Skip to main content
Log in

Factor risk premiums and invested capital: calculations with stochastic discount factors

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Asset Management Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Factor portfolios with value, size, momentum, profitability, and low volatility stocks have historically exhibited high returns after adjusting for market risk. As the weights of these portfolios increase in the stochastic discount factor, the excess returns of these factor strategies should decrease. We compare weights of these factor portfolios in the efficient set relative to which there are no factor risk premiums with market capitalization weights.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Ang (2014) contains a comprehensive summary of common factor risk premiums with their economic rationales.

  2. Following the literature, we use the words “stochastic discount factor” and “pricing kernel” interchangeably. Because the tangency portfolio is efficient, we also use the words “tangency portfolio” and “efficient portfolio” interchangeably. Strictly speaking, the efficient portfolio is constructed with the tangency portfolio and the risk-free asset—but the pricing effects are due to the tangency portfolio alone.

  3. Unless otherwise stated, the data underlying the analysis in this paper is the Fama–French factors, constructed by Kenneth French using the time periods of July 1963 to July 2017 and is available at http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data_library.html.

  4. See a summary in Ang et al. (2011).

  5. An economic interpretation of the pricing kernel, m, is that it represents an index of “bad times” (see Ang 2014), which accounts for the negative sign in the price of risk of the pricing kernel, λ. Equation (3) says that if an asset’s covariance with respect to the pricing kernel is high, then its expected return is low; assets with payoffs that tend to be high during bad times are valuable and a representative investor does not require high expected returns to hold those assets because of their hedging properties. The mean of the pricing kernel determines the risk-free rate, with \( E\left( m \right) = 1/R_{f} \).

  6. The notion of no arbitrage in the Hansen and Jagannathan (1991) pricing kernel is embedded in Eq. (3), which can be rewritten as the Euler condition \( E\left( {mR} \right) = 1 \). This is a weaker condition than general equilibrium. A general equilibrium specified by agent preferences and endowments, assets, and market structure must satisfy the condition of no arbitrage, but the converse may not be true. If there is an equilibrium which satisfies no arbitrage, the returns of the efficient (or tangency) portfolio characterize that equilibrium. The advantage of using the Hansen–Jagannathan pricing kernel compared to fully specifying a general equilibrium is that it requires fewer modeling primitives—and it is a well-defined efficient set under which the factor risk premiums are equal to zero. We examine the pricing implications of moving from the market portfolio, which is a general equilibrium of the CAPM and is inefficient, to the efficient set.

  7. This exercise is similar in spirit to pricing an asset with zero net supply in a standard consumption economy, like risk-free bonds.

  8. Theoretically, an investor should use leverage to seek expected returns higher than the tangency portfolio by taking positions in the tangency portfolio and shorting risk-free assets, and by doing so lying on the CAL. This is one of the central concepts involved in “risk parity” styles of investing.

  9. The difference between the market portfolio and the efficient portfolio is a version of the Hansen and Jagannathan (1997) distance metric, which can be interpreted as a norm of the completion portfolio.

  10. A corollary of these findings is that estimates of long-term factor risk premiums using Black and Litterman (1991) methods based only on current market cap weights will produce much lower estimates of factor risk premiums compared to historical data.

  11. The size premium is smaller when measured using decile portfolios and is statistically insignificant in a formal Gibbons et al. (1989) test. Small stocks have higher returns, however, as indicated by the first column in Table 2, but much smaller risk-adjusted returns after controlling for market beta.

References

  • Ang, A. 2014. Asset management: A systematic approach to factor based investing. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ang, A., A. Madhavan, and A. Sobczyk. 2017. Crowding, capacity, and valuation of minimum volatility strategies. Journal of Index Investing 7: 41–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ang, A., R.J. Hodrick, Y. Xing, and X. Zhang. 2006. The cross-section of volatility and expected returns. The Journal of Finance 61: 259–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ang, A., W.N. Goetzmann, and S. Schaefer. 2011. The efficient market theory and evidence: Implications for active investment management. Foundations and Trends in Finance 5: 157–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berk, J., R. Green, and V. Naik. 1999. Optimal investment, growth options, and security returns. Journal of Finance 54: 1553–1607.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black, F., and R. Litterman. 1991. Asset Allocation: Combining investor views with market equilibrium. Journal of Fixed Income 1: 7–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, J.H. 2001. Asset pricing. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1993. Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 33: 3–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons, M.R., S.A. Ross, and J. Shanken. 1989. A test of the efficiency of a given portfolio. Econometrica 56: 1121–1152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, L.P., and R. Jagannathan. 1991. Implications of security market data for models of dynamic economics. Journal of Political Economy 99: 225–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, L.P., and R. Jagannathan. 1997. Assessing specification errors in stochastic discount models. Journal of Finance 52: 557–590.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lakonishok, J., A. Shleifer, and R.W. Vishny. 1994. Contrarian investment, extrapolation, and risk. Journal of Finance 49: 1541–1578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loughran, T. 1997. Book-to-market across firm size, exchange, and seasonality: Is there an effect? Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 32: 249–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R.C. 1971. Optimal consumption and portfolio rules in a continuous-time model. Journal of Economic Theory 3: 373–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Novy-Marx, R., and M. Velikov. 2016. A taxonomy of anomalies and their trading costs. Review of Financial Studies 29: 104–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ratcliffe, R., P. Miranda, and A. Ang. 2017. Capacity of smart beta strategies from a transaction cost perspective. Journal of Index Investing 8: 39–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross, S.A. 1976. The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing. Journal of Economic Theory 13: 341–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sharpe, W.F. 1964. Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. Journal of Finance 19: 425–442.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The views expressed here are those of the authors alone and not of BlackRock, Inc. We thank Johnny Kang and Ron Ratcliffe for helpful suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andrew Ang.

Appendix: Completion portfolios

Appendix: Completion portfolios

We show the equivalence of the CAPM as one particular pricing kernel in the more general framework of Hansen and Jagannathan (1991).

We start with the Euler condition:

$$ E\left( {mR} \right) = 1, $$
(7)

where m is the candidate pricing kernel and R is a gross return of a test asset. Equation (7) says that when evaluating the expectations of the return payoffs of the portfolios using the pricing kernel, we obtain the price of the portfolios today—which is $1 as we work in gross returns.

Hansen and Jagannathan (1991) show how to construct the pricing kernel that satisfies Eq. (7). The pricing kernel’s volatility must be greater than a certain minimum threshold, and the pricing kernel with the minimum required volatility, m*, that solves Eq. (7) is given by

$$ m^{*} = w^{*} \cdot R, $$
(8)

where the optimal weights, w*, on the test portfolios are given by

$$ w^{*} = \frac{1}{{R_{f} }} + \left( {R - \bar{R}} \right)^{{\prime }} \varSigma_{R}^{ - 1} \left( {1 - \frac{1}{{R_{f} }}} \right). $$
(9)

In terms of computation, R is a T × N matrix of T observations of N asset gross returns; \( \bar{R} \) is the average gross return of the portfolios; R f is a given gross risk-free rate; and \( \varSigma_{R}^{ - 1} \) is the empirical covariance matrix of R. In practice, the pricing kernel tends to place large weights on portfolios with high excess returns and low weights on low excess return portfolios, adjusted for risk in the covariance matrix, Σ R . Hansen and Jagannathan (1991) derive Eq. (9) as an ordinary least squares (OLS) projection.

We compute the portfolio alphas using

$$ \alpha = \left( {\bar{R} - R_{f} } \right) - E^{m} \left( {R - R_{f} } \right), $$
(10)

where \( E^{m} \left( {R - R_{f} } \right) \) is the excess return implied by the choice of the pricing kernel m. We evaluate

$$ E^{m} \left( {R - R_{f} } \right) = \frac{{{\text{cov}}\left( {R,m} \right)}}{E\left( m \right)}, $$
(11)

which is the same as Eq. (3).

One way to derive the constants a and b for the CAPM in Eq. (4) is as follows. The constant a pins down the risk-free rate and solves \( E\left( {m_{\text{mkt}} } \right) = 1/R_{f} \). The constant b prices the market portfolio itself, \( E\left( {m_{\text{mkt}} R_{\text{mkt}} } \right) = 1 \).

When the optimal weights w* are normalized using \( w^{*} /{\mathbf{sum}}(w^{*} ) \), they represent the weights in the efficient portfolio (the tangency portfolio of the intersection of the Capital Allocation Line and the mean–variance frontier). In this case, the alphas in Eq. (5) are equal to zero.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ang, A., Hogan, K. & Shores, S. Factor risk premiums and invested capital: calculations with stochastic discount factors. J Asset Manag 19, 145–155 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41260-017-0069-0

Download citation

  • Revised:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41260-017-0069-0

Keywords

Navigation