Introduction

This article benefitted from the insightful comments of Diane Fromage, Mariolina Eliantonio, Kathryn Wright, Jakub Kerlin and other participants of the University of Maastricht and University of York joint workshop “Constitutional Challenges in the Field of Financial Regulation” which took place on 19 October 2020 as well as Dalvinder Singh and Marta Božina Beroš and other participants at the University of Zagreb’s conference “EU Financial Regulation and Markets: Beyond Fragmentation and Differentiation” which took place on 26–27 November 2020 as well as two anonymous reviewers. Any errors remain my own.

Cross-border banking presents a unique set of problems from the point of view of arranging EU oversight. Banks operating across a number of Member States can be highly integrated in terms of their management, strategy and cash flows. However, their distinct parts operating in different Member States, either as integrated outposts (branches) or separate legal entities connected through ownership (subsidiaries),Footnote 2 may be perceived differently in terms of their riskiness or significance to the public interest when viewed from the parent company at top of the company hierarchy (the home Member State) or from the local market (the host Member State). The subjective perception of risk in the context of EU-wide or local financial stability has been the source of challenges in arranging cross-border cooperation of authorities overseeing such multinational EU banks. Joint oversight across a number of Member States needs to assuage the concerns of different national authorities which in the absence of safeguards or adequate trust revert to ring-fencing and other measures protecting the local market. Such interventions result in fragmentation, undermining the internal market and foregoing the benefits of integration. Structuring of administrative cooperation in a way which is conducive to trust-building and mutual engagement is an essential condition for overcoming disintegrative tendencies. But which multilevel design yields best results? Is centralisation always superior or are looser forms of cooperation better at creating trust? The design of the post-crisis resolution framework creates a unique opportunity for a comparative assessment of different models of administrative cooperation in this regard.

With the creation of the European Banking Union (EBU) and the overhaul of the European Union’s (EU) bank regulation framework since the Great Financial Crisis of 2008, two types of multilevel administrative structures tasked with bank crisis preparation and management (resolution law) across the EU’s internal market have been created. Within the EBU, this is the highly integrated and centralised Single Resolution Mechanism, SRM. For the EU as a whole, the less integrated and network-like resolution colleges have been put in place. Both arrangements are subject to an additional layer of complexity, where even in horizontal contexts, they allow for differentiation between national regulatory authorities (NRAs) depending on whether they are members of the euro area or not, or which part of the bank they are responsible for. Such complexity became realised with the entry of Croatia and Bulgaria into close cooperation with the EBU in October 2020 as a precondition to their euro area membership. This article analyses the different models of national and EU public authority cooperation in EU resolution law. It further assesses their relative suitability to achieve their goals in relation to the objectives of relevant EU law and discusses the constitutional conundrums which arise.

To this end, this article proceeds as follows. Section ``Cross-border bank resolution in the EU: falling short'' reviews the evidence of how the administrative structures at EU and EBU levels with regard to EU resolution law operate in practice and formulates the article’s puzzle to be answered. Section ``Multilevel cooperation in the EU cross-border bank resolution: between centralisation and networks'' comparatively analyses the set-up of multilevel administrative structures established for resolution of cross-border bank groups in the EU and the EBU, in particular explaining their respective complexity. Section ``Explaining the outcomes of multilevel administrative cooperation'' discusses possible explanations for the different results achieved across the administrative structures. Section ``Conclusions'' concludes and discusses the implications and possible constitutional problems arising from the article’s findings.

Cross-border bank resolution in the EU: falling short

Since the Great Financial Crisis new regulatory tools were created to be wielded by the new bespoke authorities (resolution authorities) to address the lack of administrative capacity for management of cross-border banking crises [13]. Their responsibilities differ from those of regular supervisors who concentrate on monitoring the day-to-day performance, safeness and soundness of the bank. By contrast, resolution law allows for both crisis management and ex ante preparation for bank failure by pre-allocating losses, removing specific impediments which are the source of the “too-big-to-fail” problems and establishing playbooks for how a failure would be (publicly) managed. In addition, and remedying a pre-crisis lacuna, the 2014 Bank Resolution and Recovery Directive (BRRD) [24], which applies to all EU Member States, created a new form of cross-border cooperation, namely resolution colleges. These integrated administrative structures are charged with implementation of BRRD rules and tasks related to ex ante bank crisis prevention and management of crises with regard to individual cross-border bank groups. In the context of EBU, the establishment of a more centralised mechanism for supervision (Single Supervision Mechanism, SSM), laid the groundwork for the subsequent creation of an analogous mechanism for resolution, namely the SRM [28]. The SRM, as this article shall discuss, is formally significantly more integrated than the resolution colleges, for example, through the centralised decision-making. However, there are significant flaws in its design, which as the empirical evidence suggests, preclude full attainment of SRM’s regulatory objectives. Some such flaws become amplified in the context of adherence of non-euro area Member States to the mechanism. As a first step in the analysis, I review the objectives, means and outcomes of BRRD and SRM in the cross-border context.

Objectives

In the aftermath of the widespread bank bailouts, resolution was created as a procedure to reinstall market discipline, protect creditors, investors, depositors, taxpayers and the real economy from the instability caused by financial collapse [24 Art. 32(1), 28 Art. 14]. BRRD and SRM set up the administrative framework within which these objectives are to be attained. Specifically, in a cross-border context at the EU and EBU levels, respectively, they seek to achieve a number of specific objectives with regard to managing bank failure, facilitating market integration and improving legal certainty.

With regard to managing cross-border bank failure, the BRRD requires an ex ante definition of resolution strategy of the bank (that is the decision on how different procedures across Member States involved would relate to each other in terms of failure) and the removal of impediments to the bank’s resolvability (that is any specific obstacles to smooth cross-border cooperation) [24 Art. 10 on resolution planning and Art. 17 on powers to remove impediments to resolvability]. The definition of resolution strategy of the cross-border bank implies choosing whether it would be resolved as a single entity (so-called Single Point of Entry, SPOE approach) or whether distinct entities would be dealt with separately (so-called Multiple Point of Entry, MPOE approach) [30]. In the case of the former, all coordination of bank crisis management is done by a single authority of the state where the parent entity is established. Decisions of this authority then have legal effects across all jurisdictions where the bank is active. In the case of the latter, multiple authorities cooperate with each other, but remain responsible for “their” part of the bank. From a supranational perspective, SPOE is preferable in terms of overall efficiency of resolution [33]; however, it requires significant trust between authorities in addition to a suitable cross-border group structure, if the ex ante resolution plan is to be followed once the crisis occurs [31 p. 44]. Over the course of the GFC, lack of trust between authorities resulted in ring-fencing of national parts of a cross-border bank, which subsequently increased the overall costs of crisis management and persistent market fragmentation. Consequently, improving cooperation between NRAs is in fact a key objective of both BRRD and SRM. In the context of SRM, one of the objectives of centralisation is specifically to improve efficiency of cross-border bank failure [28 Recitals 9–10]. Second, the establishment of a common cross-border resolution framework is meant to facilitate greater market integration and protection of financial stability and critical functions provided by banks, in order to improve the outcomes for the consumers and clients [28 Recital 4]. Finally, establishing a new common procedure for dealing with bank failures is to improve legal certainty, especially in a cross-border setting [24 Recital 3, 28 Recital 1].

Means

With a view to achieving these objectives, the EU resolution law establishes dedicated procedures oriented at achieving ex ante preparedness (resolution plans) as well as specific tools of crisis management (resolution). The latter allow that in the event, the bank is deemed failing or likely to fail and resolution is necessary in the public interest, resolution authorities can take over bank management. Within the EBU, such procedures are centralised, within the EU—coordinated, albeit with a possibility for defection.Footnote 3 In normal times, however, the main task of resolution authorities is preparing ex ante resolution plans outlining possible courses of action if a bank should fail. The content of such plans is specified under the BRRD to include: a demonstration of how critical functions and core business lines could be legally and economically separated from other functions so as to ensure their continuity (“continuity of critical functions”), provisions for the financing of resolution without public support (including Emergency Liquidity Assistance facilities provided by central banks), a description of critical interdependencies of the bank as well as an external communication plan [24 Art. 17]. Further they include the determination of a number of key regulatory requirements, such as the minimum requirement of bailinable debt the bank is to hold (Minimum Requirement of Own Funds and Eligible Liabilities, MREL) and an assessment of the resolvability of the bank (i.e. whether it can be safely dealt with in crisis) [22 Art. 45 as amended, 25 Art. 12 as amended]. Resolution authorities have then the powers to require changes in the current bank operation if it threatens its resolvability and sanction for non-compliance with the requirements they impose on the banks, e.g. by imposing a prohibition on distributions such as dividends [22 Art. 16a, 25 Art. 10a]. These requirements apply both to integrated banks as well as bank groups composed of multiple legal entities. For cross-border bank groups active across a number of Member States, the BRRD and SRM provide for an elaborate framework of cooperation between the NRAs and EU level spanning, as discussed below, highly integrated structures for EBU and more loose arrangements for the EU as a whole. Cross-border bank group’s resolution plans are not only to prepare the credit institution for a crisis, but also to ex ante align NRAs’ expectations of how bank failure could play out and improve their mutual understanding of sensitivities so as to enable greater trust and productive cooperation should an actual failure of a cross-border bank group occur. The organisation of the preparation of such group plans is, however, organised differently in EBU and EU as a whole.

Outcomes

It might be assumed that centralised structures might be more conducive to integrated outcomes, for example, with regard to resolution strategies. However, it is not only within the EBU that SPOE is the preferred strategy for cross-border banks of the resolution authorities, but rather across the internal market as a whole [38 p. 26]. Further, fragmentation has persisted as has ring-fencing of cross-border banks within the EBU [1, 14, 41]. Textbook bank resolution, meanwhile, appears to have been implemented mostly outside of the EBU, rather than inside [44]. While the SRB has deferred to national orders and private solutions, first full-blown resolution cases have been carried out in Croatia, before it entered into close cooperation. Meanwhile outside the EBU, there are many examples of successful cooperation in crisis management on a cross-border basis in the Nordics [8].

Why does centralisation within EBU appear not to yield the expected results? Scholars have answered this question–directly and indirectly–from a variety of vantage points. The first set of explanations looks to the incompleteness of EBU, highlighting especially the absence of a common deposit insurance and backstop limitations. Such incompleteness manifests equally as persistent obstacles to intra-group capital flows or shortcomings in the design of resolution tools, such as the bail-in tool, which impede SRM’s ability to meet objectives [46]. The second set of explanations has drawn on political economy. Despite centralisation, national interest reigns over best laid plans of EU agencies. This is in particular where the interest of large banks is involved [11]. Thirdly, the legal scholarship has focussed on limits on the powers of the core of the SRM due to constitutional limits drawn by the Meroni doctrine [39]. This article builds on this final approach exploring in addition the complex features of the different integrated administrative structures.Footnote 4

Multilevel cooperation in the EU cross-border bank resolution: between centralisation and networks

Two distinct forms of EU integrated multilevel procedural cooperation can be distinguished with regard to the implementation of resolution law tasks and oversight over cross-border bank groups with respect to crisis prevention and management [34 p. 166]. They cover analogous procedures which organise the cooperation of NRAs responsible for different parts of a cross-border bank either within the EBU or for the EU as a whole. For the EBU countries, the SRM provides for centralised cooperation of national authorities with the “specific” EU agency (Single Resolution Board, SRB) at its core.Footnote 5 For the EU as a whole (encompassing, therefore, the EBU but as well NRAs in other Member States), relatively loose networked arrangements known as resolution colleges are established. Both forms include both horizontal (national) and vertical (national-EU) dimensions of the administrative cooperation, which have, however, some important nuances. As shall be further explained below, complexity arises in the context of differentiated positions of NRAs along the horizontal dimension with regard to their powers and responsibilities within the administrative cooperation procedures. This section outlines the design of SRM and resolution colleges. It covers as well the design of the building blocks of administrative multilevel structures, namely the NRAs (the national level) as well as the European Banking Authority (EBA) the EU agency playing a role in ensuring consistency across the overall regime.

National resolution authorities (NRAs)

The BRRD requires that each Member State set up an NRA. BRRD allows for these to be delegated to central banks, other public authorities, and—in some cases—also supervisors, though there must be adequate structural arrangements in place to ensure “operational independence” and prevent conflicts of interest [24 Art. 3(3)]. Few Member States had authorities with a specific crisis management mandate before the BRRD and there is no dominant model which has been adopted, with Member States—both euro and not–equally split between central banks and independent agencies acting as the NRAs.Footnote 6 Within the EBU (i.e. including the non-euro Croatia and Bulgaria), there are 10 NRAs which are specialised (i.e. housed within the banking supervisor or a separate institution, in Austria, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Latvia, Luxembourg, Malta, Slovakia, Spain), while in 11 Member States it is the national central bank that also acts as the principal NRA (Belgium, Bulgaria, Croatia, Cyprus, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Lithuania, Netherlands, Portugal, Slovenia). The remaining six non-euro Member States equally opt either for the central bank (Czechia, Hungary, Romania) or a separate authority (Denmark, Sweden, Poland). This heterogeneity is important as it may partly explain different sensitivities of NRAs. Across various multilevel cooperation arrangements, the NRAs remain involved in decision-making and maintain the implementation powers.

Resolution colleges

For cross-border bank groups active across the EU, the primary form of administrative cooperation is the “European resolution colleges” [22 as amended]. For banks operating globally, these cover the part active in the EU, where recently an obligation to establish an EU parent undertaking was introduced [45 for a critical comment]. Colleges are established for each cross-border bank group with a view to producing joint decisions on ex ante resolution plans and resolution schemes should the bank be failing [22 Art. 89 as amended, 32 and 54 on group resolution]. Each college boasts broad membership spanning the group-level NRA, NRAs in countries where the bank has subsidiaries and branches, NRA of the parent financial holding company, relevant supervisors, central bank(s), competent ministries, deposit guarantee authorities and EBA representatives. Such broad membership reflects their aim to allow for an efficient, timely, clearly defined resolution, where due consideration is given to the economies of all states where the bank is active, and action is underpinned by “recognition that coordination and cooperation are most likely to achieve a result which lowers the overall costs of resolution.”Footnote 7 The broad membership reflects the will to overcome siloed thinking and information gaps prevalent during the financial crisis [4].Footnote 8

Formally resolution colleges are “not decision-making bod[ies],” but rather dedicated fora for the NRAs to work towards implementing a set of specific procedures relating to ex ante crisis prevention and management.Footnote 9 Individual decisions are taken, enforced and challengeable in national jurisdictions of the NRAs participating. The colleges’ role is specifically limited by reference to proportionality as a cooperation arrangement; they are meant to be “less intrusive” than full centralisation [32 p. 165]. These formal provisions of the BRRD, however, are somewhat at odds with the prescription that through cooperation in the college the NRAs are to arrive at a set of joint decisions on resolution plans and–if part of the bank is deemed failing or likely to fail—joint resolution schemes. Further, their preparation is highly proceduralised and regulated. In addition to the BRRD rules, the European Commission’s Delegated Regulation No 2016/1075 specifies the internal procedures (e.g. communication and information exchange requirements), while further “written arrangements” are to be developed by the group-level NRA [19 Art. 50].

As a result, the framework within which the NRAs in a college develop the joint decisions on a bank group resolution plan is highly prescriptive. Further, in practice, the joint decisions (or their absence) have a significant impact on the cross-border risk distribution in a bank group since they may cover administrative decisions that the bank remove specific impediments to resolvability (e.g. through changes to the legal or operational structure of a bank), determination of MREL, and the resolution strategy identified [39]. Through cooperation within the colleges the NRAs and the bank may as well decide on frameworks of intra-group stabilisation support in case of failure.Footnote 10 According to the EBA’s 2019 Report, generally resolution colleges have been successful with regard to delivering on the joint resolution plans, notwithstanding early cases where EBA mediation–discussed below–was required.Footnote 11

With regard to resolution proper, the BRRD equally provides for a framework around which joint decisions of the college would be taken. However, given the possible fiscal implications of bank failure and the absence of a centralised fund,Footnote 12 it remains flexible. For example, NRAs may withdraw from cooperation, that is not participate in the process of formulating a joint decision, in cases where national financial stability is a concern. The obligation to cooperate is in such an event substituted by transparency requirements [24 Arts. 91 and 92 supplemented by Resolution College RTS].

Three aspects make the resolution colleges a multilevel arrangement rather than purely horizontal cooperation. First, the procedures foreseen by the BRRD and detailed in EBA’s delegated rules, grant a special role to the group-level NRA, that is the authority of the Member State where the parent entity of the cross-border bank is established. Second, there is a specific “cross-border”/European mandate which the colleges create for the NRAs. Third, EBA is the EU agency charged with detailing the rules of cooperation of the colleges, as well as solving specific problems which may occur within them.

The first aspect, that is the special role of group-level NRA, is evident, for example, in the process of “mapping” the college, that is the set of detailed procedural rules which outline how the college is to be constituted. BRRD confers specific responsibilities on it here, such as the identification of the relevant regulatory architecture for the banking sector in the countries where the given bank group is active as well as the relative importance of the entity (subsidiary or a branch, in accordance with the locally relevant criteria for importance) [24 Art. 88(5)(e)].Footnote 13 The group-level NRA therefore enjoys some discretion in determining the scope of the bank in the mapping process (via the “written arrangements”) and the assessment of materiality of distinct parts of the group. Other special functions of the group-level NRA relate to its representative functions vis-à-vis the bank, EU bodies and third country authorities [19 Art. 51].

Second, resolution colleges have a role in relation to safeguarding the critical functions of cross-border functions of the bank, which can be described as the participating NRAs’ “European” mandate.Footnote 14 In the strictly national context bank critical functions include deposit-taking, lending activities and payment services “since they are provided to a limited number of third parties and can be replaced in an acceptable manner and within a reasonable timeframe” [48]. The BRRD’s extension of the notion of critical functions cross-border is in stark contrast to another key concept of EU resolution law, namely “public interest in financial stability”, which remains primarily national [20 paras. 111–115].Footnote 15 As a consequence, the definition of critical cross-border functions of the bank is one of the main tasks unique to cooperation in cross-border colleges, since individual NRAs would hardly be able to determine these unilaterally. Experts have suggested that such functions include the smooth operation of payment systems and continued access to essential banking services” [35 p. 373].

The final multilevel aspect of college functioning arises in the context of the role played by the EU (supranational) agency—the EBA. Such a role has three facets. First, the EBA is the rule-maker, that is through ever more granular procedural requirements established in line with the BRRD, it constrains the operation of the colleges. Secondly, as member of all the colleges, the EU agency ensures consistency across their operation. Finally, through its mediation mandate, EBA is tasked with solving disputes between the authorities, which preclude joint decision-making.

European Banking Authority (EBA)

The EBA is an EU networked agency consisting of the 27 national banking supervisors, endowed with the secretariat to act independently and in the interest of the Union [26 Recitals 42 and 52]. Its resolution mandate is exercised by the dedicated ResCo (Resolution Committee) established within the agency. ResCo is composed of a Chairperson and the heads of the 27 EU NRAs, with observers from resolution authorities of the EEA EFTA countries represented in the EBA Board of Supervisors (BoS), representatives of the European Commission, the SRB, the European Systemic Risk Board, the European Central Bank (SSM), the European Securities and Markets Authority (ESMA) and the European Insurance and Occupational Pension Authority (EIOPA).Footnote 16 The ResCo is a permanent structure which–unlike resolution colleges or the variable Executive Board of SRB discussed below–has a permanent membership and is not concerned with a particular bank.

In the context of cross-border banking, the EBA has a general coordination function “in particular in situations where adverse developments could potentially jeopardise the orderly functioning and integrity of financial markets or the stability of the financial system in the Union” [26 Art. 32].Footnote 17 In the context of resolution colleges specifically EBA is meant to improve the convergence and consistency of their decisions [24 Art. 88(4)]. Such a contribution is made by issuing best practice documents, guidelines to complement the Single Rulebook, leadership and action plans as well as IT platforms [21 p. 48]. In last resort scenarios, EBA may also act as a mediator and an arbiter between NRAs.Footnote 18 Such mediation can be entered into on the request of a national authority part of a college, and is binding on the parties affected (except where the matter impinges on fiscal matters). These powers are intended to address a specific lacunae in the governance framework identified by the de Larosière report in 2009, whereby during the financial crisis the NRAs did not have a formal route to challenge the decisions of authorities in the Member State where a different part of the bank was established, even if these affected directly the position of the legal entity in their jurisdiction. As a result, governance problems in cross-border groups were aggravated [9 p. 23, 13 p. 73]. Early examples of EBA mediation suggest that it has been resorted to by non-euro area hosts of EBU-based banks. In 2018, EBA mediated on a case involving a Romanian subsidiary, whose resolution authority disagreed with the resolution planning approach of the group-level authority (SRB). EBA’s solution was to focus predominantly on the procedure, which is meant to ensure that all the concerns of various authorities are properly addressed in the group-level decision-making processes [47 s. 2.46 for discussion].

Single Resolution Mechanism (SRM) and the Single Resolution Board (SRB)

In comparison to the resolution colleges, the EBU structure established for the purpose of administrative cooperation in the area of resolution law—the SRM—is more integrated. The SRM is composed of NRAs of participating Member States and the SRB, a “specific” EU agency endowed with centralised decision-making powers and a legal personality [28 Art. 42(1), 6 and 51 p. 169–204 on SRB].Footnote 19 The SRM becomes the “national” authority for the purpose of the resolution-related tasks.Footnote 20 The interaction between the NRAs and SRB is regulated by the SRM Regulation and rules of procedure which apply generally—no bespoke “written arrangements” as in the case of resolution colleges—are necessary [47 p. 43, 49 for the Framework for Cooperation between the SRB and NRAs]. The NRAs thus have a greater and more predictable access to information within this form of cooperation, which is not conditional on the good-will of the group-level NRA. Furthermore, while the EBA still has a role as the rule-maker with regard to the SRM, any conflicts between the authorities are internalised and to be solved by the SRB’s Appeal Panel.

The SRB is the owner of the Single Resolution Fund (SRF), that is the fund to which banks themselves contribute, which can finance resolution in cases of a credit institution’s failure. Such funds are also established on the national basis under the BRRD. They then amount to 1% of covered deposits paid by local banks with contributions collected and administered at the national level. In the EBU, however, the national funds become mutualised under the 2014 Intergovernmental Agreement accompanying the creation of the SRM. In addition to creating a joint fund—which is meant to solve problems of loss-allocation for cross-border bank groups—the SRF is the source of a key difference with the NRA-based college arrangements described above, namely that the individual bank contributions to the SRF are determined at a centralised level by the SRB.Footnote 21 Thus, it is the EU agency which becomes the main interlocutor of the entities within the bank in this regard. Further, if the banks disagree with an SRB decision, they no longer have recourse in the national legal system: any disagreement with regard to the contribution amount set, but also specific components of the resolution plans, is within the exclusive jurisdiction of the CJEU [37].

The multilevel cooperation within the specific administrative crisis prevention procedures is more integrated in the SRM than in the resolution colleges. The SRB takes the decisions on group resolution plans for bank groups established in one of the participating Member States. However, additional complexity is to be identified here. First, the NRAs may assist in the process, meaning the procedure is rather composite than centralised [28 Art. 7–8, 15 for an analysis of the composite administrative procedures]. In fact, the local jurisdiction continues to play a key role, for example, with regard to setting the MREL requirement within the group (internal MREL), where certain forms of cross-border guarantees are excluded within the EBU, as well as in the EU [24 Arts. 45b and 45f, 28 Arts. 12c and 12g]. On the other hand, the SRB in preparing the group resolution plans is to look specifically at the EU scope of the bank, rather than purely its EBU-located entities.Footnote 22

With regard to crisis management, the SRM creates a mandatory framework for implementation of the resolution schemes once a bank is deemed failing or likely to fail. The SRB becomes the NRA responsible for determining whether the public interest and critical functions tests have been met to put a bank in resolution (rather than insolvency). In contrast to the resolution colleges, the EBU resolution procedures do not allow for defection by national authorities, even if the decision-making procedures involving the Council and the European Commission to settle on the amount of SRF used, are particularly cumbersome [28 Art. 18]. The SRM is not, however, fully centralised. Three specific features add to the complexity along the vertical dimension of cooperation primarily, namely the variability of the SRB’s Executive Board composition, the reliance on the NRAs for decision implementation and the differentiated position of the non-euro area NRAs within the EBU more broadly

With regard to the first point, the core of the SRM has a variable composition, depending on the bank with regard to which it takes a particular decision. The SRB’s Executive Board is composed of five full-time members [28 Art. 43(1)] and the NRAs of the Member States where the bank in question is established, as well as those where it has subsidiaries.Footnote 23 This variability is a result of the dominant role of the NRAs in the implementation of resolution procedures. Due to the limitations set by the Meroni doctrine of the Court of Justice in terms of the powers that may conferred on an EU agency, the SRB relies exclusively on the NRAs for the implementation of specific decisions taken vis-à-vis the bank group, including any sanctions. While greater coordination in the case of cross-border bank groups may be achieved through centralised decision-making, the trust issue which arises horizontally in the context of resolution colleges, is here reproduced vertically; in addition, the SRB has few tools of coercion vis-à-vis the NRAs.Footnote 24

The final caveat of the SRM as a multilevel administrative structure relates to the inadvertently differentiated position of the non-euro States who decide to participate in the EBU, now a practical consideration given that Bulgaria and Croatia entered into close cooperation in October 2020, while others such as Denmark or Sweden consider joining the EBU without the prospect of joining the common currency. At first glance such a differentiation between euro and non-euro participating Member States might be surprising, given that SRM is an internal market measure established on the basis of Art. 114 TFEU and the SRB is an EU agency. In fact–unlike in the SSM–no dedicated arrangement is necessary to provide for the inclusion of non-euro States in the decision-making procedures of the SRM when they enter into close cooperation.Footnote 25 However, the position of the non-euro States within the SRM differs in at least two respects, namely the operation of the safety net and the powers of the SRB vis-à-vis the NRAs.

The first aspect involves two components relating to the public support which banks from outside the euro area, but within the EBU, can rely on in a crisis. With the entry into the SRM, the non-euro Member State’s banking system becomes part of the Single Resolution Fund framework established at the EBU level. However, the access to the fiscal backstop of the European Stability Mechanism (ESM) remains restricted. In December 2020, the Eurogroup approved a revised ESM Treaty, which creates the common backstop to the SRF, should its needs exceed the collected contributions. The ESM, however, is an explicitly euro area-only endeavour (created as a stabilisation function outside of the EU Treaty). The revised ESM Treaty includes provisions for the participation of non-euro area Member States, who have to provide parallel credit lines to the SRF alongside the ESM. Such countries would then gain partial access to the ESM information [10 Recital 9A and Art. 5(4), 40, 42]. Further differentiation arises in the context of the EBU procedures involving the European Central Bank (ECB). Whereas in the context of crisis management measures (recovery and resolution), the banks from the euro area participating Member States may rely on the liquidity and firepower of the ECB (notwithstanding the “Chinese walls”, equally the supervisor and the monetary policy authority), the non-euro States have only their local central banks to lean on. As a consequence, in the light of a more restricted safety net, the reliance of non-euro SRM members on the joint crisis prevention procedures may well be greater than for the euro area NRAs.

The second aspect relates to the specific powers which the SRB has vis-à-vis the non-euro NRAs, and not the euro area ones. Should close cooperation in the EBU be terminated, the SRM regulation provides for a disentangling of the non-euro participating Member State involvement in the SRF (no such provision is made for the euro area NRAs). In such cases, the SRB “shall decide within three months after the date of adoption of the decision to terminate close cooperation, in agreement with that Member State, on the modalities for the recoupment of contributions that the Member State concerned has transferred to the Fund and any conditions applicable” [28 Art. 4(3)]. The specific powers of the SRB in this regard are unique, and serve to highlight the point that for the non-euro States participation in the EBU is reversible and conditional.

Consequently, the difference between the non-euro and euro area Member States within the SRM relates primarily to the stability of cooperation and the interaction with other pillars of EBU as well as links with broader euro area economic governance (see Table 1 for summary). Such factors may well have a bearing on incentives to cooperate and the level of trust established between the NRA and the SRB in particular, adding to the complexity of the overall multilevel administrative design.

Table 1 Multilevel administrative cooperation in the EBU and EU cross-border bank group resolution

Explaining the outcomes of multilevel administrative cooperation

There is little empirical evidence that the more centralised multilevel administrative structure of the SRM is more successful in attaining the goals of cross-border resolution, that is achieving efficient, fair and timely solutions for the group, while protecting financial stability in all the Member States where the group operates [24 Recital 97] and ensuring continuity of critical functions, including those of cross-border nature [24 Art. 2(1)(35) and Art. 31(1)(2), 36], than looser arrangements such as resolution colleges. This observation extends as well to the crisis preparation measures, where banks operating EU-wide are no less likely to have integrated (SPOE) resolution strategies, than those active within the EBU. In the light of the preceding analysis, are there specific aspects of the individual multilevel cooperation arrangements which explain their relative successes or shortcomings in terms of creating a framework within which effective cross-border resolution is possible without market fragmentation? In other words, can we identify specific features of multilevel administrative cooperation which are more conducive to constructive engagement and trust-building among the authorities involved, where these are necessary condition for a successful cross-border resolution? This section discusses some explanations.

The apparent success of resolution law (in terms of number of resolution cases) outside of the scope of the EBU, may be partially explained by two circumstantial factors. First, it may be too soon to assess the progress made by the SRB, operational only since 2015. Though indeed some experts have pointed to the less positive experiences of NRAs working within the SRB [31 p. 37], these may well be evidence of a steep learning curve. Where a lack of trust between NRAs and SRB is caused by disagreements over definitions, further experience in intra-SRM cooperation and the SRB’s internal capacity-building could help overcome them. Second, the choice of resolution strategies (e.g. the fully integrated SPOE) may be explained by cross-border bank group’s business choices rather than the applicable administrative cooperation arrangement. Specifically, the EU cross-border banks in fact operate largely between the euro area and the Nordics (Sweden, Denmark) or the Central, Eastern and South-Eastern Europe (Czechia, Poland, Romania, Bulgaria) [31]. In other words, an apparent success of resolution colleges in achieving cooperative outcomes (i.e. integrated resolution strategies) is the consequence of the market structure, rather than its cause. There are just more EU cross-border bank groups, than the EBU ones. The institution of centralised oversight–either for supervision or resolution–has not (yet) changed that.

From the perspective of EU administrative law, however, it may be that the SRM’s design (even with the heterogeneity inbuilt), exasperates rather than assuages the home-host conflicts between Member States, in particular in the absence of a third-party arbiter, such as the EBA in the context of resolution colleges. Theoretically, joining the SRM should ensure that the interests of different NRAs are better represented in the overall approach of the SRB. However, scholars and experts have pointed out that this arrangement, especially where the subsidiaries in the smaller economies are nominally not significant in the overall balance sheet of the cross-border bank, might result in small host NRAs’ concerns becoming an afterthought in the SRB’s approach, with the only recourse available being the SRB’s Appeal Panel [39, 47]. However, this route does not appear effective in resolving intra-SRM conflicts. For example, in 2018, the SRB Appeal Panel ruled in a case where the SRB was accused of failing to determine the MREL requirement at the level of an individual entity within a cross-border group (it had done so only at the consolidated group level). The Appeal Panel stated it had no competence to hear actions for SRB’s failure to act, suggesting full administrative integration comes at a cost of protective elements for the hosts.Footnote 26 The role of the Appeal Panel is, therefore, quite different from that of EBA which–given the convergence and mediation mandate–is oriented towards outcomes which are mutually acceptable to the parties involved. At the same time, even though the design of the SRM, therefore, is less sensitive to possible internal jurisdictional and interest conflicts than the colleges, it nonetheless relies significantly on NRAs. Further, the substantive tests applied in resolution law and in the adjacent areas of law (e.g. insolvency) continue to be national. In such a context centralisation which risks reduced sensitivity to local financial stability concerns, may subsequently reduce trust between authorities necessary for a successful implementation of resolution within the SRM. In the light of insufficient conflict management arrangements, the result may be only exasperated internal conflict and bureaucratic politics, which appears to be a serious impediment at the heart of the SRM.

Conclusions

This article has analysed comparatively the multilevel administrative cooperation established for bank crisis prevention and management in the EU and the EBU. It has grappled with the complexity of the resolution colleges and the SRM in order to explain why it appears that looser arrangements may well be more conducive to cooperative outcomes than centralised ones, or at least no less effective in making for cooperative cross-border resolution outcomes. Specifically, the limitations of the SRM, in terms of constrained implementation powers of the SRB as well as the differentiated position of the non-euro Member States, were discussed as evidence of inherent tensions within the integrated mechanism. On the other hand, resolution colleges were shown to be much more formalised (and centralised) than they appear at first glance. Such findings, developed from an EU administrative law perspective, raise questions of a constitutional nature, in particular relating to accountability of such administrative cooperation, equality of Member States and the implications of Meroni doctrine’s distortive effects.

With regard to the accountability question, concerns emerge with regard to the absence of democratic control over the colleges and the group-level NRAs. Since the colleges are not formally decision-making bodies, and the NRAs are embedded in the domestic constitutional settings, few provisions have been made in the BRRD to create a framework within which they could be called to answer for the effects of their actions. An exception is the accountability of colleges vis-à-vis EBA, which appears altogether insufficient given the limited (non-binding) nature of any control exercised by the agency [24 Art. 88(4) and 18(5) on EBA mediation specifically for EBA’s role in relation to colleges]. Greater public accountability over their operation, including by establishing greater transparency, is therefore warranted.

With regard to the question of equality, the problem here might not arise necessarily in the context of differentiation between euro and non-euro Member States in the EBU, discussed above. It may well be, as argued by Tridimas, that “equality of opportunity” suffices to satisfy the demands of non-discrimination [53 pp. 25–48], even if–given the Art. 114 TFEU legal basis for the SRM, i.e. internal market-wide harmonisation–such claims should be treated with caution in this case. If the EBU is indeed to be conceived of as a predominantly euro area institution, discussions of differentiation may well highlight that a separate legal basis for EMU’s financial sector regulation harmonisation is necessary. The problem of equality which arises in the context of the themes explored in this article is rather the assumption that the administrative structure established–either for the EU as a whole or within EBU–on bespoke terms for the individual banks, is to necessarily mirror the corporate structure, with the administrative powers distributed differently depending on whether the NRA is responsible for the parent, subsidiary or branch, in addition to any differentiation arising from membership of the currency union. While such a model centred around the consolidated (group-level) supervisor might have been suitable for the predominantly intergovernmental arrangements which preceded the crisis, in the context of highly integrated administrative structures, it raises concerning the relative position of distinct NRAs, in particular in the absence of local safeguards.

Finally, where the Meroni doctrine continues to be a thorn in the SRM’s side, this article has highlighted the extent to which the limits on SRB’s powers together with the prevalence of jurisdictional divisions, continue to be not only a curb on the effectiveness of the centralised regime, but also a source of potential distortions. At the same time, any greater centralisation, including greater powers with regard to overriding jurisdictional divisions within the EBU which might help improve the effectiveness of centralised administrative arrangements, should be complemented with targeted efforts oriented at building up trust between different administrative levels and towards the agency itself.