Skip to main content
Log in

Sticks or Carrots? Comparing Effectiveness of Government Informal Economy Policies in Russia

  • Published:
Comparative Economic Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Which incentives have the strongest impact on the size of the informal economy? Is it about government’s pressure against entrepreneurs operating in this sector, or is it about the benefits of legality? The goal of this paper is to explicitly contrast the role of sticks (court repressiveness) and carrots (financial aid to small- and medium-sized firms) as factors determining the size of the informal economy, using the case of the Russian taxi market. It uses a unique dataset of taxi licensing data from regional transport departments and indicators for taxi market demand and supply to estimate the extent of informal business. When controlling for market demand and supply, it finds a strong and robust positive effect of sanctions on the size of the official market, with higher repressiveness leading to a smaller informal economy. In contrast, the effect of carrots was insignificant. The results suggest that the effectiveness of carrot policies is compromised when entrepreneurs operate informally to avoid dealing with corrupt bureaucrats and have low trust in the government.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In this study, corruption is defined as non-compliance with the rules and regulations governing the behavior of public officials.

  2. According to the current Corruption Perception Index Ranking published by Transparency International. The experiments were conducted in USA (13), UK (3), Israel (2), Austria, Canada, Costa Rica, Hong Kong, Italy, New Zealand, Spain and Switzerland (each 1).

  3. Sticks and carrots relate to direct measures targeted at formalization. There are many policies that have an indirect effect on the size of the shadow economy, which are not considered here.

  4. In the case of Russia, despite a drastic reduction of rate and complexity of income taxes to a flat 13% in 2001 the shadow economy has not shrunk (Schneider et al. 2010); however, the tax reform has been connected to a reduction in informal employment (Slonimczyk 2012) and higher tax compliance (Gorodnichenko et al. 2009).

  5. A more general overview of measurements of the informal economy in Russia is given in “Appendix 2.”

  6. There is even a Russian word for informal taxis (bombily) and working as an informal taxi driver (bombit’).

  7. After 2015, Uber and its local competitors such as Yandex.Taxi and Gett began disrupting the Russian taxi market in the bigger Russian cities. As is the case in other countries, these firms were met with resistance from official taxi firms. The incumbents pointed out that Uber drivers often did not have an official taxi license (Buravtseva 2015). As a consequence, Uber began cooperating with the Moscow authorities and implemented policies that required their drivers to upload their taxi licenses during registration on the Uber platform (Shebalina 2016; Uber 2017). In the case of Moscow, the growth of Uber and its competitors led to a drastic reduction of prices (while Uber does not publish ride statistics, Yandex.Taxi grew threefold in 2016, Roem.ru 2017). This resulted in pressure on informal taxis. Especially the younger Muscovites prefer to order cabs on their phones. Here, the combination of Uber-like services and a growing number of licenses is leading to an increasing formalization of the taxi industry. This is indicated by the number of active licenses in Moscow and Moscow region, which increased from 121,000 to 153,000 in the past 18 months (Mer Moskvy 2017). Thus, the developments triggered by Uber are somewhat contrary to what happened in markets with limited license supply, where the number of unlicensed drivers increased. However, Uber is so far (mid-2017) only present in 30 cities in Russia (Taxiuber.ru 2017). The dataset of this paper is not affected by Uber and co., however, as it considers only licenses issued until mid-2015. Also, in the econometric analysis, we control for urbanization (with large urban centers being the only place Uber has been active in Russia) and also conduct a robustness check that excludes the primary markets of the new services (regions with more than 5000 operators).

  8. TAXIreal is bigger than TAXIobs, hence TAXIobs − TAXIreal < 0. If TAXIobs goes up and TAXIreal does not change, TAXIobs − TAXIreal increases (but decreases in absolute terms, i.e., the gap between the observed and the real number of taxis goes down).

  9. Note that, hypothetically, some of these variables (urbanization, economic development, etc.) could also have an impact on legalization, if there were a demand of the population for legality of taxis in Russia. Empirically, however, this demand appears to be very small. In a 2015 survey, the ‘official yellow’ color of the car (which the legal Russian taxis are supposed to bear) was the factor with the smallest importance among all affecting the choice of the taxi service; the most important factors remained the price of the service and the waiting time (VTSIOM 2015).

  10. If we transform the regression in OLS and compute the VIF statistics, for none of the specifications (1)–(6) reported in Table 2 we find evidence of strong multicollinearity (VIF exceeding 10).

  11. As always, the interpretation of the marginal effects we reported should be made with caution and serve merely to demonstrate the extent of the effects.

  12. More specifically, the data are available for the regional capitals.

  13. If we simply control for the number of crimes per capita or satisfaction with one’s security, our results also do not change.

  14. There are several problems with including this variable in the set of covariates. First, the quality of information is extremely poor: suffices to say that Rosstat reports the highest taxi prices (in Rubles) in Adygea and Dagestan—two very poor Russian ethnic republics of the Northern Caucasus. Rosstat is also obviously unable to measure prices of the unofficial taxis (and appears to be imprecisely measuring the official taxi prices as well). Second, the interpretation of including this variable in the set of covariates is not clear, since the price level should also be determined by demand and supply, which we control for anyway.

  15. In particular, we find a significant and positive effect of regional subsidies in case we transform subsidies into logs; in the specification (6) for the median regressions and if we use logs of all covariates. Federal subsidies are significant, if one controls for corruption levels, in specification (6) if we use logs of all covariates, and in specification (2) if one controls for the price level for taxi services, but have a negative effect.

  16. For obvious reasons, data on the illegal market are unavailable; it is prudent to assume that they are mostly dominated by single-cab drivers, who may, however, be involved in various forms of informal networks or enjoy some sort of protection from criminal groups or corrupt local officials.

  17. Note that in the regression tables we measure the subsidies in trillion rubles to obtain coefficients easy to present in a table.

References

  • Aidis, R., and Y. Adachi. 2007. Russia: Firm Entry and Survival Barriers. Economic Systems 31(4): 391–411.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alexeev, M., and W. Pyle. 2003. A Note on Measuring the Unofficial Economy in the Former Soviet Republics. Economics of Transition 11(1): 153–175.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allingham, M., and A. Sandmo. 1972. Income Tax Evasion: A Theoretical Analysis. Journal of Public Economics 1(2): 323–338.

    Google Scholar 

  • Asea, P.K. 1996. The Informal Sector: Baby or Bath Water? A Comment. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 45: 163–171.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G.S. 1968. Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach. Journal of Political Economy 76(2): 169–217.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bemelmans-Videc, M.-L., R.C. Rist, and E. Vedung (eds.). 1998. Carrots, Sticks & Sermons: Policy Instruments and Their Evaluation. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blackwell, C. 2010. A Meta-Analysis of Incentive Effects in Tax Compliance Experiments. In Developing Alternative Frameworks Explaining Tax Compliance, ed. J. Alm, J. Martinez-Vazquez, and B. Torgler, 97–112. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brockmann, H., P. Genschel, and L. Seelkopf. 2016. Happy Taxation: Increasing Tax Compliance Through Positive Rewards? Journal of Public Policy 36(3): 381–406.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buehn, A. 2012. The Shadow Economy in German Regions: An Empirical Assessment. German Economic Review 13(3): 275–290.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buravtseva, M. 2015. Peterburgskiye taksisty prosyat zapretit’ Uber, Gett i ‘Yandeks.Taksi’. Vedomosti. https://www.vedomosti.ru/business/articles/2015/07/03/599119-peterburgskie-taksisti-prosyat-zapretit-uber-gett-i-yandekstaksi. Accessed 11 Dec 2017.

  • Chaudhuri, K., F. Schneider, and S. Chattopadhyay. 2006. The Size and Development of the Shadow Economy: An Empirical Investigation from States of India. Journal of Development Economics 80(2): 428–443.

    Google Scholar 

  • Choi, J.P., and M. Thum. 2005. Corruption and the Shadow Economy. International Economic Review 46(3): 817–836.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chong, A., and M. Gradstein. 2007. Inequality and Informality. Journal of Public Economics 91(1–2): 159–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dabla-Norris, E., M. Gradstein, and G. Inchauste. 2008. What Causes Firms to Hide Output? The Determinants of Informality. Journal of Development Economics 85(1–2): 1–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, J.S., G. Hecht, and J.D. Perkins. 2003. Social Behaviors, Enforcement, and Tax Compliance Dynamics. Accounting Review 78(1): 39–69.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Paula, A., and J.A. Scheinkman. 2007. The Informal Sector. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER Working Paper No. 13486.

  • De Soto, H. 1989. The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in the Third World. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dekker, H., E. Oranje, P. Renooy, F. Rosing, and C.C. Williams. 2010. Joining Up the Fight Against Undeclared Work in the European Union. Brussels: DG Employment, Social Affairs and Equal Opportunities.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A., C. Kotsogiannis, and S. McCorriston. 2009. How Do Institutions Affect Corruption and the Shadow Economy? International Tax and Public Finance 16(6): 773–796.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eilat, Y., and C. Zinnes. 2002. The Shadow Economy in Transition Countries: Friend or Foe? A Policy Perspective. World Development 30(7): 1233–1254.

    Google Scholar 

  • Enste, D.H. 2010. Regulation and Shadow Economy: Empirical Evidence for 25 OECD-Countries. Constitutional Political Economy 21(3): 231–248.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ermolyuk, A. 2015. V Kemerove nelegal’nykh taksistov lovyat «na zhivtsa». Komsomol’skaya Pravda. https://www.kp.ru/daily/26348.5/3231031/. Accessed 11 Dec 2017.

  • Farrell, D. 2004. The Hidden Dangers of the Informal Economy. McKinsey Quarterly 3: 26–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feige, E.L. 1990. Defining and Estimating Underground and Informal Economies: The New Institutional Economics Approach. World Development 18(7): 989–1002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feige, E.L. 2016. Reflections on the Meaning and Measurement of Unobserved Economies: What Do We Really Know About the ‘Shadow Economy’. Journal of Tax Administration 2(1): 5–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feige, E.L., and I. Urban. 2008. Measuring Underground (Unobserved, Non-observed, Unrecorded) economies in Transition Countries: Can We Trust GDP? Journal of Comparative Economics 36(2): 287–306.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feld, L.P., and B.S. Frey. 2002. Trust Breeds Trust: How Taxpayers are Treated. Economics of Governance 3(2): 87–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feld, L.P., and B.S. Frey. 2007. Tax Compliance as the Result of a Psychological Tax Contract: The Role of Incentives and Responsive Regulation. Law & Policy 29(1): 102–120.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feld, L.P., and F. Schneider. 2010. Survey on the Shadow Economy and Undeclared Earnings in OECD Countries. German Economic Review 11(2): 109–149.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, E., S. Johnson, D. Kaufmann, and P. Zoido-Lobaton. 2000. Dodging the Grabbing Hand: The Determinants of Unofficial Activity in 69 Countries. Journal of Public Economics 76(3): 459–493.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frye, T., and A. Shleifer. 1997. The Invisible Hand and the Grabbing Hand. American Economic Review 87(2): 354–358.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frye, T., and E. Zhuravskaya. 2000. Rackets, Regulation, and the Rule of Law. Journal of Law Economics and Organization 16(2): 478–502.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerring, J. 2006. Case Study Research Principles and Practices. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • GIBDD. 2016. Gosavtoinspektsiya: Narusheniya i shtrafy. https://www.gibdd.ru/mens/fines/. Accessed 16 Dec 2016.

  • Goncharova, O. 2011. Taksisty v zakone. Vedomosti. https://www.vedomosti.ru/newspaper/articles/2011/06/09/taksisty_v_zakone. Accessed 11 Dec 2017.

  • Gorodnichenko, Y., J. Martinez-Vazquez, and K. Sabirianova Peter. 2009. Myth and Reality of Flat Tax Reform: Micro Estimates of Tax Evasion Response and Welfare Effects in Russia. Journal of Political Economy 117(3): 504–554.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hart, K. 1973. Informal Income Opportunities and Urban Employment in Ghana. Journal of Modern African Studies 11(1): 61–89.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hindriks, J., M. Keen, and A. Muthoo. 1999. Corruption, Extortion and Evasion. Journal of Public Economics 74(3): 395–430.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, S., D. Kaufmann, A. Shleifer, M.I. Goldman, and M.L. Weitzman. 1997. The Unofficial Economy in Transition. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1997(2): 159–239.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, S., D. Kaufmann, and P. Zoido-Lobatón. 1998. Regulatory Discretion and the Unofficial Economy. American Economic Review 88(2): 387–392.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, D., and A. Kaliberda. 1996. Integrating the Unofficial Economy into the Dynamics of Post-Socialist Economies: A Framework for Analysis and Evidence. In Economic Transition in Russia and the New States of Eurasia, ed. B. Kamiński, 81–120. London: M.E. Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kazemier, B. 2006. Monitoring the Underground Economy: A Survey of Methods and Estimates. Jahrbuch Schattenwirtschaft 7: 11–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kenyon, T., and E. Kapaz. 2005. The Informality Trap. Washington: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, B.-Y., and Y. Kang. 2009. The Informal Economy and the Growth of small ENTErprises in Russia. Economics of Transition 17(2): 351–376.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirchgässner, G. 2017. On Estimating the Size of the Shadow Economy. German Economic Review 18(1): 99–111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirchler, E., E. Hoelzl, and I. Wahl. 2008. Enforced Versus Voluntary Tax Compliance: The ‘Slippery Slope’ Framework. Journal of Economic Psychology 29(2): 210–225.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kireenko, A., Y. Ivanov, E. Nevzorova, and O. Polyakova. 2017. Shadow Economy in the Regions of the Russian Federation and the Ukraine. In New Trends in Finance and Accounting, ed. D. Procházka, 301–312. Cham: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kitching, J. 2006. A Burden on Business? Reviewing the Evidence Base on Regulation and Small-Business Performance. Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy 24(6): 799–814.

    Google Scholar 

  • Komarova, T.V. 2003. Shadow Economy in Russia’s Regions, Master Thesis. New Economic School.

  • La Porta, R., and A. Shleifer. 2008. The Unofficial Economy and Economic Development. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2008(2): 353–363.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ledeneva, A.V. 2006. How Russia Really Works: The Informal Practices that Shaped Post-Soviet Politics and Business. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Libman, A., V. Kozlov, and A. Schultz. 2012. Roving Bandits in Action: Outside Option and Governmental Predation in Autocracies. Kyklos 65(4): 526–562.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loayza, N.V. 1996. The Economics of the Informal Sector: A Simple Model and Some Empirical Evidence from Latin America. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 45: 129–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loayza, N., A.M. Oviedo, and L. Servén. 2005. The Impact of Regulation on Growth and Informality Cross-Country Evidence. Rochester, NY: Social Science Research Network, SSRN Scholarly Paper No. 755087.

  • Mer Moskvy. 2013. Zasedaniye kollegii Departamenta transporta i razvitiya dorozhno-transportnoy infrastruktury goroda Moskvy. https://www.mos.ru/mayor/transcripts/522056. Accessed 16 Dec 2016.

  • Mer Moskvy. 2017. Reyestr vydannykh razresheniy na osushchestvleniye deyatel’nosti po perevozke passazhirov i bagazha legkovym taksi na territorii goroda Moskvy i Moskovskoy oblasti. https://www.mos.ru/pgu/ru/application/taxi/zapros/#step_1. Accessed 9 July 2017.

  • MinEkonomRazvitiya. 2016a. Federal’nyye programmy podderzhki malogo i srednego predprinimatel’stva. http://smb.gov.ru/measuresupport/programs/celved/. Accessed 20 Jan 2017.

  • MinEkonomRazvitiya. 2016b. Gosudarstvennaya podderzhka malogo i srednego predprinimatel’stva v 2016 godu. Moscow: MinEkonomRazvitiya.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mironov, M. and E. Zhuravskaya. 2011. Corruption in Procurement and Shadow Campaign Financing: Evidence from Russia. In: SSRN eLibrary.

  • Murphy, K. 2005. Regulating More Effectively: The Relationship Between Procedural Justice, Legitimacy, and Tax Non-Compliance. Journal of Law and Society 32(4): 562–589.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nikolayenko, S., Y. Lissovolik, and R. MacFarquhar. 1997. The Shadow Economy in Russia’s Regions. Russian Economic Trends 4: 108–117.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paneyakh, E. 2014. Faking Performance Together: Systems of Performance Evaluation in Russian Enforcement Agencies and Production of Bias and Privilege. Post-Soviet Affairs 30(2–3): 115–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pokida, A., and N. Zybunovskaya. 2016. Stimuly i Motivy Uchastiya Rabotnikov, Zanyatykh po Naymu, v Ofitsial’noy i Nekriminal’noy Tenevoy Ekonomicheskoy Deyatel’nosti. Moscow: RANEPA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rist, R.C. 1998. Choosing the Right Policy Instrument at the Right Time: The Contextual Challenges of Selection and Implementation. In Carrots, Sticks, and Sermons: Policy Instruments and Their Evaluation, ed. M.-L. Bemelmans-Videc, R.C. Rist, and E. Vedung, 159–162. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roem.ru. 2017. Yandeks.Taksi podderzhali demping Uber. Zhdyom Gett? https://roem.ru/10-04-2017/247339/uber-zateyal-demping/. Accessed 9 July 2017.

  • Rose-Ackerman, S. 2001. Trust, Honesty and Corruption: Reflection on the State-Building Process. European Journal of Sociology 42(3): 526–570.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rossiyskaya gazeta. 2005. Taksistam otmenili litsenzii. Rossiyskaya gazeta. https://rg.ru/2005/06/10/mintrans.html. Accessed 11 Dec 2017.

  • Rossiyskaya gazeta. 2011a. Izmeneniya v otdel’nyye zakonodatel’nyye akty RF, kasayushchiyesya PDD. Rossiyskaya gazeta. https://rg.ru/2011/04/25/pdd-dok.html. Accessed 11 Dec 2017.

  • Rossiyskaya gazeta. 2011b. Ekspert: Novyy zakon o taksi ne vyvedet iz teni ‘bombil’. Rossiyskaya gazeta. https://rg.ru/2011/10/05/reg-szfo/taxi.html. Accessed 11 Dec 2017.

  • Rosstat. 2015. Maloe i Srednee Predprinimatel’stvo Rossii 2015. Moscow: Rosstat.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosstat. 2016a. Stranitsa summarnoy metodologii. Rynok truda: zanyatost. http://www.gks.ru/bgd/free/b00_24/IssWWW.exe/Stg/d000/I000091R.HTM. Accessed 21 Dec 2016.

  • Rosstat. 2016b. Rabochaya sila, zanyatost’ i bezrabotitsa v Rossii—Prilozheniye k sborniku (informatsiya v razreze sub”yektov Rossiyskoy Federatsii). Moscow: Rosstat.

    Google Scholar 

  • Safavian, M.S., D.H. Graham, and C. Gonzalez-Vega. 2001. Corruption and Microenterprises in Russia. World Development 29(7): 1215–1224.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sapsford, R., P. Abbott, C. Haerpfer, and C. Wallace. 2015. Trust in Post-Soviet Countries, Ten Years on. European Politics and Society 16(4): 523–539.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, F. 2005. Shadow Economies Around the World: What Do We Really Know? European Journal of Political Economy 21(3): 598–642.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, F., and C.C. Williams. 2013. The Shadow Economy. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, F., A. Buehn, and C.E. Montenegro. 2010. New Estimates for the Shadow Economies all over the World. International Economic Journal 24(4): 443–461.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schreiner, M., and G. Woller. 2003. Microenterprise Development Programs in the United States and in the Developing World. World Development 31(9): 1567–1580.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schultz, A., V. Kozlov, and A. Libman. 2014. Judicial Alignment and Criminal Justice: Evidence from Russian Courts. Post-Soviet Affairs 30(2–3): 137–170.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sepulveda, L., and S. Syrett. 2007. Out of the Shadows? Formalisation Approaches to Informal Economic Activity. Policy & Politics 35(1): 87–104.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shchedrova, O. 2014. Bombily v bezvykhodnom prilozhenii. Kommersant. https://www.kommersant.ru/doc/2380754. Accessed 11 Dec 2017.

  • Shebalina, Y. 2016. Uber podpisal soglasheniye s vlastyami Moskvy. Vedomosti. https://www.vedomosti.ru/business/news/2016/03/14/633477-uber-soglashenie-sotrudnichestve-transporta. Accessed 11 Dec 2017.

  • Slonimczyk, F. 2012. The Effect of Taxation on Informal Employment: Evidence from the Russian Flat Tax Reform. In: Informal Employment in Emerging and Transition Economies, 55–99. Bingley, England: Emerald Group.

  • Small Business Council. 2004. Small Business in the Informal Economy: Making the Transition to the Formal Economy. London: Small Business Council.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, N., and E. Thomas. 2015. Determinants of Russia’s Informal Economy: The Impact of Corruption and Multinational Firms. Journal of East-West Business 21(2): 102–128.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taxiuber.ru. 2017. V kakikh gorodakh rabotayet Uber. http://taxiuber.ru/cities.html. Accessed 9 July 2017.

  • Thiessen, U. 2003. The Impact of Fiscal Policy and Deregulation on Shadow Economies in Transition Countries: The Case of Ukraine. Public Choice 114(3–4): 295–318.

    Google Scholar 

  • Timm, C. 2010. Neopatrimonialism by Default. State Politics and Domination in Georgia after the Rose Revolution. Conference paper, workshop ‘Neopatrimonialism in Various World Regions’. Hamburg: GIGA German Institute of Global and Area Studies.

  • Torgler, B. 2007. Tax Morale in Central and Eastern European Countries. In Tax Evasion, Trust and State Capacities: How Good is Tax Morale in Central and Eastern Europe, ed. N. Hayoz and S. Hug, 155–186. Bern: Peter Lang.

    Google Scholar 

  • Torgler, B., and F. Schneider. 2009. The Impact of Tax Morale and Institutional Quality on the Shadow Economy. Journal of Economic Psychology 30(2): 228–245.

    Google Scholar 

  • Uber. 2017. Razresheniya na perevozku passazhirov i bagazha legkovym taksi dlya voditeley v Moskve. https://drive.uber.com/moscow/license_info/. Accessed 9 July 2017.

  • van Eck, R., and B. Kazemier. 1989. Zwarte arbeid, een empirische en methodologische studie. Amsterdam: University of Amsterdam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Varese, F. 2005. The Russian Mafia: Private Protection in a New Market Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vasileva, A. 2017. Trapped in Informality: Small Firms in Russian Capitalism. In: Economic Crisis and Industrial PoliciesPolicy Options for a Return to Growth in Russia (forthcoming), ed. R. Traub-Merz and D. Efimenko. Moscow: Political Encyclopedia.

  • Vedung, E. 1998. Policy Instruments: Typologies and Theories. In Carrots, Sticks, and Sermons: Policy Instruments and Their Evaluation, ed. M.L. Bemelmans-Videc, R.C. Rist, and E. Vedung, 21–58. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vorobyev, P. 2015. Estimating Informal Economy Share in Russian Regions, Economics Education Research Consortium Working Paper (E15/02).

  • VTSIOM. 2015. Servis Taxi: Chto Izmenilos’ s Prikhodom Novykh Tekhnologiy, Press-Vypusk No. 2985.

  • Webley, P., and S. Halstead. 1986. Tax Evasion on the Micro: Significant Simulations or Expedient Experiments? Journal of Interdisciplinary Economics 1(2): 87–100.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wenzel, M. 2004. The Social Side of Sanctions: Personal and Social Norms as Moderators of Deterrence. Law and Human Behavior 28(5): 547–567.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams, C.C. 2014. Confronting the Shadow Economy: Evaluating Tax Compliance and Behaviour Policies. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams, C.C. 2016. What is to be Done About Entrepreneurship in the Shadow Economy? In Entrepreneurship and the Shadow Economy, ed. A. Sauka, F. Schneider, and C.C. Williams, 201–226. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams, C.C., and S.J. Nadin. 2012. Tackling Entrepreneurship in the Informal Economy: Evaluating the Policy Options. Journal of Entrepreneurship and Public Policy 1(2): 111–124.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams, C., and S.J. Nadin. 2014. Facilitating the Formalisation of Entrepreneurs in the Informal Economy: Towards a Variegated Policy Approach. Journal of Entrepreneurship and Public Policy 3(1): 33–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams, C.C., and J. Round. 2008. The Hidden Enterprise Culture of Moscow: Entrepreneurship and Off-the-Books Working Practices. Journal of Developmental Entrepreneurship 13(4): 445–462.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wiseman, T. 2013. US Shadow Economies: A State-Level Study. Constitutional Political Economy 24(4): 310–335.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. 2016. Doing Business 2017: Equal Opportunity for All. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yakovlev, A.A. 2006. The Evolution of Business—State Interaction in Russia: From State Capture to Business Capture? Europe-Asia Studies 58(7): 1033–1056.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The study has been funded within the framework of the Basic Research Program at the National Research University Higher School of Economics (HSE) and by the Russian Academic Excellence Project “5-100”. We appreciate the very helpful suggestions of three anonymous referees. All mistakes are our own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alexander Libman.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Summary Statistics for Key Variables

Variable

No. obs.

Mean

SD

Min

Max

Bus passenger turnover, bln passenger kilometers

79

1.565

1.489

0.006

6.976

Federal subsidies, trln. RUB (total spending in 3 years)

79

0.330

0.508

0.000

3.423

Herfindahl–Hirschman index, between 0 and 1

76

1.979

2.180

0.175

11.402

Highest number of cars by an operator

76

416.040

523.052

2.000

2904.000

Ln cars per capita (per 1000 people)

79

5.607

0.234

4.376

6.192

Ln income per capita (monthly, thousands of RUB, corrected by regional price levels)

79

3.168

0.199

2.601

3.655

Ln territory, thousands sq. km

79

4.331

1.412

0.336

8.034

Number of licenses

76

6790.500

10,903.800

102.000

65,551.000

Number of operators

76

1817.211

2412.953

65.000

14,097.000

Number of single-car operators

76

1328.934

1749.724

57.000

10,747.000

Population, mln. people

79

1.805

1.805

0.051

12.197

Regional subsidies, trln. RUB (total spending in 3 years)

79

0.150

0.243

0.002

1.816

Repressiveness (corruption), between 0 and 1

76

0.220

0.227

0.000

1.000

Repressiveness (fraud), between 0 and 1

79

0.418

0.165

0.077

0.965

Repressiveness (illicit entrepreneurship), between 0 and 1

44

0.151

0.281

0.000

1.000

Repressiveness (tax evasion), between 0 and 1

67

0.051

0.162

0.000

1.000

Repressiveness, between 0 and 1

79

0.467

0.124

0.259

0.962

Road density, road km per mln. sq. km of the territory

79

0.275

0.384

0.001

2.438

Urbanization, %

79

70.028

12.635

29.200

100.000

Appendix 2: Definition and Measurement of the Informal Economy

The research on the informal economy uses a plurality of different terms for the phenomenon it describes, many of which are only vaguely defined (van Eck and Kazemier 1989 list 45 different terms that are in use). Hart’s (1973) anthropological work is mostly credited with coining the word “informal economy.” A useful disambiguation of the different types of “underground economies” which are often mixed together is offered by Feige (1990). First, it singles out the illegal economy which consists of activities that are prohibited by law. The desired policy goal here is eradication, not formalization. There is also an unreported economy consisting of income that is not declared to the tax authorities with the motive of tax evasion. In contrast, the unrecorded economy comprises household activities or subsistence farming. Finally, the informal economy is production that circumvents formal rules (both avoiding costs and foregoing benefits). It is this part of the underground economy for which institutional causes such as corruption are the most salient (Feige 1990: 992–993). In our study, it is the informal economy we investigate.

While economists have been quite inventive in finding ways to understand the size of the informal economy, the different methods used have not yet led to converging results (Feige and Urban 2008). The existing literature can be differentiated into direct and indirect estimation approaches (a comprehensive overview can be found in Kazemier 2006). One direct approach is to estimate the size of the informal economy by evaluating small samples of actual cases of tax fraud. The Russian Federal State Statistics Services (Rosstat) uses another direct approach, conducting monthly surveys to estimate the share of informal employment in Russia (Rosstat 2016a). However, even if done carefully, measurement through surveys is haunted by distorted self-reporting.

These difficulties led to the development of indirect approaches for measuring the informal economy. We need to highlight that these approaches are not implicitly relevant for our study, because we do not attempt to find out the aggregate size of informality in the economy—thus, we report them only for completeness. One common method is to compare growth rates of formal (observed) GDP with measures that correlate with total GDP (including the informal economy) such as liquidity demand or electricity consumption (Kaufmann and Kaliberda 1996). More recently, indicators and explanatory variables have been used to estimate the size of the informal economy as a latent variable in MIMIC (Multiple Indicator Multiple Causes) models (Schneider et al. 2010). This allows to construct data for an unprecedented number of countries (162 in Schneider et al. 2010). The shortcoming of indirect approaches is that they can only capture relative changes in the size of the informal economy. To generate absolute values, they have to be initialized using estimates derived from direct measures and estimates. Depending on this initial calibration, the results of these models vary drastically (Alexeev and Pyle 2003). This adds to the complexity of the procedure and has led to renewed criticism regarding the transparency of the procedures (Feige 2016) and the possible applications of the resulting datasets (Kirchgässner 2017).

There are relatively few studies that use subnational data for the estimation of informal economies. Some of the exceptions are studies using MIMIC models on Germany (Buehn 2012), India (Chaudhuri et al. 2006) and the USA (Wiseman 2013). In the case of Russia, besides the survey-based Rosstat data on informal employment (Rosstat 2016b), there have been several studies that estimate the size of the informal economy on a regional level. They rely on differences in reported income and expenditures (Nikolayenko et al. 1997), regional data on electricity consumption (Komarova 2003; Kim and Kang 2009; Smith and Thomas 2015; Vorobyev 2015) and MIMIC models (Kireenko et al. 2017). In contrast to these studies, this paper uses a novel dataset derived from taxi licenses and focuses on one specific market. It does not produce a measure for the absolute size of the informal economy nor for changes over time, but only for relative regional differences.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kluge, J.N., Libman, A. Sticks or Carrots? Comparing Effectiveness of Government Informal Economy Policies in Russia. Comp Econ Stud 60, 605–637 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41294-017-0042-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41294-017-0042-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation