Skip to main content
Log in

Comment on “The economics of follow-on drug research and development: Trends in entry rates and the timing of development”

  • Commentary
  • Published:
PharmacoEconomics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Notes

  1. Angell[2] argues that many me-too drugs are never tested at equivalent doses to show that there are significant differences in outcomes for some patients, and claims that “the idea that patients respond differently to me-too drugs is merely an untested — and self-serving — hypothesis.”

  2. Lichtenberg[7] finds that drugs that the FDA lists as ‘priority review’ create a significant impact on population longevity, while ‘standard-review’ drugs, which have therapeutic properties the FDA considers to be similar to those of already-marketed drugs, have no discernible effect on longevity. Prices of standard-review drugs are, however, typically similar to those of the previously introduced priority-review drugs.

  3. The use of trade names is for product identification purposes only and does not imply endorsement.

  4. In this context, it is hard to understand the standard industry defence of me-too drugs, which consists of arguing that they are good because they lead to price reductions and competition before patent expiry.[13] If price reductions are desirable in themselves before patent expiry, why are patents so desirable?

  5. Before the requirement for clinical superiority was introduced to the Orphan Drug Act, firms had developed and marketed almost identical products for rare diseases, which “left the biotechnology industry susceptible to a loss in the value inherent in market exclusivity”[21]

  6. A related problem is that when a drug enters a relatively crowded market, it is not clear what the standard for approval should be. Should it be comparison with the most recent entrants, to the first entrant, or what? Requiring a demonstration of clinical superiority to six other drugs would be very expensive. Perhaps a reasonable requirement would be comparison with (at most) two therapies deemed to be most similar by the regulator.

References

  1. DiMasi J, Paquette C. The economics of follow-on drug research and development trends in entry rates and the timing of development. Pharmacoeconomics 2004; 22 Suppl. 2: 1–14

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  2. Angell M. The truth about the drug companies. New York: Random House, 2004

    Google Scholar 

  3. Avorn J. Powerful medicines. New York: Knopf, 2004

    Google Scholar 

  4. Goozner M. The $800m pill: the truth behind the cost of new drugs. Berkeley (CA): University of California Press, 2004

    Google Scholar 

  5. Lu ZJ, Comanor WS. Strategic pricing of new pharmaceuticals. Rev Econ Stat 1998; 80 (1): 108–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Ekelund M, Persson B. Pharmaceutical pricing in a regulated market. Rev Econ Stat 2003; 85 (2): 298–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Lichtenberg FR. Pharmaceutical knowledge-capital accumulation and longevity. In: Corrado C, Haltimanger J, Sichel D, editors. Measuring capital in a new economy. Chicago (IL): University of Chicago Press, 2004

    Google Scholar 

  8. Ellison S, Snyder C. Countervailing Power in Wholesale Pharmaceuticals. Cambridge (MA): MIT Department of Economics Working Paper 01-27, 2001

    Google Scholar 

  9. Cockburn I, Anis AIL Hedonic analysis of arthritis drugs. NBER Working Paper 6574. Cambridge (MA), 1998

  10. Azoulay P. Do pharmaceutical sales respond to scientific evidence? J Econ Manage Strategy 2002; 11 (4): 551–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. DiMasi J. Commission on Intellectual Property Rights, Innovation and Public Health. Comment on’ Me-too drugs: is there a problem?’ [online]. Available from URL: http://www.who.int/intellectualproperty/forum/dimasi response/en/index.html [Accessed 2005 May 15]

  12. Lichtenberg F, Philipson T. The dual effects of intellectual property regulations: within- and between-patent competition in the US pharmaceuticals industry. J Law Econ 2002; 45 (2): 643–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Kaitin KI, editor. Incremental R&D creates safer, more effective drugs & fosters competition. Tufts Center for the Study of Drug Development Impact Report. Boston (MA), 2004: 6 (6)

    Google Scholar 

  14. Rosenthal MB, Berndt ER, Donohue JM, et al. Demand Effects of Recent Changes in Prescription Drug Promotion. Kaiser Family Foundation, June 2003 [online]. Available from URL: http://www.kff.org/rxdrugs/6085-index.cfm [Accessed 15 May 2005]

  15. Kravitz RL, Epstein RM, Feldman MD, et al. Influence of patients’ requests for direct-to-consumer advertised antidepressants: a randomized controlled trial. JAMA 2005 Apr 27; 293: 1995–2002

    Google Scholar 

  16. Spence M. Product selection, fixed costs, and monopolistic competition. Rev Econ Stud 1976; 43 (2): 217–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Dixit A, Stiglitz J. Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. Am Econ Rev 1977; 67 (3): 297–308

    Google Scholar 

  18. Anderson S, de Palma A, Nesterov Y. Oligopolistic competition and the optimal provision of products. Econometrica 1995; 63 (6: 1281–301

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Olson MK. Are novel drugs more risky for patients than less novel drugs? J Health Econ 2004; 23 (6): 1135–58

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  20. Milne C, Kaitin K, Ronchi E. Orphan drug laws in Europe and the US: incentives for the research and development of medicines for the diseases of poverty. CMH Working Paper Series, Paper No. WG2: 9. Geneva: World Health Organization, 2001

    Google Scholar 

  21. Rohde DD. The Orphan Drug Act: an engine of innovation? At what cost? Food and Drug Law J 2000; 55: 125–44

    CAS  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

No sources of funding were used to assist in the preparation of this commentary. The author has no conflicts of interest that are directly relevant to the content of this commentary. This paper has benefited from the comments of an anonymous referee, and from Joseph DiMasi’s thorough response to an earlier version.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Aidan Hollis.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Hollis, A. Comment on “The economics of follow-on drug research and development: Trends in entry rates and the timing of development”. Pharmacoeconomics 23, 1187–1192 (2005). https://doi.org/10.2165/00019053-200523120-00002

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.2165/00019053-200523120-00002

Keywords

Navigation