1 Introduction

Many complex physical systems can be modeled and better understood as complex networks [13]. Recent studies show that economic systems can also be regarded as complex networks in which economic agents, like consumers, firms, and governments, are closely connected [4, 5]. To understand the interaction among economic agents, we must uncover the structure of economic networks.

Our focus in this paper is on inter-firm networks. Over the last several years, a pair of critical incidences revealed the global interconnection of firms: the financial turmoil triggered by the subprime mortgage crisis in the United States and the disruption of worldwide supply chains caused by the 2011 Fukushima earthquake and tsunami in Japan. These incidences sparked interest in inter-firm networks by network scientists, economists, and sociologists. Several aspects of inter-firm relationships were previously studied, including the firm and bank relationship [6], the customer-supplier relationship [712], and the ownership relationship (i.e., which firm owns which firm) [13, 14]. The degree distribution follows a power law, and the shortest path-lengths for any pair of firms are around five [11, 15, 16]. Newman’s community analysis [17, 18] also shows that firms tend to transact with each other when they belong to the same industry and/or are located in the same state or prefecture [19]. The structure of the inter-firm networks investigated was found to be stable [16].

One limitation of previous studies is that they mainly addressed inter-firm relationships within a country, so they have little to say about the linkages of firms in different countries. Important exceptions include studies on global ownership structure [20], and global R&D partnerships [21]. However, no work has yet investigated the structure of global customer-supplier linkages, which is the key to understanding the nature of the above incidences (i.e., the global financial crisis and the disruption of global supply chains by natural disasters). Given this background, we investigate the global aspect of inter-firm linkages using a unique dataset that contains information on business relationships (both domestic and international) for about 400,000 firms worldwide. This is the first contribution of this paper. Note that if one aggregates transactions (purchases and sales) at the firm level, one obtains transactions at the country level, called international trade by economists. The network structure of international trade has recently been studied by economists and physicists [2228]. Our investigation of international transactions at the firm level is closely related to those studies, but our firm level data reveal that firms are more likely to transact with other firms in the same industry rather than other firms in the same home country, which is quite different from what is assumed in studies on international trade. We will expand this point below.

After examining the structure of global inter-firm networks, we discuss the implications of global linkages at the firm level for the proliferation of ‘conflict minerals’ through global buyer-supplier linkages. This is the second contribution of this paper. Conflict minerals are natural minerals (gold, tin, tungsten, etc.) that are extracted from conflict zones and sold to perpetuate fighting. The most prominent example is the natural minerals extracted in the Democratic Republic of the Congo (DRC) by armed groups and funneled through a variety of intermediaries before being purchased by multinational electronics firms in industrial countries. There is wide discussion on how to mitigate the worldwide spread of conflict minerals [2931]. For example, the U.S. government passed a law in July 2010 that requires listed firms to audit their supply chains and report the use in their products of conflict minerals from the DRC or adjoining countries [32]. In this paper, we conduct simulation analysis using our firm level data on global buyer-supplier linkages to evaluate the effectiveness of various measures to mitigate the worldwide propagation of conflict minerals through global supply chains.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides a detailed description of our dataset, and Section 3 looks at the basic features of inter-firm networks, including degree distributions. Section 4 examines how closely firms are interconnected by measuring the shortest path lengths between them. Section 5 conducts community analysis employing a network’s modularity defined by Newman. Section 6 conducts simulation analysis to investigate the proliferation of conflict minerals through global supply chains. Section 7 concludes the paper.

2 Dataset

For this research, we used a unique dataset compiled by S&P Capital IQ, which is part of McGraw Hill Financial Inc. [33]. The dataset covers 423,024 major incorporated firms with information of business relationships in 217 countries in 159 industry sectors that were defined by the S&P, including all the listed firms in the world. Attribute information is available for those firms, including the location of a firm, the industry a firm belongs to, and other information reported in the financial statement of a firm. The dataset has lists of core partners (i.e., customers, suppliers, licensors, licensees, and strategic alliances) in recent period (i.e., 2013 and/or 2014) and in some years over the entire sample period (almost all relationships date from 2000) for a firm with IDs. For example, the numbers of core customers and suppliers for IBM are 446 and 184 firms in the recent period and 1,565 and 755 firms in some years over the entire sample period. The following relationship exists between customers and suppliers. When firm j is a supplier to firm i, firm i is a customer of firm j. Licensees and licensors have such an opposite relationship.

Before moving to detailed analysis using this dataset, let us make some remarks about statistical characteristics of the dataset. Needless to say, it is important to have a dataset with high quality and completeness about networks, but, in reality, it is very hard to have such an ideal dataset. It is especially so if the main interest of researchers is on global interfirm networks rather than local ones. Given this, we do not claim that the dataset we employ in this paper is a perfect one. However, we are still able to evaluate how (in)complete the dataset is by comparing this dataset with other datasets on interfirm linkages. For linkages among Japanese firms, we have access to the dataset compiled by Tokyo Shoko Research, Ltd. [34], which was used by many researchers. This dataset is said to contain almost complete information on linkages among Japanese firms. According to this dataset, the average number of customer links for a firm in 2012 is 7.4, while the corresponding number for supplier linkage is 7.9. On the other hand, according to the Capital IQ dataset, the average number of customer and supplier links for a firm is 3.2 and 2.7, respectively. This comparison indicates that the Capital IQ dataset covers about 40 percent, suggesting that the Capital IQ dataset is far from a complete one. However, if we restrict our attention to listed firms in Japan, the average number of customer and supplier links for a firm are 7.6 and 7.8 in the Tokyo Shoko Research dataset, while they are 3.7 and 3.8 in the Capital IQ dataset, indicating that the coverage is higher at about 50 percent. This implies that the Capital IQ dataset contains more information on links among major firms than on other links.

3 Scale-free global inter-firm networks

We first show the common scale-free properties of three global inter-firm networks, which are based on customer-supplier, licensee-licensor, and strategic alliance relationships. We investigate the cumulative distribution functions (CDFs) of links across firms for the following linkages: customer, supplier, licensee, licensor, and strategic alliance. In Figure 1, the horizontal axis is the number of links, and the vertical axis represents the cumulative densities. The CDFs of each kind of linkage have tails that follow a power law function.

Figure 1
figure 1

CDFs of links across firms for customer linkages (left, black), supplier linkages (left red), licensee linkages (center, black), licensor linkages (center, red), and strategic alliance linkages (right). Dashed lines show distribution in recent period (i.e., 2013 and/or 2014). Solid lines show distribution in some years over entire sample period. Guidelines express power law with an exponent of 1.5.

To test whether each link distribution has a power law tail, we conduct a likelihood ratio test, in which a power law distribution is a null hypothesis and log normal distribution is an alternative hypothesis. This test is known to be a uniformly most powerful unbiased test [3537]. Table 1 shows the estimated power law ranges for link distributions. For example, for supplier linkage, the null hypothesis cannot be rejected for \(2 \le N_{s} \le89\). Overall, the results in Table 1 indicates that the null hypothesis cannot be rejected for all types of linkage and that the power law exponent associated with each link distribution, which is estimated using observations belonging to the corresponding power law range, is somewhere around 1.5. Networks with such power laws are called scale-free networks.

Table 1 Likelihood-ratio tests of link distributions. The null hypothesis is that, beyond some threshold, the upper tail of a link distribution is characterized by a power law distribution. The alternative hypothesis is that the upper tail follows a lognormal beyond the same threshold. The significance level is set at 5 percent. The power law exponent associated with each link distribution is estimated using observations belonging to the corresponding power law range

It should be noted that, in Ref. [12], we define the number of links for a firm as the total number of links the firm had over multiple years. This definition might have contributed to making the tail part of the observed distribution appear heavier than it really is. To explain why, suppose that there are some firms with a large number of links and that these firms change their partners much more frequently than other firms. In this case, the total number of their partners over multiple years for these firms is very large, so that we may observe a power law tail even if the true link distribution at a particular point in time does not have such a heavy tail. Put differently, a power law tail emerges reflecting heterogeneity across firms in terms of link turnover. To cope with this, we repeat the same power law test but now using observations only for a shorter period (i.e., 2013-2014). Table 1 shows that the results are not so sensitive to changes in the length of the sample period examined.

4 Six degrees of separation between major incorporated firms

We measure the shortest path lengths (SPLs) for each pair of firms i and j in a non-directed customer-supplier network over the entire sample period. The number of firms on it is 345,909, so there are about 60 billion pairs. Although the density for the linkages in this network is very low, only \(1.1 \times10^{-5}\), the number of firms in its maximum connected component is 318,080, which is about 92.0% of all the firms. Figure 2 shows the SPL distribution for the connected pairs. The mode of distribution is five path lengths, and about 80% of the pairs are connected by six path lengths or fewer. We also investigate the mode for the directed customer-supplier network to consider intermediate products or money flow. This mode is also short, only seven path lengths. We also measure the SPLs in non-directed licensee-licensor, directed licensee-licensor, and non-directed strategic alliance networks. The number of firms, the network density for the linkages, the size of the maximum connected component, and the mode of the SPLs are shown in Table 2. The mode in these networks is also short: around six path lengths.

Figure 2
figure 2

Distributions of shortest path lengths (SPLs) for firm pairs. Left and right figures show distributions in recent period (i.e., 2013 and/or 2014) and in some years over entire sample period. Circles, squares, open triangles, open circles, and open squares express distributions in non-directed customer-supplier, non-directed licensee-licensor, non-directed strategic alliance, directed customer-supplier, and directed licensee-licensor networks, respectively.

Table 2 Number of firms, network density for linkages, maximum connected component (MCC) size, and mode of shortest path lengths in customer-supplier (CS), licensee-licensor (LL), and strategic alliance (SA) networks in recent period (i.e., 2013 and/or 2014) and over entire sample period

The SPL distribution of a domestic non-directed customer-supplier network was previously reported [11, 15, 16]. In the Japanese case, the mode of SPL distribution is five path lengths. International linkages for firms were not taken in these previous studies; the actual SPL for the Japanese firm’s pairs is shorter than five path lengths. We compare SPLs for firm’s pairs in the same country in a global customer-supplier network and a domestic customer-supplier network that has only domestic linkages. Figure 3 shows the probability that SPLs are extended by being limited to domestic linkages in the United States or Japan. In the Japanese case of \(\mathrm{SPL}\ge5\) and the U.S. case of \(\mathrm{SPL}\ge7\) in a global customer-supplier network, the probability is over 0.5. This result suggests that the effect from foreign countries cannot be ignored, because international relationships are indispensable for handling incidents in supply chains.

Figure 3
figure 3

Probability that shortest path lengths (SPLs) are extended by being limited to domestic linkages in global customer-supplier network over entire sample period. Circles and squares are estimation results in United States and Japan. SPL for unconnected pairs is ∞.

5 Firms’ community structure

Global inter-firm networks are built by multiple communities. Detecting the communities in networks means the appearance of dense connected groups of vertices and sparse connections among groups. Ref. [20] conduct community analysis for a global ownership network, but we do a similar exercise for global customer-supplier network. We adopt modularity as a quality function of communities introduced by Newman and detect them by a fast greedy algorithm of modularity maximization that is one effective approach to identify communities [38]. If network V is divided into L subsets \(\{V_{1},V_{2},\ldots,V_{L}\}\) which do not overlap and are not empty, modularity Q is defined as

$$ Q=\sum_{i=1}^{L} \bigl(e_{ii}-a_{i}^{2} \bigr)= \sum_{i=1}^{L} \biggl[ \frac{1}{2M}\sum_{l \in V_{i}}\sum _{m \in V_{i}}A_{lm}- \biggl(\frac{1}{2M}\sum _{l \in V_{i}}\sum_{m \in V}A_{lm} \biggr)^{2} \biggr], $$
(1)

where \(A_{lm}\) is an element of adjacent matrix which is set to be 1 or 0 according to whether nodes l and m are connected or not. \(e_{ii}\) and \(a_{i}\) are the fraction of links within subset \(V_{i}\) and the fraction of links that connect to nodes in subset \(V_{i}\), respectively. When the subsets \(\{V_{1},V_{2},\ldots,V_{L}\}\) are selected randomly, \(e_{ii}\) is canceled out by \(a_{i}^{2}\), which gives the expectation value of the network density for the linkages in subset \(V_{i}\). Using the modularity we can compare the actual network density for linkages in a subset with its expectation value. When the maximized modularity \(Q_{\mathrm{max}}\) takes a value close to zero, the network has no statistically significant communities, unlike randomly connected networks. On the other hand, \(Q_{\mathrm{max}} \simeq1\) corresponds to a network which is almost perfectly partitioned into modules.

The maximum modularities of non-directed customer-supplier, non-directed licensor-licensee, and strategic alliance networks over the entire sample period are 0.64, 0.75, and 0.74, respectively. Such sufficiently large modularity means that significant communities exist in the networks. We characterize each community by checking the majority attributes (e.g., country and industry sector) of the firms in the community. Because firm attribution bias can be found in each network, we compare the fraction of the firms’ attribution in each community with the fraction in all communities by \(R_{i,l}\), which is defined as

$$ R_{i,l}=\frac{ \text{fraction of attribution } i \text{ in community } l \text{ in network} }{ \text{fraction of attribution } i \text{ in all communities in network} }. $$
(2)

The p-values for the fraction of the firms’ attribution in each community are calculated using the null hypothesis that the firms’ attribution is independent of community.

First, we investigate the communities in the licensee-licensor network with the highest modularity over the entire sample period. The network has 4,493 communities. However, the top four account for over 50% of all firms: 22.9%, 18.3%, 7.7%, and 3.8%. Table 3 shows the fraction of firms’ attributions with a p-value < 0.01 among the top four communities. We focus on the remarkable attributions with \(R_{i,l}\ge3\) in each attribution to identify the community characteristics. The largest community is mainly comprised of movies, entertainment, semiconductors, and broadcasting firms. Many Taiwan firms appertain to this community. The major industry in Taiwan is semiconductors. Therefore, the largest community expresses sectors for broadcasting technology. As shown in Table 3, the 2nd, 3rd, and 4th largest communities show the ICT sectors in health care, the apparel sectors, and the chemical industry sectors, respectively. The licensee-licensor relationships between major incorporated firms tend to be confined to similar industrial sectors over the boundaries between countries.

Table 3 Top 5 fractions of firms’ attributes with p -value < 0.01 in major communities in non-directed licensee-licensor network. R , which expresses ratio between actual fraction and the fraction obtained by random selection, is defined by Equation ( 2 ). Bold font indicates remarkable attributes with \(\pmb{R\ge3}\)

We next focus on over the entire sample period a non-directed strategic alliance network which has 1,995 communities. The top four account for 18.1%, 17.2%, 10.8%, and 9.5% of all the firms. In each community, the firms belong to the similar industrial sectors but different home countries. The largest community mainly includes firms in ICT sectors (i.e., IT consulting and other services, communications equipment, system software) as shown in Table 4. The 2nd, 3rd, and 4th largest communities express heavy industry, bank and resort development, and medicine sectors, respectively.

Table 4 Top 5 fractions of firms’ attributes with p -value < 0.01 in major communities in non-directed strategic alliance network. Bold font expresses remarkable attributes with \(\pmb{R\ge3}\)

We also investigate firms’ attribution in each community in a non-directed customer-supplier network over the entire sample period. The network has 3,463 communities. The top four account for 20.9%, 20.7%, 12.0%, and 5.9% of all the firms. The 2nd and 3rd largest communities show industry sectors, such as aerospace/defense and health care (Table 5). On the other hand, the 4th largest community shows transactions in the ASEAN free trade area because Southeast Asian firms tend to densely connect to firms in the same area. Since various industries are included in the largest community (Table 5), we further divide the largest one into discrete sub-communities. The major sub-communities express some industry sectors. The 1st, 2nd, and 3rd largest sub-communities show the broadcasting technology sectors, department stores (i.e., apparel and restaurant sector), and the electronic equipment sectors, respectively (Table 6).

Table 5 Top 5 fractions of firms’ attributes with p -value < 0.01 in major communities in non-directed customer-supplier networks. Bold font expresses remarkable attributes with \(\pmb{R\ge3}\)
Table 6 Top 5 fractions of firm attributes with p -value < 0.01 in major sub-communities in largest community in customer-supplier network. Bold font expresses remarkable attributes with \(\pmb{R\ge3}\)

As cited above, major incorporated firms tend to have worldwide connections. We investigate the relationship between firm size and geographical distance to business partner. Here, firm size is measured by the total 2013 revenue. As shown in Figure 4, the mean of the geographical distance in a customer-supplier network is about 3,400 km, which is shorter than in other inter-firm networks (i.e., 3,700 km for strategic alliance relationships and 4,300 km for licensee-licensor relationships). Because firms choose suppliers and customers by taking into consideration transport costs and product price, the mean of the geographical distance of the customer-supplier network is short. As represented by the 4th largest community in the customer-supplier network, a large community that expresses a region is only observed in this network. In inter-firm networks, the geographical distance of a large firm whose annual total revenue exceeds 103 million dollars tends to be long; large firms are affected by the economic conditions in distant unexpected countries.

Figure 4
figure 4

Relationship between firm size measured by total 2013 revenue and mean of geographical distance to business partner. Circles, squares, and open triangles show customer-supplier, licensee-licensor, and strategic alliance relationships in some years over entire sample period, respectively.

6 Simulation for conflict minerals proliferation

In this section, we conduct a simulation exercise to learn about the implications of the structure of the global buyer-supplier network, which we studied in the previous sections, for the proliferation of conflict minerals. Our analysis in the previous sections suggest the following. First, the finding in Section 3 (i.e., the link distribution has a power law tail) suggests that a small number of firms with an extremely large number of links play an important role in the proliferation of conflict minerals. Second, the finding in Section 4 (i.e., most firms are connected within six links) suggests that the proliferation of conflict minerals may be surprisingly quick. Third, the finding in Section 5 (i.e., firms within an industry – rather than within a country – tends to form a community) suggests that national borders do not matter for the proliferation of conflict minerals. Combined together, our analysis suggests that it is critically important to identify key firms located at the very upstream of the conflict mineral supply chain and to regulate transactions associated with these firms.

In our simulation exercise, we use a simple diffusion model of the form:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{pmatrix} g_{1}(t+1)\\ g_{2}(t+1)\\ \vdots\\ g_{N}(t+1) \end{pmatrix} =& \begin{pmatrix} 1-q_{1} & 0 & \cdots& 0 \\ 0 & 1-q_{2} & \cdots& 0 \\ \vdots& \vdots& \ddots& \vdots\\ 0 & 0 & \cdots& 1-q_{N} \end{pmatrix} \begin{pmatrix} 0 & a_{12} & \cdots& a_{1N} \\ a_{21} & 0 & \cdots& a_{2N} \\ \vdots& \vdots& \ddots& \vdots\\ a_{N1} & a_{N2} & \cdots& 0 \end{pmatrix} \begin{pmatrix} g_{1}(t) \\ g_{2}(t) \\ \vdots\\ g_{N}(t) \end{pmatrix} \\ &{}+ \begin{pmatrix} \epsilon_{1}(t) \\ \epsilon_{2}(t) \\ \vdots\\ \epsilon_{N}(t) \end{pmatrix} . \end{aligned}$$
(3)

Note that similar diffusion models were employed by previous studies on interfirm customer-supplier networks, including Ref. [39] and Ref. [40]. This type of diffusion model is simple and tractable but may be oversimplified. One of the most important assumptions adopted in this model is that PageRank of a firm coincides with the ‘costs of goods sold’ (i.e., the direct costs attributable to the production of the goods sold by a firm) of that firm. To check whether this assumption is supported by the data, we compare PageRank of a firm with the costs of goods sold, which is taken from the financial statement of the firm. The result of this exercise is shown in Figure 5, in which the horizontal axis represents PageRank of a firm and the vertical axis is the costs of goods sold of the firm. It is clearly seen that there is a positive and stable relationship between the two variables, indicating that the assumption adopted in the model is supported by the data.

Figure 5
figure 5

Relationship between the ‘costs of goods sold’ of a firm in 2013 and the PageRank of the firm, which is calculated using the customer-supplier network for the entire sample period. The probability of a random jump in calculating PageRank is set at \(q=0.05\). The plots and dashed lines represent the mean and the confidence interval. The reference line shows a power law relationship with an exponent of 1.05.

We explain this general model using an example for conflict minerals. \(g_{i}(t)\) is the amount of conflict minerals possessed by firm i at time t, \(\epsilon_{i}(t)\) is the amount of conflict minerals that are extracted by firm i at time t that doesn’t stem from customer-supplier chains, \(q_{i}\) expresses the rate at which they are consumed as a port of the final consumption products in firm i, and \(a_{ij}\) is an element in an input-output matrix. Typical element \(a_{ij}\) equals \(1/\hat{N}_{j}^{C}\) if firm i is a customer of firm j and zero otherwise. Here, \(\hat{N}_{j}^{C}\) is number of customers of firm j. In the standard notation adopted in input-output analysis, \(a_{ij}\) represents the share of output j (i.e., commodity produced by firm j) in the total intermediate output use of firm i. We have information on whether firm i purchases something from firm j, but no information on the amount of output j purchased by firm i; this is the thickness of each customer link. Since we assume that the customer links of firm j have identical thickness, \(a_{ij}=1/\hat {N}_{j}^{C}\) if firm i is a customer of firm j and zero otherwise. From PageRank theory, it is trivial that \(g_{i}(t)\) converges on \(g_{i}(t-1)\) at time \(t=\infty\) when all \(q_{i}\) satisfy the inequality, \(0< q_{i}\le1\). Note that the solution of this model is given by \(g=(I-QA)^{-1}\epsilon \). However, the size of the matrix A is very large, making it difficult to obtain its inverse matrix. We solve numerically using an iterative method, in which \(g_{t}\) is calculated period by period.

We simulate the diffusion of the conflict minerals that are mined in the Democratic Republic of the Congo (DRC) and all of its nine neighbors: Angola, Burundi, Central African Republic, Republic of the Congo, Rwanda, South Sudan, Tanzania, Uganda, and Zambia. We simply assume that \(\epsilon_{i}(t)\) is time independent and set the total 2013 revenue of each firm in the ‘metals and mining’ upper-sector (which includes aluminum, diversified metals and mining, gold, precious metals and minerals, silver, and steel sectors) in these countries to \(\epsilon_{i}(t)\). Here, for \(\epsilon_{i}(t)\) for some firms whose total revenue is not recorded in this dataset, we substitute the mean of the total revenue of the firm whose total revenue is recorded in this upper-sector and these countries. Except for these firms, \(\epsilon _{i}(t)=0\). All initial values are \(g_{i}(0)=0\).

We ran the model until \(g_{i}(t)\) practically converges on \(g_{i}(t-1)\) on the customer-supplier network without banking sectors over the entire sample period. Figure 6 shows a simulated amount of the conflict minerals per firm in each country when all \(q_{i}=0.3\). The conflict minerals drift down to the firms even in most developed countries. In the G8 countries the top ten industry sectors in which many conflict minerals hide products are shown in Table 7. Conflict minerals are found in the ‘electrical components and equipment’ sector in G8. The ‘metals and mining’ upper-sector and the ‘trading companies and distributors’ sector have only 3.4% of all the firms in the G8 and account for 94.6% of the total conflict minerals in G8.

Figure 6
figure 6

Simulated amount of conflict minerals per firm outside of DRC and its neighbors. Model’s parameter is all \(q_{i}=0.3\) (see Eq. (3)). Maximum amount was normalized to one. Shades of red express logarithm amount of conflict minerals. Firms in Mali and Guinea have many conflict minerals. Black expresses DRC. Gray shows its neighbors.

Table 7 Simulated shares of conflict minerals in top 10 industry sectors in G8 and reduction rate of conflict minerals by application of the regulation that all firms in the ‘metals and mining’ upper-sector and the ‘trading companies and distributors’ sector in G8 must not distribute conflict minerals to their customers; the \(\pmb{q_{i}}\) s of these firms are one and \(\pmb{q_{i}=0.3}\) otherwise in Eq. ( 3 )

We numerically demonstrate the simplified regulation that all firms in the ‘metals and mining’ upper-sector and the ‘trading companies and distributors’ sector in G8 must not distribute conflict minerals to their customers; the \(q_{i}\)s of these firms are one and \(q_{i}=0.3\) otherwise. As shown in Table 7, the amount of conflict minerals is reduced in each sector. The conflict minerals in the ‘electrical components and equipment’ and ‘alternative carriers’ sectors fell by over 97%, where they substantially improved their conflict minerals issues.

We numerically show that the amount of conflict minerals would decrease effectively outside the G8 by a regulation on the purchases of conflict minerals directed at 3% of all the firms in G8. We selected the 3% firms in each of the following conditions and dammed the conflict mineral flow; their \(q_{i}\)s are one and \(q_{i}=0.3\) otherwise.

Condition 1:

Firms are selected in descending order of the number of supplier links in G8.

Condition 2:

Only listed firms are selected in descending order of the number of supplier links in G8.

Condition 3:

Firms are selected in descending order of the number of supplier links in the ‘metals and mining’ upper-sector and ‘trading companies and distributors’ sectors in G8.

Table 8 shows the numerical simulation results of the regulation with each condition. In Condition 1, the selected 3% firms decreased distribution of all conflict minerals by 35.0% in G8. However, the amount of conflict minerals hardly changed in the other firms. A U.S. federal law for conflict minerals among the listed firms was passed on July 21, 2010 [32]. Condition 2 expresses the situation where this law is applied to all the listed firms in G8. Although the trend improved slightly from 35.0% to 43.2% in G8, the amount of conflict minerals also hardly decreased outside of the selected firms. On the other hand, we confirmed a dramatic reduction in Condition 3. The selected 3% of firms decreased distribution of all conflict minerals by 97.3% in G8 and created a block that intercepted about 12.0% of all the conflict minerals outside of G8, DRC, and DRC’s neighbors.

Table 8 Reduction rate from amount of conflict minerals before applying regulation to 3% firms in G8 to amount after. Reduction rates in G8 firms, non-applied G8 firms, firms outside G8, DRC, and DRC’s neighbors are numerically estimated in each condition (see Section  6 )

7 Conclusion

We investigated the structure of global inter-firm relationships using a unique dataset that contains the information of business relationships for 423,024 major incorporated firms and focused on three different networks: a customer-supplier network through which products and services flow; a licensee-licensor network through which technical information and know-how flow; and a strategic alliance network through which both flow mutually.

These networks have common scale-free properties. The degree distributions follow a power law with an exponent of 1.5. The shortest path length for each pair of firms is around six for all three networks. We showed through community structure analysis that the firms comprise a community with those firms that belong to the same industry but different home countries, indicating the globalization of firms’ production activities.

We measured the mean of the geographical distance between the firms and their business partners. It was 3,400 km between business partners for customer-supplier relationships, which is shorter than for the two other relationships. This result suggests that technical information and know-how without high transport costs have the potential to be diffused rapidly worldwide. We also confirmed that the geographical distance between business partners for large firms tends to be long.

Finally, by utilizing a simple diffusion model and empirical results where firms comprise a community with those firms that belong to the same industry but different home countries, we showed numerically that regulations on the purchases conflict minerals by limited number of G8 firms belonging to some specific industries would substantially reduce their worldwide use. When these firms refuse to buy conflict minerals from their suppliers, the supply chains of many intermediaries which are positioned upstream suffer.

There remain a couple of issues for our future study. First, we need to collect more complete data on global interfirm linkage and to check the robustness of our results. Second, it is important to accurately estimate each intermediary’s amount of damage and the model’s parameters by comprehensively collecting the data of global inter-firm relationships. Part of the money which was spent in firms flows into conflict minerals through multiple inter-firm networks. Third, we need to expand our model by connecting a customer-supplier network with licensee-licensor and strategic alliance networks. This expanded model might help make more effective policies for conflict minerals. Recently, the global diffusion of weaponry, technical know-how, conflict oil, and natural gas through lawful trades is also attracting attention. Our results might resolve such issues and contribute to global peace.