1 Introduction

Let X be a real reflexive Banach space and U be a metric space, and KX, DU be two nonempty and closed sets. Let T : K → 2Dbe a nonempty-compact-valued mapping, i.e., T(x) is a nonempty compact subset for any xK, and upper semicontinuous on K. Let F : D × K × K → 2Ybe a set-valued map, where Y is a real normed space with an ordered cone C, that is, a proper, closed, and convex cone such that int C ≠ ∅.

The weak generalized vector equilibrium problem [14], abbreviated by WGVEP, is to find x ̄ K and ūT ( x ̄ ) such that

( WGVEP ) F ( ū , x ̄ , y ) - int C , y K .

For the WGVEP, its dual problem is to find x ̄ K such that

( DWGVEP ) F ( v , y , x ̄ ) int C , y K , v T ( y ) .

We denote the solution set of the WGVEP and the solution set of the DWGVEP by WS K and W S K D , respectively.

The strong generalized vector equilibrium problem [5, 6], abbreviated by SGVEP, is to find x ̄ K and ūT ( x ̄ ) such that

( SGVEP ) F ( ū , x ̄ , y ) - int C = , y K .

For the SGVEP, its dual problem is to find x ̄ K such that

( DSGVEP ) F ( v , y , x ̄ ) int C = , y K , v T ( y ) .

Similarly, we denote the solution set of the SGVEP and the solution set of the DWGVEP by SS K and S S K D , respectively. Obviously,

S S K W S K

The generalized vector equilibrium problem finds applications in economics, finance, image reconstruction, ecology, transportation, network, and elasticity in [7]. In particular, when T(x) is singleton, i.e., T is a single-valued map, then the WGVEP collapse to the problem considered in [14], and the SGVEP collapse to the problem considered in [5, 6]. In this case, based on the coercivity assumption, the existence of solution for the generalized vector equilibrium problem are deeply discussed, see [113]. Recently, by virtue of the recession method, Ansari established some necessary and/or sufficient conditions for the nonemptiness and boundedness of the solution set for the SGVEP [5]. Later, Farajzadeh and Amini established some sufficient conditions for the compactness and convexity of the solution set of the SGVEP without the requirement of the lower semi-continuity of the map y → F(x, y) [6]. Lin derived some existence results for the generalized vector quasi-equilibrium problem under pseudomonotonicity and u-hemicontinuity/l-hemicontinuity [11]. Al-Homidan proposed existence results for generalized vector quasi-equilibrium problems by establishing some new fixed point theorems and maximal element theorems [12, 13]. Since the WGVEP and the SGVEP are the generalizations of the generalized vector equilibrium problem when T is a single-valued map, it is natural to ask whether the existence of the solution and duality for the WGVEP and the SGVEP can be derived for that T(x) is multivalued, which constitutes the motivation of this article.

Generally, the existence of solution for the classical vector equilibrium problem is established under the strict feasibility condition which was originally used in scalar variational inequality and vector variational inequality [1417]. This technique can be extended to the scalar equilibrium problem [18]. On the other way, Hu and Fang extended the concept of strict feasibility to the classical vector equilibrium problem and established the nonemptyness and boundedness of the solution set of the C-pseudomonotone vector equilibrium problem if it is strictly feasible in the strong sense [19]. Motivated the study above, in this article, we first investigate the relations between solution set of the WGVEP (SGVEP) and solution set of the WDGVEP (SDGVEP) under the weakly (strongly) C-pseudomonotone condition. Furthermore, by introducing two new concepts for strictly feasible in the generalized sense to match the solvability of the WGVEP and the SGVEP, we establish some sufficient conditions to guarantee the nonemptyness and boundedness of the solution set for the generalized vector equilibrium problem if it is generalized strictly feasible. Our results generalize and extend some results of [18, 19] in some sense.

2 Notations and preliminaries

In this section, we recall some notations and preliminary results needed in the following sections. Let X, Y, K, D, C, T, F be same as in Section 1.

Definition 2.1 Let KX be a nonempty, closed, and convex set.

(i) The mapping F : K → 2Yis said to be C-convex if

α F ( x ) + ( 1 - α ) F ( y ) F ( α x + ( 1 - α ) y ) + C , x , y K , α [ 0 , 1 ] .

(ii) The mapping F : K → 2Yis said to be C-lower semicontinuous if the set {xK | F(x) - a ⊈ int C} is closed on K for any aY. F is said to be weakly C-lower semicontinuous if F is C-lower semicontinuous with respect to the weak topology of X. The map F is said to be weakly lower semicontinuous on K if it is weakly lower semicontinuous on K.

(iii) The mapping F : D × K × K → 2Yis said to be: weakly C-pseudomonotone if for all x, yK, uT (x), vT (y),

uT(x) such that F(u, x, y) ⊈ - int C ⇒ ∀vT(y) such that F(v, y, x) ⊈ int C, or equivalently,

vT(y) such that F(v, y, x) ⊈ int C ⇒ ∀uT(x) such that F(u, x, y) ⊆ - int C.

The mapping F : D × K × K → 2Yis said to be: strongly C-pseudomonotone if for all x, yK, uT(x), vT(y),

uT(x) such that F(u, x, y) ⋂-int C = ∅ ⇒ ∀vT(y) such that F(v, y, x) ⋂ int C = ∅, or equivalently,

vT(y) such that F(v, y, x) ⋂ int C ≠ ∅ ⇒ ∀uT(x) such that F(u, x, y) ⋂-int C ≠ ∅,

(iv) The asymptotic cone K and barrier cone barr(K) of K are, respectively, defined by

K = { d X | t k + , x k K with x k t k d }

and

barr ( K ) = { x * X * | sup x K x * , x < + } ,

where X* denotes the dual space of X andstands for the weak convergence.

Remark 2.1 (i) Definition 2.1 is a set-valued generalization of C-lower semicontinuity in [8]

(ii) If the map is strongly C-pseudomonotone, then it is weakly C-pseudomonotone. How-ever, the converse result is not true.

Example 2.1 Let X = R, K = [1, +), Y = R2, C= R + 2 , T(x) = {0, -1}.

Let F : D × K × K → 2Ybe defined by

F ( u , x , y ) = u , [ ( y - x ) , | y - x | ] x , y [ 1 , + ) , u T ( x ) [ 1 , 2 ] x , y [ 1 , + ) , u T ( x ) ,

x ∈ [1, + ), take u = 0 ∈ T(x), we have

F u , x , y = { 0 } × [1 , 2] - int C .

Its dual problem is:

F ( v , y , x ) = v , [ ( x - y ) , | x - y | ] x , y [ 1 , + ) , v T ( y ) [ 1 , 2 ] x , y [ 1 , + ) , v T ( y ) .

x∈[1,+∞), if v = 0 ∈ T(y), we have

F ( v , y , x ) = { 0 } × [ 1 , 2 ] int C ;

if v = -1 ∈ T(y), it holds

F ( v , y , x ) = [ - | x - y | , - ( x - y ) ] × [ 1 , 2 ] int C .

It is easy to see

F ( v , y , x ) int C , y [ 1 , + ) , v T ( y ) .

Hence F is weakly C-pseudomonotone. However, F is not strongly C-pseudomonotone.

The asymptotic cone K has the following useful properties.

Lemma 2.1 [20] Let KX be nonempty and closed. Then the following conclusions hold:

(i) K is closed cone;

(ii) If K is convex, then K = {dX | K + dK} = {dX | x + tdK, ∀t > 0}, where xK is arbitrary point;

(iii) If K is convex cone, then K = K.

Definition 2.2 The GVEP is said to be

(i) generalized strictly feasible in the weak sense if F w + ≠ ∅, where

F w + = x K | F ( u , x , x + y ) int C , y K \ { 0 } , u T ( x ) ;

(ii) generalized strictly feasible in the strong sense if F s + ≠ ∅, where

F s + = { x K | F ( u , x , x + y ) int C , y K \ { 0 } , u T ( x ) } .

Obviously, both F w +, F s + are equivalent to the F s + [19], when F is a single-valued map.

The following example is to explain that Definition 2.2 is applicable.

Example 2.2 Let X = R, K = [1, +), Y = R, C = R+, T (x) = {1}.

Let F1 : D × K × K → 2Ybe defined by

F 1 ( u , x , y ) = u , [ - ( y - x ) , y - x ] , x , y [ 1 , + ) , u T ( x ) .

It is verified that K = [0, +). For any x ∈ [1, +) and tK\{0}, one has

F 1 ( u , x , x + t ) = 1 , [ - t , t ] = [ - t , t ] int C .

So, F w + = [1, +∞). However, F s + = ∅.

Let F2 : D × K × K → 2Ybe defined by

F 2 ( u , x , y ) = u , [ ( y - x ) , 2 ( y - x ) ] , x , y [ 1 , + ) , u T ( x ) .

It is verified that K = [0, +∞). For any x ∈ [1, +∞) and tK\{0}, one has

F 2 ( u , x , x + t ) = 1 , [ t , 2 t ] = [ t , 2 t ] int C .

So, F w + = F s + = [ 1 , + ) .

Definition 2.3 [21] A set-valued map F : E → 2Xis said to be KKM mapping if, for each finite set Λ = {x1, . . ., x n } ⊆ E, one has coΛ i = 1 n F ( x i ) , where co(.) stands for the convex hull.

The main tools for proving our results are the following well-known KKM theorems.

Lemma 2.2 [22] Assume that X is a topological vector space, EX is a nonempty convex and F : E → 2Xis a KKM mapping with closed values. If there is a subset X0 contained in a compact convex subset of E such that x X 0 F ( x ) is compact, thenxEF(x) ≠ ∅.

Definition 2.4 [23, 24] Let K be a nonempty, closed, and convex subset of a real reflexive Banach space X with its dual X*. We say that K is well-positioned iff there exist x0X and gX* such that

g , x - x 0 | | x - x 0 | | , x K .

Lemma 2.3 [23, 24] Let K be a nonempty, closed, and convex subset of a real reflexive Banach space X with its dual X*. Then K is well-positioned if and only if the barrier cone barr(K) of K has a nonempty interior. Furthermore, if K is well-positioned then there is no sequence {x n } ⊆ K with ||x n || → +∞ such that origin is a weak limit of x n | | x n | | .

Lemma 2.4 [25] Let X and Y be two metric spaces and T : X → 2Ybe a nonempty-compact-valued mapping and upper semicontinuous at x*. Then, for any sequences x n → x* and u n T(x n ), there exist a subsequence { u n k } of {u n } and some u*T(x*) such that u n k u * .

3 Solvability of the WGVEP and the SGVEP

First, we investigate relations between solution set of the WGVEP (SGVEP) and solution set of the DWGVEP (DSGVEP) when K is bounded.

Theorem 3.1 Let KX be a nonempty and convex closed bounded set. If F : D × K × K → 2Ysatisfies the followings:

(i) F (u, x, x) ⊆ C, ∀xK, uT (x);

(ii) the set {(u, x), uT (x), xK : F (u, x, y) ⊈ -int C} is closed for any yK;

(iii) F is weakly C-pseudomonotone;

(iv) the set {yK | F(u, x, y) ⊈ int C} is closed and F (u, x, .) is C-convex for any xK, uT(x).

Then the WGVEP has a nonempty solution set and x*K is a solution of the WGVEP if and only if

F ( v , y , x * ) int C , y K , v T ( y ) .

Proof. Set Γ: D × K → 2Kby

Γ ( v , y ) = { x K | F ( v , y , x ) int C } , y K , v T ( y ) .

We claim that Γ is a KKM map. Suppose on the contrary, it does not hold, then there exists a finite set {x1, . . ., x n } ⊆ K and zco{x1, . . ., x n } such that z i = 1 n Γ ( v , x i ) . Thus, there exists v i T(x i ) such that F(v i , x i , z) ⊆ int C, ∀i = 1, . . ., n. It follows from the weak C-pseudomonotonity of F that

F ( u , z , x i ) - int C , i = 1 , , n .
(3.1)

Taking into account that int C is convex, we obtain

t 1 F ( u , z , x 1 ) + + t n F ( u , z , x n ) - int C ,

where z= 1 n t i x i and 1 n t i =1, t i 0,i=1,2,,n. For the above t i , due to the convexity of F(u, x,.), one has

t 1 F ( u , z , x 1 ) + t n F ( u , z , x n ) F ( u , z , z ) + C C + C C ,

which contradicts (3.1). By the condition (iv), we derive that the Γ is closed valued. Hence Γ is a KKM map. By the KKM Theorem, there exists x*∈ K such that x* ∈ ⋂vT(y), yKΓ(v, y). That is, F (v, y, x*) ⊈ int C,∀yK, vT(y).

Let us verify W S K D W S K . Take any x*∈ K, obviously

F ( v , y , x * ) int C , y K , v T ( y ) .
(3.2)

For every yK, consider x t = x* + t(y - x*), ∀t ∈ (0, 1). Clearly, x t K. The C-convexity of F (u, x t ,.) implies that

( 1 - t ) F ( u , x t , x * ) + t F ( u , x t , y ) F ( u , x t , x t ) + C C + C C .

Let us show tF (u, x t , y) ⊈-int C by contradiction. Suppose on the contrary, then tF (u, x t , y) ⊆ -int C. For any ptF (u, x t , y), it holds

( 1 - t ) F ( u , x t , x * ) C + p C + int C int C .

So F (u, x t , x*) ⊆ int C, which contradicts (3.2). Noting that -int C is convex cone, we deduce

F ( u , x t , y ) - int C .
(3.3)

Letting t → 0 in (3.3), we obtain by assumption (ii) and Lemma 2.4 that there exists u* ∈ T(x*) such that

F ( u * , x * , y ) - int C , y K .

On the other hand, by the weak C-pseudomonotonity of F, we have W S K W S K D .

Hence, W S K D = W S K .

Theorem 3.2 Let KX be a nonempty and convex closed bounded set. If F : D × K × K → 2Ysatisfies the followings:

(i) F (u, x, x) ⊆ C,∀xK, uT(x);

(ii) the set {(u, x), uT(x), xK | F (u, x, y) ∩ -int C = ∅} is closed for all yK;

(iii) F is strongly C-pseudomonotone;

(iv) the set {yK | F (u, x, y) ∩ int C = ∅} is closed and F (u, x, .) is C-convex for any xK, uT(x).

Then the SGVEP has a nonempty solution set and x* ∈ K is a solution of the SGVEP if and only if

F ( v , y , x * ) int C = , y K , v T ( y ) .

Proof. Set Γ: D × K → 2Kby

Γ ( v , y ) = { x K | F ( v , y , x ) int C = } , y K , v T ( y ) .

Following the similar arguments in the proof of Theorem 3.1, we can obtain the desired result.

In following sequel, we shall present some sufficient conditions for the nonemptiness and boundedness of the solution set of the WGVEP provided that it is strictly feasible in the strong sense.

Theorem 3.3 Let KX be a nonempty, closed, convex and well-positioned set. If F : D × K × K → 2Ysatisfies the followings:

(i) F (u, x, x) ⊆ C, ∀xK, uT(x);

(ii) the set {(u, x), uT (x), xK | F (u, x, y) ⊈-int C} is closed for any yK;

(iii) F is weakly C-pseudomonotone;

(iv) F (u, x, .) is C-convex and weakly lower semicontinuous for xK, uT(x).

Then the WGVEP has a nonempty bounded solution set whenever it is generalized strictly feasible in the strong sense.

Proof. Suppose that the WGVEP is generalized strictly feasible in the strong sense. Then there exists x0K such that x0F s +, i.e.,

F ( u , x 0 , x 0 + z ) int C , u T ( x 0 ) .

Set

D = { x K | F ( u , x 0 , x ) int C } , u T ( x 0 ) .

By assumptions (i) and (iv), x0D and D is weakly closed. We assert that D is bounded. Suppose on the contrary it does not holds, then there exists a sequence {x n } ⊆ M with ||x n || + as n → +. Since X is a reflexive Banach space, without loss of generality,

we may take a subsequence { x n k } of {x n } such that

1 | | x n k - x 0 | | ( 0 , 1 ) , lim k + x n k - x 0 | | x n k - x 0 | | = lim k + x n k | | x n k | | z K .

By Lemma 2.3, z ≠ 0 since K is well-positioned. It follows from x0F s + that

F ( u , x 0 , x 0 + z ) int C .
(3.4)

Noting that F (u, x, .) is C-convex, we have

1 - 1 | | x n k - x 0 | | F ( u , x 0 , x 0 ) + 1 | | x n k - x 0 | | F ( u , x 0 , x n k ) F u , x 0 , 1 - 1 | | x n k - x 0 | | x 0 + x n k | | x n k - x 0 | | + C = F u , x 0 , x 0 + x n k - x 0 | | x n k - x 0 | | + C .

That is,

1 | | x n - x 0 | | F ( u , x 0 , x n k ) F u , x 0 , x 0 + x n k - x 0 | | x n k - x 0 | | + C .

We claim that F u , x 0 , x 0 + x n k - x 0 | | x n k - x 0 | | int C. Suppose on the contrary, F u , x 0 , x 0 + x n k - x 0 | | x n k - x 0 | | inC, we observe

1 | | x n k - x 0 | | F ( u , x 0 , x n k ) F u , x 0 , x 0 + x n k - x 0 | | x n k - x 0 | | + C i n C + C int C ,

which contradicts F ( u , x 0 , x n k ) int C . Taking into account the condition (iv), we obtain

F ( u , x 0 , x 0 + z ) int C .

This is a contradiction to (3.4). Thus, D is bounded and it is weakly compact. For each pK, set

D p = { x D | F ( v , p , x ) int C } , p K , v T ( p ) .

Then D p ≠ ∅. Indeed, given pK, vT (p), set K0 = conv (Dp) ⊆ K, where conv means the convex hull of a set. Then K0 is nonempty, convex, and weakly compact. By Theorem 3.1, there exists x ̄ K 0 such that

F ( v , y , x ̄ ) int C , y K 0 , v T ( p ) .

Then F ( u , x 0 , x ̄ ) int C implies x ̄ D and F ( v , p , x ̄ ) int C implies x ̄ D p . We obtain D p ≠ ∅. Obviously, D p is nonempty and weakly compact.

Next we prove that {D p | pK} has the finite intersection property. For any finite set {p i | i = 1, 2, . . ., n} ⊆ K, let K1 = conv{D ⋃ {p1, p2, . . ., p n }}. Then K1 is weakly compact. By Theorem 3.1, there exists x ^ K 1 such that

F ( v , y , x ^ ) int C , y K 1 , v T ( p ) .

In particular, it holds

F ( u , x 0 , x ^ ) int C , F ( v , p i , x ^ ) int C , i = 1 , 2 , , n .

This means that x ^ i = 1 n D p i . Thus {D p | pK} has the finite intersection property. Since D is weakly compact and D p D is weakly closed for all pK, vT (p), It follows that

p K D p .

Let x* ∈ ⋂pKD p It follows that

F ( v , y , x * ) int C , y K , v T ( y ) .

By Theorem 3.1, x* is a solution of the WGVEP. As for the boundedness of the solution set of the WGVEP, it follows from Theorem 3.1 that the solution set of the WGVEP is a subset of D.

Theorem 3.4 Let KX be a nonempty, closed, convex, and well-positioned set. If F : D × K × K → 2Ysatisfies the followings:

(i) F (u, x, x) ⊆ C, ∀xK, uT (x);

(ii) the set {(u, x), uT(x), xK | F(u, x, y) ⋂ - int C = ∅} is closed for all yK;

(iii) F is strongly C-pseudomonotone;

(iv) F (u, x, .) is C-convex and weakly lower semicontinuous for xK, uT(x);

(v) F is positively homogeneous with degree α > 0, i.e., there exists α > 0 such that

F ( u , x , x + t ( y - x ) ) = t α F ( u , x , y ) , x , y K , u T ( x ) , t ( 0 , 1 ) .

Then the SGVEP has a nonempty bounded solution set whenever it is generalized strictly feasible in the weak sense.

Proof. Suppose that the SGVEP is generalized strictly feasible in the weak sense. Then there exists x0K such that x 0 F w + , i.e.,

F ( u , x 0 , x 0 + z ) int C .

Set

D = { x K | F ( u , x 0 , x ) int C = } .

By assumptions (i) and (iv), x0D and D is weakly closed. We claim that D is bounded. Suppose on the contrary it does not holds, then there exists a sequence {x n } ⊆ M with ||x n || + as n → +. Since X is a reflexive Banach space, without loss of generality, we may take a subsequence { x n k } of {x n } such that

1 | | x n k | | ( 0 , 1 ) , lim n + x n k | | x n k | | z K .

By Lemma 2.3, z ≠ 0 since K is well-positioned. It follows from x0F w + that

F ( u , x 0 , x 0 + z ) int C .
(3.5)

Since x n k D and F is positively homogenous with degree α > 0, it holds

F u , x 0 , x 0 + x n k - x 0 | | x n k | | = 1 | | x n k | | α F ( u , x 0 , x n k ) int C = .

Taking into account the condition (iv), we obtain

F ( u , x 0 , x 0 + z ) int C = .

This is a contradiction to (3.5). Thus, D is bounded and it is weakly compact. Following the similar arguments in the proof of Theorem 3.3, we can prove the Theorem 3.4.

Remark 3.1 Assumption (v) of Theorem 3.4 is not new. Clearly, if F(x, y) = 〈u, y -x〉, ∀uT(x), then F is positively homogeneous with degree = 1.

Remark 3.2 Since SS K WS K , conditions for the solution set of the SGVEP to be nonempty and bounded are stronger than the WGVEP. Compared with Theorem 3.3, the condition that F is positively homogeneous in Theorem 3.4 is not dropped for the SGVEP.

The following example shows that the converse of Theorem 3.3 or 3.4 is not true in general.

Example 3.1 Let X = R, K = R, D = [0, 1], Y = R, C= R + 2 and

T ( x ) = { 1 } , i f x > 0 { 0 , 1 } , i f x = 0 .

Let F : D × K × K → 2Ybe defined by

F ( u , x , y ) = u , ( y 2 - x 2 ) 2 , ( y 2 - x 2 ) x , y K , u T ( x ) ; u , ( y - x ) x , y K .

It is easily to see that K is well-positioned and F satisfies assumptions of Theorems 3.3 and 3.4. It can be verified that the WGVEP and the SGVEP have the same solution set {0}. On the other hand, it is easy to verify that F w + = F s + =.

For general generalized vector equilibrium problem, the following example shows WS K ≠ ∅, but SS K = ∅.

Example 3.2 Let X = R, K = R, D = [-1, 1], Y = R, C = R+ and

T ( x ) = { - 1 , 1 } , x K F ( u , x , y ) = [ - 1 , 1 ] , x , y K , u T ( x ) .

It is obvious that the WGVEP has solution set WS K = R, but solution set of the SGVEP SS K = ∅.