Liedtke PM, Monkiewicz J (eds) The fundamentals of future insurance regulation and supervision: a global perspective. Palgrave Macmillan, United Kingdom

    Google Scholar 

  • Trese H (2011) Where have all the agents gone, Agent Sales J http://www.lifehealthpro.com/2011/01/03/where-have-all-the-agents-gone. Accessed 1 Jan 2011

  • Trigo-Gamarra L (2008) Reasons for the coexistence of different distribution channels: an empirical test for the German insurance market Gen Papers Risk Insur Issues Pract 33:389–407

    Google Scholar 

  • Trigo-Gamarra L, Growitsch C (2010) Comparing single- and multichannel distribution strategies in the German life insurance market: an analysis of cost and profit efficiency. Schmalenbach Bus Rev 62:401–417

    Google Scholar 

  • Venezia I, Galai D, Shapira Z (1999) Exclusive vs. Independent agents: a separating equilibrium approach. J Econ Behav Organ 40:443–456

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilder J (2004) Competing for the effort of a common agent: contingency fees in commercial lines insurance. US Department of Justice Antitrust Division Economic Analysis Group Working Paper No. EAG03-4. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=418061

  • Williamson OE (1979) Transaction-cost economics: the governance of contractual relations. J Law Econ 22:233–261

    Google Scholar 

  • Wong C, Barnshaw M, Bevere L (2007) Bancassurance: emerging trends, opportunities and challenges. Sigma 1–37

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sharon Tennyson .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer Science + Business media, New York

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Hilliard, J.I., Regan, L., Tennyson, S. (2013). Insurance Distribution. In: Dionne, G. (eds) Handbook of Insurance. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-0155-1_25

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics