Introduction

Greenwood and Jovanovic (1990) suggest that financial development directly affects economic welfare over time. In contrast, Kuznets (1955) claims that investment in human capital is a conduit that enhances economic agents’ welfare. Both theoretical suppositions indicate the importance of improving economic welfare through financial development (FD) and increased investment in human capital. With foreign capital inflows (FCF) increasing recently in sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) (Table 1), it leaves one to wonder if these flows improve FD to augment an investment in human capital, or whether FD induces foreign capital to enhance the investment in human capital. This study empirically examines the potential interaction effect between FD and FCF on economic welfare enhancement in SSA.

Table 1 Foreign capital flows to SSA

Foreign capital augments domestic resources in many ways, such as by improving capital stock, technology, managerial skills, entrepreneurial ability, brands, and access to markets (Thirwall 2000). Thus, increasing FCF should enhance the economic welfare of economic agents. Notwithstanding the rising trend in inflows, their effect on economic welfare is not well understood, especially in the context of SSA.

This study argues that the inflows affect welfare through FD, albeit with a lag. This is because they create additional demand for financial services, which in turn compels the financial sector to develop innovative products and ultimately improve how the financial system functions. The finance welfare hypothesis suggests that the level of FD affects the accumulation of both human and physical capital, which enhance economic welfare (Galor and Zeira 1993; Banerjee and Newman 1993; Kuznets 1955). Moreover, FCF spur the financial system to develop financial derivatives tailored for such inflows (Hausmann and Fernández-Arias 2000; Prasad 2007; Gruber and Kamin 2009). Thus, at this stage of financial system development economic welfare begins to improve (Greenwood and Jovanovic 1990), suggesting a potential feedback effect of FD on FCF.

FD seeks, among other things, to attract capital inflows that improve economic agents’ welfare (Kai and Hamori 2009; Enowbi Batuo et al. 2010; Asongu 2013; Tita and Aziakpono 2016). Recent studies on SSA establish the effects of FD from financial globalization, financial depth, and financial efficiency on economic welfare (Kai and Hamori 2009; Enowbi Batuo et al. 2010; Asongu 2013; Tita and Aziakpono 2016). Nevertheless, these studies focus on GDP and related welfare indicators (income inequality) rather than specific welfare-enhancing variables that constitute an investment in human capital to improve economic welfare. Moreover, these studies consider direct links without any intermediaries between FD and economic welfare. A fall in the per-unit cost of operations at various levels of FD directly improves economic welfare.

In contrast, this study focuses on the interaction effect of FD and FCF on the intermediary factors that enhance economic welfare. I primarily contribute to the existing literature by ascertaining the interaction effect on the human economic welfare-enhancing indicators of education, health, consumption, and remittances. Education places economic agents in highly marketable positions for jobs and has a return that far outweighs its expenditures, among other effects (Kuznets 1955; Galor and Zeira 1993). Healthcare considerably determines the potential of an economic agent to secure gainful employment (Kleiman 1974; Newhouse 1977; Jacobs and Slans 2010). Consumption is a better measure of welfare than income-based indicators are. This is because it determines availability and accessibility, and denotes economic agents’ health status while income-based indicators do not (World Bank 2016). Remittances help the poor to obtain the education and employment required to enhance economic welfare over time (Addison 2005; Russell et al. 1990). These benefits represent investments in human capital intended to enhance economic agents’ welfare, though they are not prominent in the macroeconomics and international finance empirical literature. This study applies the principal component analysis (PCA) to create a single index, which I call the human economic welfare enhancement (HEWE) index, to investigate the role of FD in improving these welfare-enhancing indicators amidst increasing FCF to SSA.

The rest of the study is structured as follows. Section 2 reviews the relevant literature. Section 3 outlines the methodology. Section 4 discusses the results and Section 5 concludes the study with some policy implications.

Literature review

From a theoretical perspective, FCF interact with domestic FD to enhance economic welfare. Welfare improves when a considerable level of FD induces FCF. These increasing inflows compel the financial system to develop financial derivatives that meet the demands of foreign and domestic firms. The interaction creates an inverted U-shaped relationship between FD and economic welfare (Greenwood and Jovanovic 1990). Greenwood and Jovanovic (1990) assert that sourcing funds from financial intermediaries comes with a cost, which is especially high when the intermediaries are in the infant stages of development in which only the relatively few rich members of the population can have savings and benefit from the financial services. The process widens the rich-poor income gap and causes economic welfare to deteriorate.

Over time, as economic growth continues, there is an increased demand from the real sectors for services from financial intermediaries. The increase in demand brings about competition, efficiency and a reduction in the transaction costs of financial intermediaries, thereby enabling the poor to access financial services to invest in human or physical capital. Therefore, the interaction increases the capital inflows and liquidity of the financial sector, decreases the cost of financial transactions, and increases domestic credit for investments in human and physical capital. Hence, investment in education and training improves the marketability of labor for gainful employment. On the other hand, investment in physical capital increases the capital-labor ratio, yielding higher productivity and income.Footnote 1

The higher income due to the interaction effect may affect the health status of economic agents. On the one hand, nutritious foods, clean water, sanitation, education and medical care become more affordable and increases economic agents’ life expectancy (Deaton 2003; Deaton 2004). Moreover, health and education outcomes may improve due to the medical and educational knowledge spillovers from this interaction (Bitzer and Kerekes 2008; Ang and Madsen 2013). Furthermore, interactions that affects the market for domestic firms’ products may improve health and education conditions: the availability of pharmaceuticals, medical equipment and industry-tailored education reduces health complications and provides the entrepreneurial skills for job creation. Hence, economic agents’ ability to afford good health care and education may reduce the rate of increase in government discretionary current expenditures on education and health, leading them to re-prioritize their recurrent spending in each fiscal period. This reduction may indicate improved economic welfare in the short run, but may have welfare-reducing consequences over time, when the effect of rate reduction outweighs the affordability effect.

Developing economies’ competition for more capital inflows to enhance the interaction between capital inflows and FD to improve welfare may lead to tax incentives (Cleeve 2008). Tax incentives aiming to induce more inflows may reduce government revenue and consequently reduce its recurrent expenditure on education and health. In addition, rising rates of inflation may reduce government real expenditures on health and education. This usually occurs when prices rise such that the government rate of increase in recurring education and health expenditures fall short of that of inflation. In some cases, governments may prefer to increase expenditure on transportation networks and public security and neglect health and education (Gemmell et al. 2008; Herzer and Nunnenkamp, 2012). Thus, decreasing the government’s current expenditure on education and health in the interaction could indicate a short-run welfare reduction.

Moreover, domestic firms’ productivity in developing countries may fall: multinational enterprises (MNEs) have lower marginal cost due to the firm-specific advantage of providing unique services. This advantage increases the demand for foreign products while reducing the demand for domestic products and sending inefficient firms out of business (Aitken and Harrison 1999; Djankov and Hoekman 2000; Damijan et al. 2003). Thus, domestic firms have difficulty competing with foreign firms due to the latter’s use of advanced technology and higher skilled-labor. This may result in a fall in domestic firms’ revenue and the eventual collapse of some firms. The fall in revenue and collapse of firms may decrease economic agents’ incomes. These agents find it difficult to afford the health and education services they need, thereby requiring an increase in the government’s discretionary current expenditure to enhance economic welfare.

Furthermore, the pollution-haven hypothesis posits how cost-effective, but pollution-intensive firms, invests in developing countries with lower environmental standards (Eskeland and Harrison 2003). The education to ensure that environmental standards rise and that victims of pollution receive the appropriate health care require increasing government discretionary expenditure on health and education. Thus, the increased government spending in these areas provides social insurance against the adverse effects of the interaction between FCF and FD. Therefore, an increase in government spending on health and education may indicate an attempt to mitigate the welfare-reducing effects of this interaction (Rodrik 1998, p.997). Hence, the variability of income due to FCF and its interaction with FD correlates with economic welfare. The state of economic welfare highly determines the government’s discretionary recurrent expenditures on health and education.

Moreover, Friedman’s (1957) permanent-income hypothesis (PIH) suggests the relevance of the interaction effects to consumption and economic welfare. This hypothesis posits that an economic agent smooths his or her consumption over his or her lifetime based on the current and expected income. That is, agents will maintain a given level of consumption throughout their lifetimes, regardless of his or her current income, by saving the excess current income above the consumption level while an income below the given consumption level leads agents to borrow to finance spending. However, the agent’s borrowing decision depends on the investments in human (education, training, and experience) and physical (shares, bonds, machines, equipment, or building) capital. These investments determine the agent’s ‘expected long-term average income’ (permanent income) that guides the borrowing decision. Nevertheless, in low-savings economies, the interaction effects may augment domestic savings to meet the demand for domestic credit. Thus, the interaction of foreign capital and FD makes it highly possible to improve economic agents’ incomes and to meet their borrowing demand. These funds facilitate the investments that warrant higher levels of consumption.

The interaction of FCF and FD potentially increases remittances received for welfare enhancement, which enhance welfare. FCF create an avenue for funds to move across borders through the economy’s financial sector. The sector serves as a conduit for MNEs to facilitate the movement of funds and equipment from their host or other foreign countries to the recipient economies. The movement then necessitates a new or efficient channel to transmit funds to the recipients. The new or efficient means of funds transfer facilitate an increase in the remittances received from the domestic economic agents residing in these foreign countries. On the contrary, inefficient means to transfer funds may increase financial charges on remittances and negatively affect the remittances received. Thus, the interaction of capital inflows and FD may negatively affect the remittances received to enhance economic welfare. Notably, SSA has a relatively higher cost to receive remittances due to relatively smaller amount of FCF it receives relative to other regions.Footnote 2

Empirically, Kappel (2010) suggests that an increase in government spending does not narrow the differences in economic welfare in low-income countries. However, he confirms the government spending and an effective stock market are drivers that reduce differences in economic welfare in high-income countries. Recent studies aim to establish the threshold effects of FD on income inequality (Kim and Lin 2011; Tan and Law 2012a, 2012b; Law et al. 2014). Kim and Lin (2011) establish the non-linear threshold effect of FD by using an instrumental variable threshold regression method to analyze panel data on developed and developing countries. Their results are consistent with Greenwood and Jovanovic’s (1990) inverted U-shaped hypothesis. They suggest that below a threshold level of FD, the plight of the poor will worsen disproportionately. Nevertheless, this difficulty dissipates as a country reaches a threshold level of FD. Tan and Law (2012a, 2012b) also use the threshold effect approach, but find results that contradict Greenwood and Jovanovic’s (1990) inverted U-shaped hypothesis. Law et al. (2014) suggest that the level of efficiency and effectiveness of institutions determine the extent to which FD narrows the differences in economic welfare. They conclude that without high institutional quality, financial intermediaries will not be able to reduce income inequality. However, these studies fail to account for investment in human capital as a principal driver that narrows income inequality as the financial system develops.

In the context of SSA’s abundant natural resources, the region attracts FCF mainly due to its enhanced investment and business climate, improving macroeconomic conditions, privatization, preferred trade schemes, and reformed legal framework (Chea 2011). Furthermore, the opportunity to produce in sectors at a low cost relative to the U.S. and the E.U., low cost production for export under the African Growth and Opportunity Act (AGOA), and EU’s Everything but Arms (EBA) policy make SSA an attractive destination for export-oriented investors (Mlachila and Takebe 2011). SSA developing economies saw six-fold increase in private capital inflows since 2000, to the tune of $75 billion in 2007. Despite the financial crisis, which registered a net withdrawal of $562 million in portfolio equity, private capital increased to $79.5 billion in 2008 and then to $135 billion in 2013 (WDI, 2015). The question that empirically remains unanswered is how economic welfare responds to foreign capital flows across borders.

Considerable cross-country empirical studies on the relationship between finance and welfare in SSA exists. These studies use income inequality as a measure of economic welfare, in which a decline in income inequality as finance increases denotes improved economic welfare. Prominent among these authors are Kai and Hamori (2009), who find that economic welfare in the form of rising income inequality decreases due to globalization. However, countries with some requisite levels of education tend to reap the full benefits of globalization. These countries balance their benefits with the negative effects of rising income inequality. Moreover, globalization tends to neutralize the effect of global financial depth on reducing income inequality in developing countries because it benefits the rich rather than the poor.

Enowbi Batuo et al. (2010) and Gries and Meierrieks (2010) suggest that FD reduces the differences in economic welfare between the rich and the poor due to a decline in income inequality. Moreover, Asongu (2013) reveals that though enhanced financial depth reduces income inequality, there is a positive relationship between financial efficiency and rising income inequality. He concludes that an efficient financial system does not improve the lives of the poor, but rather those of the rich. The rich tend to benefit from the large average loans size and deposits per capita in the course of FD due to their ability to provide collateral.

Conspicuously missing from this literature are studies of how the interaction of FD and FCF influences investment in human capital, which is a key driver that enhances welfare. In view of the general support for expenditures on education, health, household consumption, and remittances as a monetary measure of investment in economic welfare (Appendix 4), I first examine the effect of the interaction of FD and FCF on these individual variables. Then I use PCA to index them as a dependent variable to estimate the model. I subsequently analyze the effect of the interaction of FCF and FD on these welfare enhancing indicators and the index.

Model, empirical strategy, and data

Model specification

To identify the interaction effects of FD and FCF in SSA, I follow the standard practice in the welfare finance literature and specify my model as in Eq. (1). The model expresses human economic welfare as an index constructed using PCA and comprising government expenditure on education and healthcare, household consumption expenditures, and remittancesFootnote 3 as a function of FCF (a vector of official credit and foreign direct investment, FDI), the FD indicator, and the interaction between the two independent variables.

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}{HEWE}_{i,t}={\beta}_{c1}{FCF}_{i,t}+{\beta}_{c2}{FCF}_{i,t-1}+{\delta}_{c1}{FD}_{i,t}+{\delta}_{c2}{FD}_{i,t-1}+{\rho}_{c1}{\left({FCF}_{i,t}\ast {FD}_{i,t}\right)}_{i.t}\\ {}+{\rho}_{c2}{\left({FCF}_{i,t}\ast {FD}_{i,t}\right)}_{i.t-1}+{\varphi}_c{X}_{i,t}+{\omega}_c{z}_{i,t}+{\varepsilon}_{i,t}\end{array}} $$
(1)

where HEWEi, t is the human economic welfare index in real per capita terms. βc, δc, ρc, and φc are the parameters of interest, with the subscript “c” denoting their lags. c = 1 denotes the level variable coefficient and c = 2 denotes the coefficient of its first lag. FCFi, t is FCF as a ratio of GDP. I introduce lags due to the theoretical supposition that the effects of macro-financial variables are not always instantaneous. For example, not all components of FCF have an instant effect on FD and welfare; credit from foreign commercial banks should have an instant effect on banks’ capital adequacy ratios and a contemporaneous effect on economic welfare through credit. The effect on the welfare occurs after some time elapses. Moreover, FDI may have both instant and later effects on economic welfare: while the transfer of skills from the inflows takes time to occur, economic welfare instantly improves through the creation of new jobs, though the inability of domestic firms to compete well with foreign firms may offset the gain from job creation. FDi, t is the FD indicator (domestic credit to the private sector; money supply) as a ratio of GDP, and FCFi, t ∗ FDi, t is the interaction term to establish whether FCF affect economic welfare as it interacts with FD. Xi, t is a vector of control variables, which include inflation and trade as a ratio of GDP. Inflation intends to capture the effects of changes in general price levels on the economic welfare variable (HEWEi, t). The trade/GDP ratio indicates the extent of openness to international trade. ωczi, t is the time dummy for the period under study (2000–2013) to capture the business cycle over the period and to mitigate possible cross-sectional dependence. All the variables are in natural logarithms. The error term εi, t captures the unobservable shocks to the welfare index (HEWEi, t). The unobservable time-invariant (fixed effect) country-specific characteristics (vi, t) such as demographics and the observation-specific errors (ei, t) constitute the error term (εi, t), specified as εi, t = vi, t + ei, t.

Empirical strategy

Identifying the parameters of the model in Eq. (1) is challenging. A notable identification challenge here is that of potential endogeneity, which when not treated well will result in biased estimates. For example, an improvement in HEWEi, t, such as via remittances and education, which plausibly correlates with higher income, could make it possible for agents to acquire collateral and access more credit. Therefore, it follows that domestic credit to the private sector possibly correlates with the error term of the dependent variable (HEWEi, t). Furthermore, higher HEWEi, t denotes healthy, educated and well-skilled human capital prepared to meet the demands and standards of FCF such as FDI, and hence a possible correlation between FCF and the error term of HEWEi, t. Moreover, an improved HEWEi, t, such as through consumption, potentially increases trade volumes. Therefore, there exists a potential correlation between trade/GDP and the error term of the dependent variable (HEWEi, t). These possible correlations between the independent variables and the error term of the dependent variable could bias the parameter estimates.

To overcome this identification challenge, I propose the system GMM estimator, which unlike other estimators, permits the use of lags of the potential endogenous independent variables as instruments. I use these instruments due to the difficulty of finding appropriate instruments that mitigate endogeneity issues. Moreover, when the sample includes fewer years than countries, the system GMM best mitigates endogeneity issues. Furthermore, using the Sargan/Hansen test is important when applying Dynamic Panel Data estimators because such estimators are instrumental variable methods. Using the Sargan/Hansen test to test the validity of the instruments is paramount ex-post GMM estimation (Roodman 2006). Moreover, a test within the estimator ascertains the state of autocorrelation in the idiosyncratic error term (εi, t). GMM estimation involving panel data test for autocorrelation has proven valid whenever researchers apply the Arellano-Bond test for autocorrelation. This test encompasses OLS and 2SLS provided that the regressors are not determined “ex-post” on the premise of future disturbances. However, this presupposition may be nullified in the fixed effect or the within-group regressions if T is small (Roodman 2006). In addition, GMM applies first differencing to transform Eq. (2), which helps to avoid inconsistency due to the weak instruments associated with fixed-effects instrumental variables (IV) estimators and to deal with possible correlation between the fixed effect and lagged dependent variable and other regressors such as the FD indicator and inflation. This is because it removes the time-invariant fixed-effect component from the model. Instrumenting the first-differenced lagged dependent variable with its past levels helps address the issue of autocorrelation.

Based on the system GMM estimator, I re-specify the empirical model (Eq. 1) as a Dynamic model.

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}{HEWE}_{i,t}={\alpha}_c{HEWE}_{i,t-1}+{\beta}_{c1}{FCF}_{i,t}+{\beta}_{c2}{FCF}_{i,t-1}+{\delta}_{c1}{FD}_{i,t}+{\delta}_{c2}{FD}_{i,t-1}\\ {}+{\rho}_{c1}{\left({FCF}_{i,t}\ast {FD}_{i,t}\right)}_{i.t}+{\rho}_{c2}{\left({FCF}_{i,t}\ast {FD}_{i,t}\right)}_{i.t-1}+{\varphi}_c{X}_{i,t}+{\omega}_c{z}_{i,t}+{\varepsilon}_{i,t}\kern0.5em \end{array}} $$
(2)

where HEWEi, t − 1 is the lag of the dependent variable. The remaining variables are the same as those in Eq. (1). I expect that foreign capital inflows (FCFi, t), being FDI or official credit, will be positive, which denotes a positive impact on real welfare-enhancement due to the transfer of skills and capital associated with such inflows. FDI for instance may shift government expenditure to provide social insurance against external risk (Rodrik 1998, p.997; Gemmell et al. 2008). However, the extent to which domestic firms will survive competition due to FDI will determine the feasibility of this positive expectation. Moreover, incentives like tax holidays or lower taxes intended to induce FCF such as FDI eventually reduces government revenue, which may affect the composition of its expenditure and decrease recurrent expenditures on education, health and other social expenditures (see Herzer and Nunnenkamp 2012). Further, the redirection of government expenditure to public safety and transportation to make an economy more FDI-friendly may reduce expenditure on education and health, thereby reducing welfare (Figlio and Blonigen 2000). I expect that the FD indicator (FDi, t), being domestic credit or the money supply, will be positive, in agreement with the theoretical supposition that it improves GDP by meeting the demands of an economy and thus provide the poor with the finance required to invest in education. The interaction term (FCFi, t ∗ FDi, t) and its lag help to establish how FCF affect welfare at the current level of SSA’s FD. FCF can take the form of foreign banks. Hence, an open economy with well-functioning legal institutions that ensure contract enforcement can induce such inflows. Its lag could have a similar effect because FD is a process. Thus, the level of FD highly determines how foreign financiers invest in the domestic economy to influence economic welfare. However, the difficulty of enforcing contracts and applying inhumane strategies to recover due loans may negatively affect income, consumption and economic welfare. Thus, the lag of the interaction term may affect economic welfare. Moreover, increasing general price levels may lead to negative coefficient on the interaction term (FCFi, t ∗ FDi, t) as the cost of borrowing tends to rise in this situation. Therefore, I expect the coefficient of (FCFi, t ∗ FDi, t) and its lag to take either a positive or negative sign because the level of FD can determine whether FCF have a negative or positive impact on the welfare enhancing variables.

Data and variables

The sample consists of 23 SSA countries (N = 23)Footnote 4 for the sample period of 2000–2013 (T = 14) based on data availability. I collected most data from the WDI (2015).

First, I created the HEWE index using PCA due to the strong correlation among the variables within each index (Table 6, Appendix 1). The HEWE index consists of remittances per capita (lnrempc), household consumption expenditure per capita (lnhcepc), government expenditure on health per capita (lngovhepc), and government expenditure on education per capita (lngoveepc), all as natural logarithms. The HEWE1 index created for HEWE explains 75% of the total variations in the original data. This denotes a reduction of the HEWE dimension to a quarter, though it preserves 75% of the information in the data. Moreover, HEWE1 is the only component with eigenvalues above unity and the only index with all constituent indicators scoring above the 0.3 or higher benchmark to determine the level of significance. Therefore, HEWE1 significantly represents the four chosen indicators and thus, the dependent variable for the estimable Eq. (2).

Second, due to limited data availability for many SSA countries, I use domestic credit and the money supply as proxies for FD. Credit to the private sector as a ratio of GDP is the most well known proxy in the literature due to its peculiar features. This variable has a strong correlation with income levels, ranging above 103% in high-income countries, four times higher than that of low-income countries (Levine and Zervos 1998). Moreover, it supports long-run economic growth and highly correlates with poverty reduction (World Bank 2012). In addition, the ratio of M2 to GDP measures the extent of monetization in an economic system.Footnote 5 These two variables fall short in determining access to bank finance, non-performing loans, and the extent of bank intermediation. Nevertheless, they can help clarify how FCF enhance economic welfare.

Third, FCFi, t is FCF. It indicates either FDI (the proxy for private capital inflows) or official credit inflows (World Bank, IMF, IBRD, IFC), expressed as a ratio of GDP. It measures the size of external debt relative to economic output. I obtain the interaction term (FCFi, t ∗ FDi, t) as the product of the FCF indicator (FDI or official credit) as a ratio of GDP and the FD indicator (domestic credit to the private sector or money supply) as ratio of GDP. I include this term in the model to assess how FCF enhance human economic welfare at a particular state of FD (Adeniyi et al. 2015). I focus on FDI or official credit inflow as an indicator of FCF because SSA economies uniquely identify FDI and official credit as the major sources of financing for domestic activities (Delechat et al., 2009). Official credit constitutes the largest proportion of FCF into SSA, followed by FDI (World Bank, 2015). Both official credit and FDI potentially affect liquidity in SSA economies. Due to the higher proportion and consistency of FDI and official credit flow compared to the other components of foreign capital, they potentially improve liquidity, income and savings, and enhance household consumption, firms’ revenue, and the financial sector’s turnover. Similarly, servicing official credit or foreign investment outflow could greatly affect the money supply and domestic credit because a government potentially borrows from the domestic credit market to smoothen its expenditure, thereby crowding-out the private sector. Firms face liquidity challenges as outflow occurs and the domestic currency tends to depreciate due to higher demand for foreign currency resulting from the outflow of funds. Thus, I expect that FDI or official credit will affect economic welfare in SSA compared to the impact of portfolio equity or private creditors. The model also includes an inflation variable, which reflects the annual percentage change in the cost to the average consumer for acquiring a basket of goods and services that may be fixed or change at specified intervals, such as yearly. Studies generally use the Laspeyres formula. Finally, I include trade as a percentage of GDP as a proxy for trade openness. It is the sum of the exports and imports of goods and services measured as a share of GDP.

Empirical results and analysis

Effect of FCF and FD on economic welfare

I use FDI and official credit (OFFCR) as proxies for FCF, and domestic credit to the private sector (DOMCR) and money supply (MS) as proxies for FD, each as a ratio of GDP. The results in Tables 2 and 3 below show the parameter estimates of the variables of interest: the interaction terms (FDI*DOMCR, FDI*MS, OFFCR*DOMCR and OFFCR*MS) and their lags.

Table 2 Dynamic panel data estimation, one-step system GMM: Interaction effect of FDI and FD on HEWE
Table 3 Dynamic panel data estimation, one-step system GMM: Interaction effect of OFFCR and FD on HEWE

The statistical significance in Table 2 suggests a possible total effect of FDI on HEWE. FDI has a direct partial effect (βc1) and.

an indirect partial effect through FD (the product of ρc1 and mean FD). The total effect from Eq. 2 is ∂HEWEi, ∂FCFi, t = βc1/ + (ρc1  x mean of FDi, t), where FCF and FD are FDI and DOMCR, respectively, in Table 2, Model III and FCF and FD are FDI and MS, respectively, in Table 2, Model V. Table 4 presents these effects.

Table 4 Effect of FDI on HEWE, conditional on FD

Moreover, I consider portfolio inflows and private creditors, despite their “true zeros” values in the data for some of the sample countries. I measured these variables following the same process to measure FDI and official credit. The effect of portfolio inflow on human economic welfare was statistically insignificant; its interaction with FD had statistically insignificant effect on welfare enhancement (Table 12 in Appendix 5). I find similar results for private credit inflow: neither private credit nor its interaction with domestic credit had a statistically significant effect on welfare enhancement (Table 13 in Appendix 5).

Given the significant correlation among some of the components of FCF (FDI, portfolio equity, private credit and official credit inflows: Appendix 6 Table 14), I conducted PCA (Appendix 6 Table 15) to ascertain the interaction effect of the combined components of FCF and FD on welfare enhancement. The first (FCF1) and second (FCF2) principal components explained 34.05% and 29.71% of the total variations in FCF, with eigenvalues of 1.36191 and 1.18846, respectively (Table 15 in Appendix 6). Portfolio and FDI returned the highest (0.6796) and second highest (0.4591) highest eigenvectors, in absolute terms, of FCF1. For FCF2, official credit and FDI registered the highest (0.7056) and second highest (0.5710) eigenvectors in absolute terms. The eigenvalues of FC3 and FCF4 are less than one. I thus use FCF1, which has the highest eigenvector (0.3746) among the minimum eigenvectors of the components.

FCF1’s interaction with FD are consistent with that of FDI’s interaction with FD (Table 16 in Appendix 6). The level interaction term of FCF1 and FD is statistically significant and positive, while its lag is negative and statistically significant. Moreover, the partial indirect effects of FCF1 on economic welfare are positive, conditional on the level of FD (DOMCR (0.195) and MS (0.569); Table 17 in Appendix 6). These results are also consistent with those for FDI. Hence, I expect its results to follow the same pattern as that of FDI as an indicator of FCF. However, due to the prevalence of “true zeros” in the portfolio equity and private credit data, I use FDI and official credit as proxies of FCF for the analysis (Tables 2, 3 and 4).

Discussion

Models III and V of Table 2 suggest that DOMCR does not enhance economic welfare: both the level and lag of DOMCR are statistically insignificant. However, the level of FDI negatively affects HEWE, indicating the partial direct effect of FDI on economic welfare that occurs in the same year. First, household consumption reduces as FDI increases: it is difficult for domestic firms to compete with foreign firms due to the use of advanced technology, higher skilled labor, and relatively low marginal costs. These advantages over SSA’s domestic firms reduce their revenue and the eventual failure of the inefficient domestic firms. This in turn negatively affects household income, decreases consumption, and reduces economic welfare. In addition, governments increase their expenditures on transportation networks and public security to induce FDI at the expense of recurrent expenditures on health and education (Gemmell et al. 2008; Nagel et. al., 2015), which harms economic welfare. FDI’s negative effect significantly affects the consumption, education and health components of HEWE when DOMCR is the proxy for FD (Table 9 in Appendix 3). On the other hand, its negative effect significantly affects the health and education components when MS is the proxy for FD (Table 10 in Appendix 3). Hence, FDI’s direct partial effect is economic welfare reducing in the current period (Table 4).

However, FDI’s total effect is significantly positive (0.175) at the 1% level according to the mean domestic credit (Table 4) because the partial indirect effect of FDI on economic welfare is significantly positive (13.496) and outweighs its negative partial direct effect (− 13.321). The positive effects may be possibly results from the creation of additional employment, funds to augment inadequate domestic savings to meet domestic credit demands, the acquisition of credit to increase human and capital investments, higher incomes that increase household consumption, and increasing current government expenditure on education and health as social insurance to mitigate the undesirable effects of FDI. Moreover, remittances may potentially increase due to the relatively cheaper cost of funds transfer in the destination of the inflows. Therefore, the total effect of FDI is economic welfare enhancing in the current period. However, when I evaluate the total effect of FDI on HEWE in terms of the mean MS, its negative effect outweighs its positive effect in the current period (Table 4). Hence, the increased MS due to FDI has economic welfare-reducing effects in SSA.

On the contrary, the positive effect of the lag of FDI on HEWE denotes its partial direct effect on economic welfare after the first period (14.585 and 21.112 of Tables 2 and 4). This result is possibly due to additional employment, skills transfer, and the ability of some domestic firms to re-strategize to compete effectively with foreign firms after the first period. Consequently, household income improves and consumption increases, governments increase their recurrent expenditures on education and health to enhance the deteriorating welfare in the first period. FDI’s partial direct positive effect significantly affects the health, education and consumption components of HEWE when I use either DOMCR or MS as the proxy for FD (Tables 9 and 10 in Appendix 3). However, the total effect is negative (− 0.721) at the 1% significance level when I evaluate it in terms of the mean DOMCR. This negative result suggests that the partial indirect effect of the lag, conditional on the level of DOMCR development, is welfare reducing (− 15.306). The total negative effect possibly results from the welfare-reducing methods the financial sector employs to recover credits granted after one year, the more careful selection of borrowers to minimize adverse selection situations, adherence to strict monitoring of contract execution to minimize moral hazard, and opting for credit portfolios that yield higher returns at the expense of welfare-enhancing products. These actions may decrease household consumption and worsen health conditions, thereby making government expenditure disproportionately small relative to the higher cost of deteriorating health conditions and that households may leave private schools to join the public schools. This potentially makes government’s current expenditure on education disproportionately small relative to the cost (new teachers, additional salary, additional supervisors, more teaching materials, and textbooks) associated with the growing demand. Hence, the negative effect outweighs the positive effect and leaves a negative total effect on economic welfare. On the other hand, the total effect of the lag of FDI is positive (1.048) at the 1% significance level in terms of the mean MS: its partial direct effect on HEWE is significantly positive (21.112) and its partial indirect effect is significantly negative (− 20.064). This result suggests that the positive effect outweighs the negative effect and enhances economic welfare after the first period.

The positive coefficient of the level FDI*DOMCR and FDI*MS suggest that FDI positively affects its contemporaneous HEWE at the current state of SSA’s financial development (Table 4). These welfare-enhancing benefits emanate from the introduction of new or modified financial derivatives intended to attract more FDIs, increase credit to the private sector, and improve the monetization of the economy (Tan and Law 2012a, 2012b). Moreover, efficiency becomes a product of the competition associated with the FDI, which leads to cost minimization in the acquisition of information, contract enforcement, and financial transaction in the financial system. This state of FD enables economic agents to borrow to smoothen their consumption on the bases of their expected long-term average incomes. Hence, household consumption increases and enhances economic welfare. Moreover, investment in human capital (education, training, skills, and experience) and physical capital (shares, bonds, machines, factory buildings) determines the expected long-term average income. Governments tend to increase its recurrent expenditures on education to provide adequate knowledge to sustain the pattern of an economic agent’s lifetime consumption, develop safety measures for firms that meet international safety standards, and training to impart skills that meet the international standards. Governments also increase their recurrent expenditures on health to address the deterioration in general health due to the higher real cost of healthcare due to inflation and the stress of longer hours of work for a relatively higher income, resulting in less rest, less social interaction and unhealthy eating habits (junk food and alcoholism) (Nagel et al. 2015). Hence, the benefits of FDI for human economic welfare at the current state of financial development tend to outweigh any negative effect. The interaction significantly affects the consumption, health, and education components of the HEWE when I use DOMCR as the proxy for FD. When I use MS as the proxy for FD, the effect is significant on the health, education, and remittances components of HEWE (Tables 9 and 10 in Appendix 3).

However, the lag of the interaction term’s coefficient is significantly negative, suggesting that given the short-term maturity in financial derivatives tailored to households, the negative effects appear one year down the line of the interaction term on human economic welfare (Clarke et al. 2006). This welfare-reducing condition occurs mostly due to the high default rate of SSA households (Andrianova et al. 2011). This plausibly emanates from adverse selection, moral hazard, and the difficulty of enforcing loan contracts. These challenges caution banks to lend little while using stress-related strategies to recover financial assets in loans and related products (Andrianova et al. 2011). Furthermore, these conditions influence the financial system to trade welfare-related products for short-term lucrative investment portfolios to continue attracting more FCF. This eventually reduces consumption and economic welfare. Furthermore, a government’s attempt to stabilize FDI inflows results in FDI-inducing expenditures at the expense of recurrent expenditures on education and health. Ghana, for instance, increased its spending on road network development and strengthening the security and legal system to induce more FDI and to develop the financial system in 2015 and 2016. This policy direction was at the expense of recurrent expenditures on education and health, notably the non-payment of $24,139,747.24 for feeding grants to 134,300 senior high school students, resulting in an indefinite suspension of the re-opening of some schools,Footnote 6 and the non-payment of National Health Insurance Scheme (NHIS) claims to providers, resulting in the withdrawal and threat of withdrawal of services by some healthcare providers.Footnote 7 The economic welfare-reducing effects were very high in 2017, thereby compelling the government to pay for all claims in the 2017 fiscal year to enhance welfare. Furthermore, the interaction negatively affects remittances: FDI does not plausibly come from countries that host domestic economic agents, and these countries have relatively high cost to transfer money. The negative effect of the interaction significantly affects the consumption, education, health and remittances of the HEWE components (Tables 9 and 10 in Appendix 3).

The positive effect of the interaction term and the negative effect of its lag on HEWE further suggest that as more FDI flows into SSA, underdeveloped financial systems possibly offer both efficient and inefficient financial derivatives, which enhance welfare in the current year. However, the financial system innovates its financial derivatives in tune with FCF in the course of its development and tailors its products to suit lucrative short-term returns to maintain its profit margins due to rising bad debts from inefficient financial derivatives.Footnote 8 In this case, the financial system uses stress-related strategies to recover loans that are likely to be bad due to the legal system’s lax enforcement (Nissanke and Aryeetey 2008). The significantly negative coefficient of the interaction term’s first lag in Models III and V denote this welfare-reducing situation.

The interaction’s coefficient in Model V of Table 1, where MS is the proxy for FD is as significant as that of Model III; nevertheless, the coefficient of the lag of MS in Model V is negative and statistically significant (Tables 2 and 4). This exceptional result in Model V suggests that the MS in the previous year (L1 MS) has a negative effect on the current year HEWE. This suggests that MS tends to negatively affect HEWE after one year. Thus, productivity falls short of the increase in MS, and this gap eventually results in rising general price levels, and higher cost of living reduces real consumption, government education and health expenditures, and effects of remittances.

Official credit (OFFCR) and DOMCR are the proxies for FCF and FD, respectively, in Model III of Table 3. DOMCR’s coefficient is positive and statistically significant, but its lag is significantly negative. These results suggest that liquidity in the financial system improves due to OFFCR, which enhances HEWE through DOMCR. DOMCR positively and significantly affects the consumption, education, and health components of HEWE (Table 11 in Appendix 3). Nevertheless, the influence of its lag on HEWE is negative and significant. These results support Clarke et al.’s (2006) hypothesis of widening income inequality as financial development proceeds. Though DOMCR’s lag has an insignificant effect on the individual components of HEWE, it significantly affects the HEWE index (Table 11 in Appendix 3). Therefore, the results in Model III of Table 3 suggest that domestic credit supports economic welfare enhancing activities as new official credit flows into SSA. These inflows, among other things, improve financial derivatives to increase credit and monetize the economy. Nevertheless, the negative effect of the previous year’s DOMCR on current welfare is plausibly due to the haste among financial institutions to issue new and improved financial derivatives in the current years in their attempt to capture a considerable share of the market. However, banks may not thoroughly think through a supposedly new and improved financial derivative or properly analyze their risks before selling them to economic agents. These risks, along with the laxity associated with risk assessment and monitoring of loans in current years tend to reduce investment in welfare-enhancing activities after one year (Ocaya 2012).

Model V, which also uses official credit as a proxy for FCF and MS as the proxy for FD have equally positively statistically significant coefficients for its level of MS. The basic difference between Models III and V is that the lag in FD of Model V is statistically insignificant, while that of the former is statistically significant. Nevertheless, FD has a consistent and positive impact on HEWE when official credit is the main source of FCF because the increased money supply, which tends to improve the monetization of the economy, positively affect human economic welfare.

Impact of the interaction effect of FCF and FD on economic welfare

I use Models III and V of Table 2 to compute the predicted impact of FDI on economic welfare. These models use domestic credit and money supply as a measure of financial development, respectively. All variables are in natural logarithms. A partial derivative of each model gives the predicted impact when I take the derivative with respect to the interaction of FDI with financial development (FCFi, t ∗ FDi, t)i. t. The significant coefficient on FCFi, t ∗ FDi, t is (ρc1) for each model. Hence, ρc1 ∗ (meanFCFi, t ∗ meanFDi, t)i. t gives the predicted mean impact of FDI on economic welfare at various stages of financial development. I illustrate the results for these predictions in Figs. (1) and (2) for Models III and V of Table 1, respectively (Figs. 1 and 2 in Appendix 2).

The predicted ranges for the impact of FDI on economic welfare range from 0.005 to 1.2 and 0.008 to 2.3 in Figs. (1) and (2), respectively. Burundi registers the lowest impact and Liberia registers the highest impact in each range. These results indicate that FDI inflows to Burundi and Liberia, due to financial development, enhanced economic welfare by 0.005% and 1.2%, respectively. These results suggest that Liberia’s household consumption and remittances improved more than they did in Burundi when FDI inflows increased due to improved financial development. Moreover, Liberia may enhance economic welfare by increasing its current expenditures on health and education to mitigate any effects of FDI that may reduce welfare (Rodrik 1998, p.997). Nevertheless, Ghana’s 0.25 and South Africa’s 0.20 (Fig. 1) results do not necessarily suggest that the amount of FDI inflows are higher in aggregate terms in Ghana than in South Africa; rather, Ghana’s economic welfare is more sensitive to FDI inflows due to financial development than that in South Africa. The same analogy applies to Burundi and Liberia. Burundi and Kenya in the low-income economies of SSA were highly insensitive to the interaction effect of FDI and financial development on economic welfare. However, the remaining countries in this income category were equally sensitive to the effect on average as the countries in the lower-middle income group (Cameroon, Cote d’Ivoire, Nigeria, Lesotho, and Swaziland) and upper-middle income (Botswana and South Africa). Liberia (1.2%) and Seychelles (1.1%) in the low and upper-middle income economies were the most sensitive within their income categories.

Conclusion

The existing literature provides two main motivations for this study: the conduit by which FD transforms FCF into effects on economic welfare and the indicators for assessing improvements in welfare, which are GDP-based, though not all components of GDP have direct welfare enhancing effects. I apply the PCA method to create a single index, which I call the HEWE index; it consists of four direct welfare-enhancing indicators (education, health, household consumption and remittance received) without indirect welfare variables (like per capita GDP) as the conduit by which welfare improves. Thus, a decline in income inequality (a measure of improved welfare) may result from the favorable effect of FD, FCF, or their interaction with HEWE. Therefore, I investigate the role of FD in improving this direct welfare-enhancing index in the presence of FCF in SSA.

I employ the system GMM estimator to consider two cases of FCF and FD: the first in which the main source of FCF is either FDI or official credit, and the second in which FD takes the form of domestic credit to the private sector or the MS. Both the MS and domestic credit have significantly positive direct effects on economic welfare when official credit is the source of FCF. However, the effect of domestic credit on the welfare becomes negative after one year. Contrary to the effect of FD, the direct effect of official credit on welfare is statistically insignificant.

On the other hand, when FDI is the source of FCF, FD (domestic credit or money supply) has a statistically insignificant direct effect on economic welfare. However, the effect of FDI on welfare is statistically significant at all conventional levels: the partial indirect effect of its level on the welfare, which is conditional on the level of FD, is significantly positive; and the partial indirect effect of its lag on the welfare conditional on the level of FD, is significantly negative. These results are consistent with its total effect when I evaluate the mean domestic credit: the total effect of its level is significantly positive on economic welfare in the current period, while the total effect of its lag is significantly negative. These results are consistent with the level and lag interaction term coefficients: the interaction term of FDI and FD (domestic credit or money supply) is significantly positive in the current period, while this effect becomes negative after one year.

In conclusion, this study reveals the interaction effect between FDI and financial development on economic welfare. It further confirms that FDI affects economic welfare through credit to the private sector and the money supply positively at first, but become negative after one year. Additionally, the magnitude of its indirect effect on economic welfare, conditional on domestic credit to the private sector, is greater than that of its direct effect on welfare. Moreover, the magnitude of its indirect effect on welfare, conditional on the money supply, is less than that of its direct effct. Hence, the interaction improves the magnitude of the effect of domestic credit, and it decreases the magnitude of the effect of the money supply to enhance economic welfare compared to the direct effect of FDI on welfare. Thus, without financial development, FDI inflows rarely produce the desired welfare-enhancing results. I also establish that interaction between official credit and financial development has no effect on economic welfare. Though its inflow improves domestic credit, it becomes negative after one year. The consistent negative effects after one year possibly stem from financial intermediaries’ attempt to minimize risk and modify their target markets to minimize the effects of adverse selection and moral hazard in the first period. Additionally, the relatively high levels of inflation affect the real incomes and consumprion levels of economic agents in SSA. The negative effects could dissipate if SSA economies consider an intentional and balanced approach to induce FDI to the health and education sectors, encourage cost efficiency to make such services accessible to the SSA’s population, and adhere to inflation-related policies that enhance consumption and economic welfare.