Skip to main content
Log in

Connecting Classical and Early Neoclassical Views on Savings and Capital Formation to Modern Growth Theory Through the Lens of F. P. Ramsey

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Eastern Economic Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We investigate the origins of modern growth theory using Ramsey’s seminal A Mathematical Theory of Saving (1928) by dividing Ramsey’s optimal savings problem into two principal components, (1) the relationship between personal savings and the formation of capital, and (2) the optimal intertemporal balance between consumption and savings. The first component serves as a philosophical conduit for surveying classical and early neoclassical perspectives on savings and capital formation. The second details early neoclassicists’ consideration of mathematical methods and intergenerational welfare. Taken together, we create a pathway between early discussions of savings and capital formation, and the origins of growth theory.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The author wishes to express his gratitude to the late Roy Gardner for his generous mentorship. I am also indebted to several readers and colleagues for their advice. I alone am responsible for all errors and omissions.

    Since the publication of Solow (1956), many theoretical economists have accepted economic growth as coincidental with an improvement in welfare, albeit not without occasional criticism. However, it is important to note that Ramsey’s novel approach explicitly incorporated intergenerational responsibility into his and many subsequent models of savings and economic welfare which are cited later.

  2. Ramsey also maintained a close professional relationship with philosopher Ludwig Wittgenstein.

  3. The University of Pittsburg Library System (ULS) has archived an impressive collection of Ramsey’s notes on economics, philosophy and logic, and mathematics. These are available to the public at https://digital.library.pitt.edu/collection/frank-plumpton-ramsey-papers.

    The University of Cambridge also houses a collection of Ramsey’s personal reflections and correspondence. See https://archivesearch.lib.cam.ac.uk/repositories/7/resources/1216.

  4. The University of Pittsburg Library System (ULS) has archived an impressive collection of Ramsey’s notes on economics, philosophy and logic, and mathematics. These are available to the public at https://digital.library.pitt.edu/collection/frank-plumpton-ramsey-papers. The University of Cambridge also houses a collection of Ramsey’s reflections and correspondence.

  5. See “Ramsey Economics” (006-07-01, 36) in the archives of The University of Pittsburg Library System (ULS), https://digital.library.pitt.edu/islandora/object/pitt%3A31735044221434/viewer#page/10/mode/2up .

  6. Misak (2020) provides a comprehensive overview of F.P. Ramsey’s life and professional contributions. Those interested in learning more about F.P. Ramsey should start with her book.

  7. See “Ramsey Economics” (006-07-10, 13) in the archives of The University of Pittsburg Library System (ULS), https://digital.library.pitt.edu/islandora/object/pitt%3A31735044221434/viewer#page/10/mode/2up . Accessed July 17, 2023.

  8. Though the distinction is sometimes difficult to discern, the author attempts to use term ‘formation’ when referring to how new capital is added, and ‘accumulation’ otherwise. In reality, economic growth does not become a focal point of discussion until the twentieth century.

  9. It is not possible herein to list the entire body of literature on savings, capital and investment that existed prior to Ramsey (1928). The works cited herein are those that appear to lay a path for Ramsey (1928) while also considering Ramsey’s age, location, immediate influencers, and intended career path as a mathematical logician (Misak 2020). I am indebted to several readers and colleagues who have helped to define this list. I remain solely responsible for all remaining omissions and debatable influences.

  10. Baumol and Tobin (1989) acknowledges that Allais (1947) first described the square-root formula for the transactions cost model of optimal cash balances found in Baumol (1952) and Tobin (1956).

  11. Allais (1947) also introduces the golden-rule for optimal growth.

  12. According to Google Scholar, Ramsey (1928) is cited in over nine-thousand books and articles.

  13. Political economy investigates the impact of economic activity within a political context. Classical economics focuses on economic problems and solutions. However, it is often difficult to distinguish between the two, especially when considering the literature from the 18th and 19th centuries.

  14. Hoselitz et al. (1960) provides the narrative from Mills Principles [1900 (1848), 407–427].

  15. Fetter (1900) offers critiques of how Böhm-Bawerk, Clark and Fisher interpreted capital. He continues his criticism of Fisher and others in Fetter (1914). Fisher (1907b) offers a convincing rebuttal. Due to his position at Cambridge in mathematics, it is likely that Ramsey was at least indirectly familiar with the collective works of Böhm-Bawerk, Clark and Fisher; these remain cornerstones of current theory.

  16. See Dimand (2019) for a thorough discussion of the Fisher Diagram (Fisher 1907a, 409).

  17. At this juncture, it is important to note the much earlier contributions of A.R.J Turgot [1727–1781] to the concept of time-preference. In an excellent narrative on theories of time-preference, Rothbard (2011), declares that A.R.J Turgot “in a relatively few hastily written contributions, anticipated almost completely the later Austrian theory of capital and interest” (61). Turgot recognized that due to future risk, goods and assets received in the present are preferred to those received in the future, and that “the rate of interest equates present with future, or temporally distant, money” (61).

References

  • Ahmad, Syed. 2007. On the Bicentennial of the Other “Inquiry”: Lauderdale’s. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 29(1): 85–100. https://doi.org/10.1080/10427710601178286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allais, Maurice. 1947. Economie et Interet. Paris Imprimerie Nationale et Librairie des Publications Officielles.

  • Becker, Robert A. 1980. On the Long-Run Steady State in a Simple Dynamic Model of Equilibrium with Heterogeneous Households. Quarterly Journal of Economics 95(2): 375–382. https://doi.org/10.2307/1885506.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, William J. 1952. The Transactions Demand for Cash. Quarterly Journal of Economics 67(4): 545–556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, William J., and James Tobin. 1989. The Optimal Cash Balance Proposition: Maurice Allais’ Priority. Journal of Economic Literature 27(3): 1160–1162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Böhm-Bawerk, Eugen. (1889; 1891) 1959. Positive Theory of Capital, in Capital and Interest. South Holland, IL: Libertarian Press.

  • Boianovsky, Mauro. 1998. Wicksell, Ramsey and the Theory of Interest. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 5(1): 140–168. https://doi.org/10.1080/10427719800000006.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowley, Arthur L. (1924) 1965. The Mathematical Groundwork of Economics. New York, Augustus M. Kelley.

  • Brems, Hans. 1986. Pioneering Economic Theory, 1630–1980: A Mathematical Restatement. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brewer, Anthony. 1995. The Concept of Growth in Eighteenth-Century Economics. History of Political Economy 27(4): 609–638. https://doi.org/10.1215/00182702-27-4-609.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cass, David. 1965. Optimum Growth in an Aggregative Model of Capital Accumulation. Review of Economic Studies 32(3): 233–240. https://doi.org/10.2307/2295827.JSTOR2295827.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cass, David, and Tapan Mitra. 1991. Indefinitely Sustained Consumption Despite Exhaustible Natural Resources. Economic Theory 1(2): 119–146. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01211530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, John B. 1908. The Distribution of Wealth: A Theory of Wages. New York, The Macmillan Company: Interest and Profits.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, John B (1907) 1915. Essentials of Economic Theory. New York: The Macmillan Company.

  • Cournot, Arthur. (1838) 1960. Researches into the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth. New York: Kelley Publishing.

  • Dasgupta, Partha. 2020. Ramsey and Intergenerational Welfare Economics. Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, The Metaphysics Research Lab Center for the Study of Language and Information Stanford University, Stanford, CA, Summer 1–32.

  • Dimand, Robert W. 2019. The Fisher Diagram and the Neoclassical Theory of Interest and Capital. Great Thinkers in Economics. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-05177-8_4.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dobb, Maurice. 1929. A Skeptical View of the Theory of Wages. Economic Journal 39(156): 506–519.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duarte, Pedro G. 2010. Beyond Samuelson’s Chapter on Ramsey. History of Economic Ideas 28(3): 121–159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edgeworth, Francis Y. (1881) 1968. Mathematical Psychics, An Essay on the Application of Mathematics to the Moral Sciences. In Precursors in Mathematical Economics, An Anthology, ed. by W.J. Baumol and S.M. Goldfeld. London: University of London Press.

  • Fetter, Frank A. 1900. Recent Discussion of the Capital Concept. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 15(1): 1–45. https://doi.org/10.2307/1885860.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fetter, Frank A. 1914. Interest Theories, Old and New. The American Economic Review 4(1): 68–92.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fetter, Frank A. 1915. Economic Principles, vol. 1–2, New York: The Century Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, Irving. 1907a. The Rate of Interest. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, Irving. 1907b. Fetter on Capital and Income. Journal of Political Economy 15(7): 421–434.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, Irving. 1927. A Statistical Method for Measuring “Marginal Utility” and Testing the Justice of a Progressive Income Tax. In Economic Es- says Contributed in Honor of John Bates Clark, ed. J.H. HollanderNew York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, Irving (1906) 1965. The Nature of Capital and Income. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.

  • Friedman, Milton. 1957. A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton University Press: Princeton.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, Scott. 1991. The History and Philosophy of Social Science. New York: Routledge Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoselitz, Bert F., J.J. Spengler, J.M. Letiche, E. McKinley, J. Buttrick, and H.J. Bruton. 1960. Theories of Economic Growth. Glencoe: IL, The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jevons, William S. (1911) 1931. Theory of Political Economy. Fourth edition. London: Macmillan.

  • Keynes, John M. (1933) 1951. Essays in Biography. New York: Horizon Press.

  • Koopmans, Tjalling C. 1965. On the Concept of Optimal Economic Growth, The Economic Approach to Development Planning, 225–287. Chicago: Rand McNally.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lauderdale, James M. (1819) 1962. An Inquiry into the Nature and Origin of Public Wealth, and into the Means and Causes of Its Increase. Second edition, New York: Augustus M. Kelley.

  • Lucas, R.E. 1988. On the Mechanics of Economic Growth. Journal of Monetary Economics 22(1): 3–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malthus, Thomas R. (1820; 1836) 1964. Principles of Political Economy. Fairfield, N.J.: Augustus M. Kelley.

  • Marshall, Alfred. (1890; 1920) 2012. Principles of Economics. Eighth edition. London: Macmillan

  • McCulloch, John R. (1864) 1965. Principles of Political Economy. Fifth edition. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.

  • McVickar, John. (1825) 1966. Outlines of Political Economy. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.

  • Mill, John S. (1848) 1900. Political Economy, Vol. I. Silver Library edition. New York: P.F. Collier and Son.

  • Misak, Cheryl. 2020. Frank Ramsey: A Sheer Excess of Powers. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nævdal, Eric. 2019. New Insights from the Canonical Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans Growth Model. Macroeconomic Dynamics 25(6): 1569–1577. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1365100519000786.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paglin, Morton. 1961. Malthus and Lauderdale, the Anti-Ricardian Tradition. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.

  • Pareto, Vilfredo. (1911) 1968. Economie Mathematique. In Precursors in Mathematical Economics, An Anthology, ed. W.J. Baumol and S.M. Goldfeld. London: University of London Press.

  • Phelps, Edmund S. 1961. The Golden Rule of Accumulation. American Economic Review 51(4): 638–643.

    Google Scholar 

  • Phelps, Edmund S. 1965. A Second Essay on the Golden Rule of Accumulation. American Economic Review 55(4): 793–814.

    Google Scholar 

  • Phelps, Edmund S., and John G. Riley. 1978. Rawlsian Growth, Dynamic Programming of Capital and Wealth for Intergenerational ‘Maximin’ Justice. Review of Economic Studies 1: 103–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, Arthur C. 1918. The Economics of Welfare. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, Arthur C. (1928) 1929. A Study in Public Finance. 2nd edition. London: Macmillan.

  • Posada, Carlos E. 2011. Un modelo cuasi-Solow y el caso de la tasa de ahorro endogena. (A Solownian Model and the Case of the Endogenous Savings Rate. With English summary.). Desarrollo y Sociedad 68: 157–170.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rae, John. (1834) 1964. New Principles of Political Economy. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.

  • Romer, Paul. 1986. Increasing Returns and Long Run Growth. Journal of Political Economy 94(5): 1002–1037. https://doi.org/10.1086/261420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, Paul. 1990. Endogenous Technological Change. Journal of Political Economy 98(5): S71–S102. https://doi.org/10.1086/261725.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramsey, Frank P. (1920-1930). Frank Plumpton Ramsey Papers, Collection.128. The University of Pittsburg Library System (ULS), https://digital.library.pitt.edu/collection/frank-plumpton-ramsey-papers

  • Ramsey, Frank P. (1923) 1991. Socialism and Equality of Income. In Frank P. Ramsey, Notes on Philosophy, Probability and Mathematics, ed. by Maria C. Galavotti. Naples, Italy: Bibliopolis-Edizioni di Filosofia e Scienze, 313–19.

  • Ramsey, Frank P. (1925; 1926; 1928) 1930. The Foundations of Mathematics and other Logical Essays, ed. by R.B. Braithwaite. Routledge & Kegan Paul: London.

  • Ramsey, Frank P. 1927. A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation. Economic Journal 37(145): 47–61. https://doi.org/10.2307/2222721.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramsey, Frank P. 1928. A Mathematical Theory of Saving. Economic Journal. 38(152): 543–559. https://doi.org/10.2307/2224098.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ricardo, David. (1817; 1911) 2004. The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. London: J.M. Dent and Sons Ltd., Dover Publications, London

  • Rothbard, Murray N., 2011. The Pure Time-Preference Theory of Interest, ed. J.M. Herbener. Auburn, AL, Ludwig von Mises Institute.

  • Samuelson, Paul A. 1958. An Exact Consumption-Loan Model of Interest with or without Social Contrivance of Money. Journal of Political Economy 66(6): 467–482. https://doi.org/10.1086/258100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sent, E.M. 1997. Engineering Economic Dynamics. In New Economics and its History, ed. J.B. Davis, vol. 29, Durham and London: Duke University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, Adam. (1976) 1990. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Books I–III. London, Penguin Books.

  • Solow, Robert M. 1956. A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 70(1): 65–94. https://doi.org/10.2307/1884513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow, Robert M. 1974. Intergenerational Equity and Exhaustible Resources. Review of Economic Studies, Symposium Issue 41(5): 29–45. https://doi.org/10.2307/2296370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow, Robert M. 1992. An Almost Practical Step Towards Sustainability. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Spiegel, Henry W. 1996. The Growth of Economic Thought, 3rd ed, Durham, NC: Duke University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stokey, Nancy, and Robert Lucas. 1989. Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, James. 1956. The Interest-Elasticity of Transactions Demand for Cash. The Review of Economics and Statistics 38(3): 241–247. https://doi.org/10.2307/1925776.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, James. 1965. Money and Economic Growth. Econometrica 33(4): 671–684. https://doi.org/10.2307/1910352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, James. 1985. Neoclassical Theory in America. American Economic Review 75(6): 28–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • University of Pittsburgh Library System (ULS). 2023. Guide to the Frank Plumpton Ramsey Papers, 1920–1930, ASP.1983.01, https://digital.library.pitt.edu/islandora/object/pitt%3AUS-PPiU-asp198301/viewer#aspace_ref124_k6b

  • Uzawa, Hirofumi. 1961. On a Two-Sector Model of Economic Growth. Review of Economic Studies 29(1): 40–47. https://doi.org/10.2307/2296180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walras, Leon (1926, 1954) 1969. Elements of Pure Economics. Translated by William Jaffe. New York: Kelley.

  • Wicksell, Knut. 1914. Lexis Och und Böhm-Bawerk, Ekonomisk Tidskrift, 16(2): 294–300; 16(3): 321–334.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Francis E. Raymond.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Raymond, F.E. Connecting Classical and Early Neoclassical Views on Savings and Capital Formation to Modern Growth Theory Through the Lens of F. P. Ramsey. Eastern Econ J 50, 54–78 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41302-023-00262-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41302-023-00262-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation