Introduction

For decades, economic policymakers have experimented with many development mantras, with various objectives ranging from increasing economic growth and reducing inequality to alleviating poverty, and especially for the “bottom billion.”Footnote 1 However, economic approaches in developing countries have historically revealed no compelling evidence of any particular suitable model that has worked perfectly in the developing world, and in Africa in particular (Ascher et al. 2016; Olu and Afeikhena 2014). For instance, various models on financial development—such as micro-credit and digital payment systems meant to increase access to finance for the poor—are still being promoted in African countries, but Africa’s level of poverty is increasing while declining in other regions worldwide (Asongu and Sara 2018; Santos and Kvangraven 2017; Bateman 2017; World Bank, 2015; Hulme and Maitrot 2014).Footnote 2

Moreover, a recent analysis of financial development indicators in Africa revealed that fewer than one-quarter of adults have an account with a formal financial institution, many adults use informal methods to save and borrow, and a majority of small and medium-sized enterprises are unbanked, with access to financing as their greatest challenge (Demirguc-Kunt and Klapper 2012). Among other reasons, the study also found that the low penetration of bank accounts in Africa is partially attributed to the low income levels that hinder savings, limited physical access points, and the high costs of maintaining bank accounts.

While acknowledging the low income across African communities as a possible constraint to financial inclusion through traditional banking systems, financial inclusion for the “bottom billion” is clearly possible through technology.Footnote 3 For instance, Ndung’u (2017, 2018) noted that digitalization has driven the accelerated provision of financial services through retail payments, virtual savings, and credit supply. This has been demonstrated in Kenya, where the country’s M-Pesa services have contributed to the growth of bank account-holders, from 26.7% in 2006 to over 75% in 2016.Footnote 4 Although the debate regarding the finance-growth nexus is far from concluded, evidence exists based on endogenous growth theories to suggest that a well-developed, inclusive financial system will support higher levels of growth and lower levels of poverty (Terfa 2018; Terfa and Fonta 2018; Mauzu and Alagidede 2018; Zulfiqar et al. 2016; Andrianaivo and Kpodar 2012).

Therefore, focus has intensified following a steady increase in remittance flows to Africa, toward leveraging remittances to enhance financial inclusion and promote financial development. Additionally, research activity has intensified in this area, although these studies present mixed findings. Some studies have confirmed that families receiving migrant remittances can access better health facilities, obtain a better education, and have better financial access and lower poverty levels than those that do not receive such remittances (Uzochukwu and Chukwunonso 2014; Dilip 2013; Reanne et al. 2009). Moreover, remittance flows through formal channels provide opportunities for encouraging savings, increasing deposits, and deepening financial inclusion (Al-Tarawneh 2016; Meyer and Shera 2016; Shera and Meyer 2013). However, other studies have demonstrated that remittances lead to the relaxation of borrowing constraints, which subsequently decreases the marginal utility of wealth and increases the consumption of all normal goods, including leisure. In this case, migrant remittances cause reduction of labor supply among the non-migrants who substitute income for leisure. This may adversely impact investments and the accumulation of capital (Berrak et al. 2018; Guha 2013).Footnote 5

This debate on the remittance-finance link has not escaped policy circles in Kenya; approximately three million Kenyans constituting around 7.0% of the total population live abroad (Ministry of Foreign Affairs 2014). Remittances have steadily increased in Kenya, at an average annual rate of 15.8% in the past decade and increasing from US$934 million in 2011 to an estimated US$2.7 billion in 2018, or 3.0% of Gross Domestic Product -GDP (World Bank 2019). Kenya is one of the top five highest remittance-recipient countries in Africa, after Egypt, Nigeria, Morocco and Ghana, as per the World Bank estimates in 2018. Remittances to Kenya have consistently increased, with higher levels recorded than foreign direct investments and portfolio equity flows. However, these statistics only reflect remittance flows through formal channels and are believed to be grossly underestimated, as migrants send money through informal channels and in-kind transfers, and these are often unrecorded.

As summarized by Filippo et al. (2014), money transferred through financial institutions paves the way for recipients to demand and access other financial products and services. Moreover, providing remittance transfer services allows banks and financial institutions to gather recipients’ information, which is important for mitigating adverse selection problems. The same paper also noted that remittance channels can be used to sell financial service packages geared toward low-income individuals. This debate takes on special importance in the case of Kenya, where cross-border remittance transactions have been extensively revolutionized using mobile phone technology. Kenya is one country used as a worldwide example of what adopting technology can accomplish, as with its well-known M-Pesa products.Footnote 6 An international remittance transfer service is one such product with substantial potential to reach millions of people, including low-income and unbanked populations in rural areas.

However, in spite of these remittances’ potential impacts on financial development, few country-specific studies have empirically examined the remittance-financial development linkages in the African region. Moreover, no consensus exists regarding the impact or direction of the causality between remittances and financial development (Coulibaly 2015; Nyamongo et al. 2012; Gupta et al. 2009). Previous studies on migration and remittances have concentrated on remittances and growth and have ignored the channels through which migration and remittances affect economic growth (Fayissa and Nsiah 2010). The few studies that have considered these channels have primarily focused on investment and consumption channels, ignoring those that could promote financial development (Makori et al. 2015; Aboulezz 2015; Mwangi and Mwenda 2015; Ocharo 2014; Kiio et al. 2014).

This study attempts to fill this gap by analyzing the relationship between remittances and financial development as it contributes to existing knowledge in at least four respects. First, no study to the best of our knowledge has examined the remittance-financial development nexus using Kenyan data. Second, this paper uses multiple indicators of financial development, including such indicators of financial inclusion as the numbers of bank accounts and mobile transactions that have not been used in previous studies based on Kenyan data. Third, the paper’s data set also incorporates the bound co-integration technique or the autoregressive distributive lag model (ARDL), which previous studies have not utilized. Fourth, this study also examines whether any reverse causality exists between remittances flows and financial development, as existing literature indicates the possibility of such a relationship. This study’s results are critical for policymakers keen to leverage technology to facilitate enhanced remittances and improved financial inclusion. The study is also beneficial to private sector actors—primarily banks, but also governments—that can benefit by developing customized products for the diaspora.

Remittance flows in Kenya

This section presents an overview of trends in Kenya’s remittance flows. Figure 1 illustrates that remittance flows to Kenya increased in 2003 and has been steadily growing over the last decade. Such flows were stable even during the global financial crisis, when other capital flows were volatile. Figure 2 provides trends on remittances flows and other capital flows.

Fig. 1
figure 1

inflows to Kenya (1975–2018) in Million US$. Source: World Bank Migration and Remittances data, Central Bank of Kenya

Fig. 2
figure 2

Capital inflows (in Millions US$). Source: World Development Indicators, World Bank Migration and Remittances data

Remittances to Kenya have consistently increased, with higher levels recorded than foreign direct investment and portfolio equity flows. Although official development assistance flows have increased, their developmental impact is not directly tangible compared to remittances that flow directly to their beneficiaries, with potential impacts on health, education, small-scale businesses, and the real sector. Moreover, several previous studies note that official development assistance does not necessarily translate to high economic growth rates (Yiew and Lau 2018; Phiri 2017; Murshed and Khanaum 2014). Historically, official development assistance has been misappropriated at both state and non-governmental levels (Elayah 2016; Kono and Montinola 2013; Bodomo 2013; Doucouliagos and Paldam 2011; Maipose 2000).Footnote 7 Further, remittance flows through formal channels to African countries—including Kenya—are believed to be grossly underestimated, as migrants often send unrecorded funds through informal channels and in-kind transfers.

Kenya receives the highest remittance flows from the United States, Asia, United Kingdom and African countries, or approximately 47%, 15% and 11% of total flows, respectively as illustrated in Fig 3. These numbers indicate not only areas of focus in terms of bilateral agreements to ease and enhance remittance flows, but also where the private sector—and especially commercial banks, mobile companies, and online remittance platforms—should concentrate their attention to attract more remittance flows and expand their market territory. The government could also focus on these corridors in terms of incentives and policies that are conducive to harnessing these flows.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Sources of remittance inflows to Kenya in 2017. Source: World Bank Migration and Remittances data

Remittance flows to Kenya constitute about 3.0% of the nation’s GDP based on 2018 estimates. Figure 4 displays these trends over time (World Bank, April 2019). In spite of remittance flows’ potential importance, Kenya’s remittance market—and indeed, markets elsewhere on the African continent—is not devoid of challenges. Aside from the inaccuracy of data due to remittance flows through informal channels, it is incredibly expensive to send funds to Sub Saharan Africa, with an average cost of approximately 9.3%, versus a global average of 7.0% (World Bank 2019).Footnote 8 This is 6.3% above target 10c of the sustainable development goals.Footnote 9 The high cost to send funds to Africa are due to an exclusive regulatory framework leading to limited competition, compliance with the Anti-Money Laundering/Countering Financing of Terrorism (AML/CFT) international standard, few rural payout stations, financial illiteracy, and the low utilization of cheaper, more modern technology, among other factors.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Remittances inflows as a share of GDP. Source: World Bank Migration and Remittances data

We illustrate the magnitude of these costs with Fig. 5, which presents the cost of sending money to Kenya for selected corridors. The figure reveals that it is more expensive to send funds from within the continent than externally. For example, the costs of sending US$200 from South Africa and Tanzania to Kenya are 14.3% and 13.1%, respectively, while sending the same amount costs 6.6% from the United Kingdom. Substantial variations also exist across corridors, as indicated by the cost of sending similar amounts of money from Rwanda, recorded at 5.5%, yet those in neighboring Tanzania can send the same amount at double the cost. High remittance-transfer costs not only encourage the use of informal channels, with negative implications for the financial sector, but also de-incentivize migrants from sending higher remittance flows.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Cost of sending money to Kenya by corridor in 2017. Source: Remittance Price Worldwide and Send Money Africa

Review of literature

Literature includes diverse arguments linking remittances to financial development, although most lean toward their potential to enhance financial inclusion, and especially for the unbanked lowest income earners in developing countries. One theory linking remittances and financial development is anchored in the financial literacy hypothesis. Proponents of this hypothesis argue that both remittance senders and recipients create a demand for the financial systems involved in international remittances, which can incentivize either or both parties to seek and interact with the financial institutions involved in other financial products beyond remittances. This will subsequently increase financial awareness both for the sender and recipient and can lead to the recipients’ demand for other financial products, such as savings, insurance, and mortgage services, among others. Increasing the possibilities for formal money transfer services as such could be one response to existing demand. The financial literacy perspective assumes that the exposure to—and knowledge of—financial services induces remittance recipients’ use of formal banking services (Brown et al. 2013; Toxopeus and Lensink 2008).

Karikari et al. (2016) further supports the positive relationship between remittances and financial intermediation by arguing that migrant transfers in excess of consumption expenditures are likely to be placed in savings, thus introducing recipient individuals to financial products and services, which could lead to enhanced financial development. Related to these arguments are postulations on how remittances provide an alternative option for financing entrepreneurs who do not qualify for credit in mainstream commercial banks. Over time, these entrepreneurs may become “bankable,” and influence commercial banks to compete for them. Similarly, Ambrosius and Cuecuecha (2016) summarize the connections between remittances and financial access. They posit that remittances function as a substitute for credit; in this case, remittance-receiving households’ different spending behavior is explained within a theoretical framework involving imperfect credit markets, in which remittances help poor households overcome the liquidity constraints that restrict investments in human or physical capital.

Considerable arguments on the supply side contend that regular remittance flows facilitate the creation of a credit history and connections that establish recipients’ creditworthiness; these current and potential remittance flows could possibly be considered as collateral in allocating credit (Giuliano and Ruiz-Arranz 2009; Toxopeus and Lensink 2008). Further, Anzoategui et al. (2014) corroborate this reasoning to argue that remittances might increase a household’s likelihood of obtaining a loan, as processing remittance flows provides financial institutions with information on the recipient households’ income. In this case, remittances potentially lower a client’s risk profile, as banks can obtain information on remittance recipients who are prospective loan clients. The bank can use this knowledge to further emphasize soft data, such as the client’s reliability and character. When remittances go through banks, clients can use both current and future inflows as “collateral” to access credit. If these banks accept such inflows as explained, loans could be covered—at least partially—by remittance inflows, thus lowering the bank’s risk and motivating payback and optimal project management. Moreover, remittance receipts’ deposited in banks increases these banks’ loanable funds, and consequently their ability to extend credit to both remittance- and non-remittance-receiving households (Brown et al. 2013; Motelle 2011).

Further arguments based on policy considerations contend that the government can encourage transfers through formal channels by removing income remittance taxes, relaxing exchange and capital controls, allowing domestic banks to operate overseas, providing identity cards for migrants, and providing financial products targeting the diaspora, among other incentives.Footnote 10 In cases in which the use of formal financial institutions are constrained by a lack of migrant documentation, governments can consider entering into bilateral agreements to facilitate the opening of bank accounts and using formal financial institutions. For example, Mexico’s Matrícula Consular de Alta Seguridad is an alternative form of identification issued to Mexicans that is also acceptable in US consulates (Toxopeus and Lensink 2008).

In contrast, some arguments indicate negative connections between remittances and financial development. For example, Brown et al. (2013) note that migrants could possibly distrust formal banking services due to reasons other than financial illiteracy, such as the avoidance of formal records of income flows occasioned by required AML/CFT compliance.Footnote 11 In this case, remittances may not be associated with the opening of bank accounts. Muktadir-Al-Mukit and Islam (2016) also discuss other negative views on the remittance-financial development nexus.

More recent theories have also focused on leveraging technology for financial inclusion, and especially in developing countries. Proponents of this assertion contend that adopting electronic payments can generate important cost reductions in the managing and safeguarding of cash, as well as in such money transmission services as remittances (Santos and Kvangraven 2017).

Many empirical studies have been conducted using both primary and secondary data. For example, Li et al. (2014) use primary data to indicate that remittance-receiving households are more likely to have savings accounts and use bank accounts than households that do not receive remittances. The Table 1 below summarizes some of these empirical findings, including the methods used and countries covered.

Table 1 Summary of International Empirical Evidence on remittances-financial development relationship

Data, variables and methodology

The study uses quarterly data obtained from the Central Bank of Kenya and the Kenya Bureau of Statistics from 2006 to 2016. This data was selected based on its availability in our estimation frequency and based on standard variables as identified in literature (Beck et al. 2018; IMF 2005). Consistent with previous studies, we use the ratios of bank deposits to GDP and credit to the private sector to GDP, the number of bank accounts and mobile transactions, value of mobile transactions, number of mobile agents, and the number of bank branches as proxies for financial development and financial inclusion, and as dependent variables (Ito and Kawai 2018; Camara and Tuesta 2014; Ayadi et al. 2013; Afi 2013; World Bank 2006). The remittance variable is separately regressed against each of the dependent variables. Our control variables include inflation, real GDP, the exchange and interest rates, and trade openness-TOPEN, (Al-Tarawneh 2016).Footnote 12

Following from previous studies, the basic general model is specified below:

$$ {FIND}_t={\alpha}_0+{\beta}_1\operatorname{Re}{m}_t+{\beta}_2{X}_t+{\varepsilon}_t $$
(1)

where FinD represents financial development variables, Rem represents remittance variables, and X represents all control variables in all models. Eq. 1 is then reformulated into a long-run relationship, as represented in Eq. 2:

$$ {\gamma}_t={LFinD}_t-{\alpha}_0-{\beta}_1L\operatorname{Re}{m}_t-{\beta}_2{X}_t+{\varepsilon}_t $$
(2)
$$ \Delta {LFinD}_t={\delta}_0+\sum \limits_{i=1}^p{\rho}_i\Delta {LFinD}_{t-i}+\sum \limits_{i=0}^q{\delta}_i\Delta L\operatorname{Re}{m}_{t-i}+\sum \limits_{i=0}^m{\tau}_i\Delta {LX}_{t-i}+{Z\gamma}_{t-1}+{\varepsilon}_t $$
(3)

The reformulation of Eqs. 2 and 3 results in an ARDL specification, as noted in Eq. 4 (Tung 2015; Karamelikli and Bayar 2015):

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\Delta {LFinD}_t={\alpha}_0+{\beta}_1{LFinD}_{t-1}+{\beta}_2L\operatorname{Re}{m}_{t-1}+{\beta}_n{LX}_{t-1}+\sum \limits_{i=1}^p{\rho}_i\Delta {LFinD}_{t-i}+\sum \limits_{i=0}^q{\delta}_i\Delta L\operatorname{Re}{m}_{t-i}\\ {}+\sum \limits_{i=0}^m{\tau}_i\Delta {LX}_{t-i}+{\varepsilon}_t\end{array}} $$
(4)

where LFinD represents the log of financial development variables, LRem is the log of remittances, and LX represents the log of the control variables in the model, as previously described. Further,

p, q and m are optimal lag lengths;

ρi, δi, and τi are the ARDL model’s short-term dynamics;

β1, β2,..., and βn are long-run multipliers;

Δis the first difference operator;

α0, is a constant term; and

εtis the white noise error term

In line with previous studies, other factors affecting financial development include: real GDP, trade openness, the consumer price index (CPI), exchange rate and interest rate (Polat 2018; Karikari et al. 2016; Ayadi et al. 2013; Chinn and Ito 2006). We include trade openness as many previous studies have identified its importance in fostering financial development, (Antonio et al. 2014; Kim et al. 2010; Siong 2009).Footnote 13 The increase in trade openness generates a demand for new financial products, including instruments for trade finance and the hedging of risks. Simultaneously, trade openness may cause macro-level uncertainty and unfavorably influence the financial development-economic growth connection (Rehma et al. 2015; Raza 2014; Antonio et al., 2014); therefore, the a priori sign for this variable is ambiguous. Trade openness constitutes the total of exports and imports divided by GDP, (Qamruzzaman and Jianguo 2017).

We also include the CPI, which measures the average price of the consumer goods and services a household purchases. Several studies indicate that high inflation erodes savings returns, leading to reduced incentives to save, and hence, fewer savers and savings amounts, (Dash and Kumar 2018; Gashe 2017; Muradoglu and Taskin 1996). Consequently, the borrowing pool and credit allocation shrinks with negative implications for the financial sector. This challenge is aggravated in financial markets where collateral is required for efficient borrowing and lending, as too few savings can inhibit the accumulation of collateral and impede growth-enhancing financial intermediation. Moreover, periods of high inflation are often followed by tight monetary policy, which implies high interest rates with potentially inefficient financial markets. High inflation also hampers long-term contracting, and subsequently induces financial intermediaries to maintain incredibly liquid portfolios (Akosah 2013; Manoel, 2011). Thus, we expect a negative relationship between inflation and financial development.

Works by McKinnon (1973) and Shaw (1973) encompass the relationship between interest rate (INT) and financial development. The two authors argue that financial repression—in the form of interest rate ceilings, high reserve ratios, and directed credit—lead to low savings and credit rationing, and hence, low financial depth in most developing countries. The subsequent liberalization theory is hinged on the premise of a real rate of interest adjusting to equilibrium levels, thereby enabling expanded savings and a real supply of credit with positive implications on financial deepening. We used the deposit rate to capture the effect of interest rate liberalization with an anticipated positive sign, as the interest rate’s deregulation was meant to increase yields in deposit rates and result in increased savings—and hence, increased financial depth.

The relationship between economic growth and financial development based on demand-following theories is positive. According to these theories, increased demand for financial services induces growth in the financial sector as the real sector develops. Economic growth generates both additional and new demands for financing, which causes a supply response in the financial system’s growth. Therefore, a lack of financial institutions indicates a lack of demand for their services, (Sahoo 2013; Huang 2011; Al-Naif 2012; Ghosh and Banerjee 1998; Stammer 1972; Patrick 1966).

Equation 4 represents a standard way of specifying an unrestricted error-correction model, which captures both the short- and long-run relationships among this study’s variables. We then test the null hypothesis regarding the relationships among variables.

H0: β1 = B2 =  …  = βn = 0 (In that the long-run relationship does not exist) against the alternative H1: β1 ≠ 0B2 ≠ 0, … , βn ≠ 0 (In that the long-run relationship exists). A rejection of the null hypothesis implies that such a long-run relationship exists. We test this hypothesis by comparing the F-statistics obtained from Wald’s test with the critical values for small samples, or between 30 to 80 observations, as provided by Narayan (2005).

Discussion of results

This section presents unit root test results, as displayed in Table 2.Footnote 14 We then estimate the ARDL model as well as the long-run model with different dependent variables in each equation.Footnote 15 We consider five dependent variables representing financial development, and correspondingly estimate five different equations. We use credit to the private sector as a share of GDP (CRED), bank deposits as a share of GDP, the number of bank accounts and bank branches, and the value of mobile transactions as separate dependent variables in the five separate equations. Tables 34, and 5 reports the co-integration results while Tables 6 and 7 present the results from the long-run and error-correction models, respectively.

Table 2 Augmented Dickey-Fuller test results for unit roots
Table 3 Credit to the private sector as a share GDP is the dependent variable
Table 4 Value of mobile transactions is the dependent Variable
Table 5 Number of bank accounts is the dependent variable
Table 6 Estimated long-run coefficients
Table 7 Econometric results for the error correction model

Unit root tests

This sub-section presents the unit root tests and ARDL findings based on different indicators of financial development as dependent variables. Although ARDL models do not require unit root tests, these tests are conducted to ensure that the variables considered in our models are either I(0) or I(1), as the inclusion of I(2) variables can collapse the system, rendering the computed F-statistics invalid, (Nkoro and Uko 2016; Sharaf 2014; Narayan 2005; Pesaran et al. 2001). To satisfy the condition for using the ARDL model, we transform all our variables except interest rates into logs, and use an augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test to establish that all variables are either I(1) or I(0) as reported in Table 2.

Co-integration tests

We conducted five co-integration tests based on the five different dependent variables, but we only present the results that exhibit long-run relationships between the dependent and independent variables. Table 3 reveals that credit to the private sector as a share of GDP was considered as the dependent variable in testing for the presence of co-integration or a long-run relationship between the dependent and explanatory variables. We conducted an F-test by restricting the independent variables’ coefficients at a one-period lagged level as equal to zero.

The results in Table 3—and specifically as noted in the second row—indicate F-statistics of 5.28, which is greater than the upper- and lower-bound values, signifying the presence of a co-integration between credit to the private sector as a share of GDP and its determinants. In Tables 4 and 5, we replaced credit to the private sector as a share of GDP with the value of mobile transactions (Mob) and number of bank accounts as other indicators of financial development or inclusion, respectively. In both cases, we obtained F-statistics greater than the upper bound values, at 5% and 1 % levels of statistical significance for the value of mobile transactions and the number of bank accounts, respectively. Therefore, we draw similar conclusions regarding the presence of long-run relationships between the dependent and independent variables in both cases.

However, our F-test results changed when we substituted credit to the private sector as a share of GDP, with deposits to GDP and the number of bank branches as indicators of financial development. Our results in this case were inconclusive, with F-statistics of 3.47 and 3.42 when the deposits to GDP or the number of bank branches are the dependent variable, respectively; this is lower than our upper-bound values, at 5% and 1 % significance levels. These values lie between the lower- and upper-bound values provided by Narayan (2005), indicating inconclusive results.

The long-run model’s econometric results

This section presents the coefficients of the long-run equations for the credit to the private sector to GDP, value of mobile transactions, and number of bank account equations. Although we did not report the Wald’s test results for the numbers of mobile agents and mobile transactions, we use them separately as dependent variables by replacing the value of mobile transactions in each case; Table 6 reports the long-run results. Accordingly, Table 6 reports the results of five different models from Columns 2 through 6, in which we use five different dependent variables as indicators of financial depth and inclusion.

The relationship between remittances is positive and significant in all the models presented in Table 6. This implies that remittances and financial development are important for both financial depth and inclusion, as the relationship persists regardless of the indicator for financial development. Column 2 displays the credit to the private sector as a share of GDP, and the positive coefficient of remittances implies that higher remittances increase savings, therefore facilitating more credit to the private sector. A similar interpretation is applicable to the relationship between remittances and number of bank accounts, as displayed in Column 6. This result is anticipated, as remittance flows provide opportunities for recipients to open bank accounts and access financial systems, and particularly in areas where banks serve as the primary remittance-paying agents. Moreover, received remittances can potentially expose both banked and unbanked remittance recipients to new financial products. These results corroborate findings from Fromentin (2017), Karikari et al. (2016), and Aggarwal et al. (2011), among others.

Columns 3 through 5 involve proxies for mobile remittance transfers, and the results seem to suggest that higher remittances boost the values and numbers of mobile transactions, as well as the number of agents involved in mobile transfers. This strong, positive relationship implies that more remittances are channeled through mobile technologies; further, migrants who take advantage of the low costs and convenience of mobile transfer channels can possibly increase their remittances through formal channels and subsequently deepen their financial inclusion, and especially in rural areas. As rural areas have substantial mobile coverage but low formal services through banks, this result suggest a potentially enhanced role of remittances on financial inclusion in such areas.

Moreover, mobile-to-mobile remittances also save costs related to travel and man-hours that would otherwise be wasted in traditional queues. These saved costs can subsequently boost remittance flows. The positive relationship between all indicators of mobile transactions and remittances further reflect the enabling regulatory environment that has led to the growth and acceptance of online remittance platforms, such as Skrill and Worldremit, which facilitate international remittance transfers. This analysis and its results are also supported by Kim et al. (2018), Ouma et al. (2017), International Fund for Agricultural Development-IFAD and the World Bank (2015), Mago and Chitokwindo (2014), and Mashayekhi (2014), among others.

The results demonstrate that the level of economic activity as represented by real GDP positively affects financial development, but its coefficient is only significant in the two models in which private sector credit to GDP and number of bank accounts are used as dependent variables. The results conform to the demand-pulling hypothesis of financial development as postulated by Patrick (1966). The relationship between trade openness and financial development is also positive as expected, and significant in all models except one. This result supports the theory that trade openness increases the demand for new financial products, including instruments for trade finance and the hedging of risks. Ho and Iyke (2018), Kim et al. (2010), and Law and Demetriades (2004) found similar results. The interest rate’s coefficient is positive and significant as expected in Column 2 of Table 6, in which we used private sector credit to GDP as the dependent variable. However, when we replace private sector credit to GDP with the value and number of mobile transactions, the sign becomes negative, with a significant coefficient. A plausible explanation for this negative relationship between the deposit interest rate and mobile transactions would be that, as the commercial bank deposit interest rates increases, most bank deposits are kept in bank accounts, rather than in mobile accounts. Thus, more bank deposits will attract more savings toward commercial banks, rather than in mobile accounts where they earn no returns. The coefficient of inflation has a negative sign, as anticipated, but it is not significant in any of the models, except where we use the number of mobile agents as the dependent variable.

Table 7 presents the results of the short-term model and the error correction term, the latter of which represents the dependent and independent variables’ adjustment speed to their long-run equilibrium following any shock. The coefficient measures the proportion of the last period’s equilibrium error, which is corrected in the current period. The coefficient is negative and statistically significant in all estimated models, implying a convergence in the variables’ long-run dynamics. The error-correction term in Column 2 implies that 11% of the last period’s disequilibrium is corrected in the current period. In the case of a shock, it takes nearly ten quarters for the dependent variable and independent variables to restore their long-run equilibrium relationship. Columns 3 and 4 indicate that approximately 39% of the last period’s disequilibrium is corrected in the current period; in this case, it takes approximately two and half quarters for the variables’ equilibrium relationship to be restored.

In the last column, approximately 9% of the last period’s disequilibrium is corrected in the current period, while it takes approximately 10 quarters for the equilibrium relationships among the variables to be restored. The results also demonstrate that remittances negatively affect financial development and inclusion in the short-run. This can be explained by arguing that when migrants initially move, they focus on sending money for consumption, but as time passes and their families are stable, the possibilities of savings and increased deposits occur, an outcome visible in our long-run results.

Conclusions

Remittance flows have steadily increased over the last two decades to developing countries in general, and Kenya in particular, necessitating a review of the importance of the various remittance channels that impact growth aside from consumption smoothing. Thus, research on remittances’ possible role in various macro-dimensions: the balance of payments through boosted foreign exchange reserves; increased financial inclusion and development through increased savings and enhanced bank deposits; and economic growth through increased diaspora investments has dominated the last one decade.

Against this background, this study examined the relationship between remittances and financial development using the ARDL co-integration technique on quarterly data from Kenya covering the period of 2006 to 2016. The study considered private sector credit as a share of GDP, indicators of mobile transactions, the number of bank accounts and bank branches, and commercial bank deposits to GDP as dependent variables. The results revealed a sensitivity to the indicators used for financial development. They also demonstrated co-integration relationships between the dependent variable and explanatory variables when private sector credit as a share of GDP, indicators of mobile transactions, and the number of bank accounts were used as dependent variables. However, no long-run relationship could be observed when deposits to GDP and the number of bank branches were used as dependent variables.

Therefore, our long-run models only considered those equations that indicated a co-integration between the dependent variable and the independent variables of interest. These model results demonstrated a strong, positive connection between remittances and financial development, regardless of the indicators selected for the latter. This relationship persisted when private sector credit as a share of GDP, the value of mobile transactions, number of mobile agents, number of mobile transactions, and number of bank accounts were used as dependent variables. This remittance-financial development connection implies that the potential exists for remittance flows to encourage the opening of bank accounts, which will enhance savings and influence credit allocations in Kenya. Thus, mobile technologies can be used as an international remittance transfer channel to expose the unbanked population to both existing and new financial products. This will ultimately promote the opening of bank accounts and positively impact financial depth and inclusion.

These results reveal a policy window for not only reducing remittance transfer costs by continuing to expand the regulatory space for more international remittance payment platforms, but also increasing remittance flows and financial inclusion. Therefore, it may be important to promote policies that encourage the use of modern, less expensive technology in the remittance-transfer business. Given remittances’ importance in credit allocations, commercial banks may find it useful to increase tailored products for migrants and tap into the huge unexploited potential of the diaspora that can increase their deposit base and enhance savings and credit creation. These would include offering higher interest rates on deposits of remittances compared to local currency deposits to encourage the opening of diaspora accounts in local banks, as well as considering regular remittance flows as collateral for credit allocation. Additionally, an avenue worth exploration in Kenya involves the reactivation of bonds for diaspora participants to raise funds for infrastructure projects. This would simultaneously provide an opportunity for these participants to not only accumulate savings, but also invest and participate in national development .Footnote 16 Other relatively new diaspora frontiers not yet fully exploited include evolving the drive for increased remittances, savings mobilization, and the investment of diaspora funds through the Kenya Savings and Credit Co-operative Societies (SACCO)s, which have substantial potential to enhance financial inclusion in Kenya. This initiative’s success would depend on a collaboration among the Ministry of Industry, Trade and Cooperatives; the Ministry of Foreign Affairs; the Ministry of Labor and Social Protection; the National Treasury; diaspora organizations; and private sector developers. These groups would ultimately develop strategies on the following issues, among others: the identification, mapping, profiling, and registration of the diaspora; the mobilization of savings; and the provision of information, education, and sensitization and training of the diaspora on prospects not yet tapped through the cooperative movement.Footnote 17

This study’s main limitation is assessment of remittances channeled through informal channels. Whether the amounts are substantial is not clear as data through these channels is unrecorded implying possibilities of understatements, which would be impeding capacities of policy makers to design appropriate policies aiming at leveraging remittances on development. Further research covering possibilities of capturing this data would enrich knowledge in this area and would trigger interest across the private sector, academia, policy makers and government in general.