Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The Causes of Fiscal Transparency: Evidence from the U.S. States

  • Published:
IMF Staff Papers Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We use unique panel data on the evolution of transparent budget procedures in the U.S. states over the past three decades to explore the political and economic determinants of fiscal transparency. Our case studies and quantitative analysis suggest that both politics and fiscal policy outcomes influence the level of transparency. More equal political competition and power sharing are associated with both greater levels of and increases in fiscal transparency during the sample period. Political polarization and past fiscal conditions, in particular state government debt and budget imbalances, also appear to affect the level of transparency.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Petrie (2003) provides thoughtful suggestions on how to make the implementation of transparency reform more effective.

  2. Trust increases when transparency means “tell them what you’re going to do.” If politicians have a history of having nothing to hide, they are more likely to have the people’s trust when they ask them to take something on faith. Transparency reassures people that politicians have not abandoned long-term goals; the confidence this fosters can give politicians greater flexibility.

  3. Greater disclosure makes actions more predictable when transparency means “give them details and justifications.”

  4. In the political market, voters get a clearer view of performance and can make more effective use of votes. In financial markets, participants are not misled and risks are reduced (Glennerster and Shin, n.d.). Generally, better observability is welfare-improving, as it reduces transaction costs in the broadest sense.

  5. Lowry (2001) provides such an interpretation of balanced budget rules, conditional on market behavior. In monetary policy, an incumbent wishing to be seen to fight inflation can do so more effectively if the standard for what will count as fighting inflation is unambiguous.

  6. This potential for “harmful” competition may be a reason to support secret voting (Dal Bo, 2005).

  7. For a different asymmetric information model applied to fiscal policy, see Rogoff (1990). Geraats 2002 analyzes transparency in a signaling model in which the incentive effects of transparency are sometimes set against the effects of inflation fighters’ reputations.

  8. Alt and Lassen (2006b) find support for this hypothesis in a cross-section of advanced OECD economies for the 1990s. They use this, and a measure of legal origin (common vs. civil law), to instrument for transparency in an analysis of the effects of transparency on government debt.

  9. For example, the introduction of balanced budget rules in the nineteenth century took place as a result of fiscal crises following from the construction of railroads and canals (Heckelman and Wallis, 1997).

  10. Alt and Lassen (2006b) present a transparency index based on similar principles for 19 OECD countries.

  11. Around the same time, Rhode Island took many other steps to open up the legislative process to public scrutiny. For a summary of these reforms, see http://www.rilin.state.ri.us/studteaguide/RhodeIslandHistory/chapt9.html

  12. If control of the legislature is split between parties, we code the case as divided government. We return to this in Table 5.

  13. It is defined as −1*abs(share of seats in lower house held by Democrats −0.5)*abs(share of seats in upper house held by Democrats −0.5).

  14. Recall that a polarization measure is available only for states represented by more than one party in Congress. States that elect only one party to Congress will, besides typically having small populations, have some degree of polarization and may even be more polarized than states electing more than one party, when everything else is equal. For consistency, they are represented in our analysis by a dummy variable because a score of zero indicates minimal polarization, as well as only one party in Congress.

  15. Alt and Lassen (2006b) show that, in a sample of OECD countries, lower transparency leads to higher debt.

  16. In fact, what Table 3 shows is that, absent fiscal shocks, the effect of divided government is stronger than it appeared in Table 1. This may be because divided government is slow to respond to fiscal shocks (Alt and Lowry, 1994). We will also reexamine the other competition indicators, whose effects were stronger in Table 1, for evidence of interactions.

  17. All robustness test results are available from the authors upon request.

  18. The estimation was carried out using Stata’s xtabond2 procedure (Roodman, 2003) with the noleveleq option. There was no sign of overidentification or second-order autocorrelation in the first-differences. For computational reasons, the instrument matrix was constructed using xtabond2’s collapse option, which drastically reduces the dimension of the instrument matrix, which becomes large in Arellano-Bond estimation of long panels. In long panels, the collapse correction reduces efficiency, which implies that the reported standard errors are conservative, but at the same time it counters problems with bias arising from the number of instruments approaching the number of observations.

  19. We also experimented with a random effects Tobit model, with no qualitative effect on the results.

References

  • Alesina, Alberto, and Roberto Perotti, 1996, “Fiscal Discipline and the Budget Process,” American Economic Review, Vol. 86 (May), 401–07.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alt, James E., and David Dreyer Lassen, 2006a, “Transparency, Political Polarization, and Political Budget Cycles in OECD Countries,” American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 50 (July), pp. 530–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • —, 2006b, “Fiscal Transparency, Political Parties, and Debt in OECD Countries,” European Economic Review, Vol. 50 (August), pp. 1403–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alt, James E., David Dreyer Lassen, and David Skilling, 2002, “Fiscal Transparency, Gubernatorial Popularity, and the Scale of Government: Evidence from the States,” State Politics and Policy Quarterly, Vol. 2 (Fall), pp. 230–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alt, James E. and Robert C. Lowry, 1994, “Divided Government, Fiscal Institutions, and Deficits: Evidence from the States,” American Political Science Review, Vol. 88 (December), pp. 811–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • —, 2000, “A Dynamic Model of State Budget Outcomes under Divided Partisan Government,” Journal of Politics, Vol. 62 (November), pp. 1035–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, Robert, 1973, “The Control of Politicians: An Economic Model,” Public Choice, Vol. 14 (Spring), pp. 19–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, Timothy, forthcoming, Principled Agents? The Political Economy of Good Government (Oxford: Oxford University Press).

  • —, and Anne Case, 2003, “Political Institutions and Policy Choices: Evidence from the United States,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 41 (March), pp. 7–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • —, and Andrea Prat, forthcoming, “Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand: Media Capture and Government Accountability,” American Economic Review.

  • —, and Michael Smart, 2005, “Fiscal Restraints and Voter Welfare,” Political Economy and Public Policy No. 6 (London: London School of Economics).

    Google Scholar 

  • Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2005, Current Unemployment Rates for States and Historical Highs/Lows (Washington). Available via the Internet: http://www.bls.gov/web/lauhsthl.htm.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campos, J. Edgardo, and Sanjay Pradham, 1999, “Budgetary Institutions and the Levels of Expenditure Outcomes in Australia and New Zealand,” in Fiscal Institutions and Fiscal Performance, ed. by J. M. Poterba and J. von Hagen (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Dal Bo, Ernesto, 2005, “Bribing Politicians” (unpublished: Berkeley, California: University of California at Berkeley).

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn, John, 1986, “Incumbent Performance and Electoral Control,” Public Choice, Vol. 50 (July), 5–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • —, 1999, “Accountability and Authority: Toward a Theory of Political Accountability,” in Democracy, Accountability and Representation, ed. by A. Przeworski, S. Stokes, and B. Manin (New York: Cambridge University Press), pp. 31–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox, Justin, 2005, “Government Transparency and Policymaking,” Leitner Working Paper 2005-01 (New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University).

    Google Scholar 

  • Gavazza, Alessandro, and Alessandro Lizzeri, 2005, “Transparency and Economic Policy,” Working Paper (New York: New York University).

    Google Scholar 

  • Gelos, R. Gaston, and Shang-Jin Wei, 2005, “Transparency and International Portfolio Holdings,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 60 (December), pp. 2987–3020.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geraats, Petra, 2002, “Central Bank Transparency,” Economic Journal, Vol. 112 (November), pp. F532–F565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • —, 2005, “Transparency of Monetary Policy: Theory and Practice,” CESIfo Economic Studies, Vol. 52 (March), pp. 111–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glennerster, Rachel, and Yongseok Shin, n.d. “Do Sovereign Bond Markets Reward Transparency?” (unpublished; Madison, Wisconsin: University of Wisconsin). Previous version presented at the International Monetary Fund’s Jacques Polak Fifth Annual Research Conference.

  • Governing.com, 2005, The Government Performance Project: Grading the States’ 05. Available via the Internet: http://governing.com/gpp/2005/de.htm.

  • Government Performance Audit Committee (GPAC), 1992, Performance Audit of Planning, Budgeting, and Program Evaluation Processes: Final Report (Background and Current Situation), December 1992 (Raleigh: North Carolina General Assembly). Available via the Internet: http://www.ncga.state.nc.us/GPAC/planbud.html.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, Peter, and Rosemary Taylor, 1996, “Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms,” Political Studies, Vol. 44 (December), pp. 936–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanssen, F. Andrew, 2004, “Is There a Politically Optimal Degree of Judicial Independence?” American Economic Review, Vol. 94 (June), pp. 712–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heald, David, 2003, “Fiscal Transparency: Concepts, Measurement and UK Practice,” Public Administration, Vol. 81 (December), pp. 723–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckelman, Jac C., and John Joseph Wallis, 1997, “Railroads and Property Taxes,” Explorations in Economic History, Vol. 34 (January), pp. 77–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Judson, R. A., and A. L. Owen, 1999, “Estimating Dynamic Panel Data Models: A Guide for Macroeconomists,” Economics Letters, Vol. 65 (October), pp. 9–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kopits, George, and J. D. Craig, 1998, “Transparency in Government Operations,” IMF Occasional Paper No. 158 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck, Assar, and Jörgen Weibull, 1987, “Balanced-Budget Redistribution as the Outcome of Political Competition,” Public Choice, Vol. 52 (January), pp. 273–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lowry, Robert C., 2001, “A Visible Hand? Bond Markets, Political Parties, Balanced Budget Laws, and State Government Debt,” Economics and Politics, Vol. 13 (March), pp. 49–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • —, James E. Alt, and Karen E. Ferree, 1998, “Fiscal Policy and Elections in American States,” American Political Science Review, Vol. 92 (December), pp. 759–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria, 2004, “Good, Bad or Ugly? On The Effects of Fiscal Rules with Creative Accounting,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 88 (January), pp. 377–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morris, Stephen, and Hyun Song Shin, 2002, “The Social Value of Public Information,” American Economic Review, Vol. 92 (December), pp. 1521–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, Douglass C., 1990, “Institutions and a Transaction-Cost Theory of Exchange,” in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. by J. E. Alt and K. A. Shepsle (Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, Torsten, Gérard Roland, and Guido Tabellini, 1997, “Separation of Powers and Political Accountability,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112 (November), pp. 1163–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petrie, Murray, 2003, “Promoting Fiscal Transparency: The Complementary Roles of the IMF, Financial Markets, and Civil Society,” IMF Working Paper 03/199 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    Google Scholar 

  • Poole, Keith and Howard Rosenthal, 1997, Congress: A Political-Economic History of Roll Call Voting (New York: Oxford University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Posen, Adam, 2002, “Six Practical Views of Central Bank Transparency,” Institute for International Economics Working Paper (Washington: Institute for International Economics). Available via the Internet: http://ssrn.com/abstract=312667.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prat, Andrea, 2005, “The Wrong Kind of Transparency,” American Economic Review, Vol. 95 (June), pp. 862–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, Kenneth, 1990, “Equilibrium Political Business Cycles,” American Economic Review, Vol. 80 (March), pp. 21–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roodman, David, 2003, “XTABOND2: Stata Module to Extend Xtabond Dynamic Panel Data Estimator” (Boston: Boston College Department of Economics. Revised January 18, 2006).

    Google Scholar 

  • Shi, Min, and Jakob Svensson, 2002, “Conditional Political Budget Cycles” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 3352 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    Google Scholar 

  • Stasavage, David, 2004, “Public versus Private Deliberation in a Representative Democracy,” Working Paper (London: London School of Economics).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Additional information

The authors thank Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti; Ilyana Kuziemko; and participants at the Colloquium on Law, Economics, and Politics at New York University, and the IMF Annual Research Conference for helpful suggestions. Lassen thanks the Economic Policy Research Unit network for funding.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Alt, J.E., Lassen, D.D. & Rose, S. The Causes of Fiscal Transparency: Evidence from the U.S. States. IMF Econ Rev 53 (Suppl 1), 30–57 (2006). https://doi.org/10.2307/30036021

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.2307/30036021

JEL

Navigation