Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Exchange Rate Policy Attitudes: Direct Evidence from Survey Data

  • Published:
IMF Staff Papers Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Analyses of the political economy of exchange rate policy posit that firms and individuals in different sectors of the economy have distinct policy attitudes toward the level and stability of the exchange rate. Most such approaches hypothesize that internationally exposed firms prefer more stable currencies and that producers of tradables prefer a relatively depreciated real exchange rate. As sensible as such expectations may be, there are few direct empirical tests of them. This paper offers micro-level, cross-national evidence on sectoral attitudes about the exchange rate. Using firm-level data from the World Bank's World Business Environment Survey, we find systematic patterns linking sector of economic activity to exchange rate policy positions. Owners and managers of firms producing tradable goods prefer greater stability of the exchange rate: in countries with a floating currency, manufacturers are more likely to report that the exchange rate causes problems for their business. With respect to the level of the exchange rate, we find that tradables producers—particularly manufacturers and export producers—are more likely to be unhappy following an appreciation of the real exchange rate than are firms in nontradable sectors (services and construction). These findings confirm theoretical expectations about the relationship between economic position and currency policy preferences.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3
Figure 4
Figure 5
Figure 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Obviously, policymakers have a wide choice of regime, ranging from a completely free float to a variety of managed floats, degrees of fixity ranging from a target zone to a peg, and a currency board or dollarization. This discussion focuses on the extremes—hard pegs and pure floats—however, because the analysis of intermediate cases flows from the extremes, and the trade-offs described apply to the intermediate choices, albeit never as starkly as to the extremes.

  2. Under most regimes a government must decide whether it prefers a relatively appreciated or relatively depreciated currency. Free floats are rare, and by the same token, countries that opt for a pegged regime always have the choice of abandoning the peg.

  3. See Mundell (1961), McKinnon (1963), and Kenen (1969). A more recent survey is Tavlas (1994).

  4. See for example, the empirical results in Frankel (1995), Rose (2000), Végh (1992), and Ghosh and others (1997).

  5. For a discussion of the WBES project, see Batra, Kaufmann, and Stone (2003).

  6. LYS include an “intermediate” category, which we omit from our analysis because we have no strong theoretical priors about business elites’ attitudes in these regimes.

  7. We drop all firms identifying themselves as “Other.”

  8. Respondents that indicated they were exporters were also asked to specify the percentage of exports to total sales. Unfortunately, most firms did not respond to this inquiry, and so we are constrained to use a dummy variable to indicate whether a firm exports or not.

  9. The data are from the International Financial Statistics (IFS) and the Bank for International Settlements (BIS). The World Development Indicators provide data for Georgia, but coverage ends at 1998. Therefore, REER Appreciation for Georgia measures the percentage change in the real effective exchange rate between 1998 and 1997.

  10. Government ownership is a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if a respondent indicates state ownership. Firm size is an ordered response: 1=small (5–50 employees); 2=medium (51–500 employees); 3=large (>500 employees).

  11. Similar effects (not reported) were obtained substituting the interactions of REER appreciation with exporter and tradables.

References

  • Balistreri, Edward, 1997, “The Performance of the Hecksher-Ohlin-Vanek Model in Predicting Endogenous Policy Forces at the Individual Level,” Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 30, No. 1 (February), pp. 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Batra, Geeta, Daniel Kaufmann, and Andrew W.H. Stone, 2003, “The Firms Speak: What the World Business Environment Survey Tells Us about Constraints on Private Sector Development,” in Pathways Out of Poverty: Private Firms and Economic Mobility in Developing Countries, ed. by Gary S. Fields and Guy Pfefferman (Norwell, Massachusetts, Kluwer Academic Publishers).

    Google Scholar 

  • Beaulieu, Eugene, 2002, “Factor or Industry Cleavages in Trade Policy? An Empirical Analysis of the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem,” Economics and Politics, Vol. 14, No. 2 (July), pp. 99–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, Thorsten, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt, and Ross Levine, 2006, “Bank Supervision and Corruption in Lending,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 53, No. 8 (November), pp. 2131–2163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broz, J. Lawrence, 1997, “The Domestic Politics of International Monetary Order: The Gold Standard,” in Contested Social Orders and International Politics, ed. by D. Skidmore (Nashville, Tennessee, Vanderbilt University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, Guillermo A., and Carmen M. Reinhart, 2002, “Fear of Floating,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107, No. 2 (May), pp. 379–408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campa, Jose, and Linda S. Goldberg, 1997, “The Evolving External Orientation of Manufacturing: A Profile of Four Countries,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review, Vol. 3, No. 2 (July), pp. 53–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campa, Jose, and Linda S. Goldberg, 2005, “Exchange Rate Pass-Through into Import Prices,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 87, No. 4, pp. 679–690.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collins, Susan M., and Francesco Giavazzi, 1992, “Attitudes Towards Inflation and the Viability of Fixed Exchange Rates: Evidence from the EMS,” in A Retrospective on the Bretton Woods System: Lessons for International Monetary Reform, ed. by Barry Eichengreen and Michael Bordo (Chicago, University of Chicago Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Devereux, Michael B., and Charles Engel, 2002, “Exchange Rate Pass-Through, Exchange Rate Volatility, and Exchange Rate Disconnect,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 49, No. 5, pp. 913–940.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen, Barry, 1992, Golden Fetters (Oxford, Oxford University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen, Barry, 1995, “The Endogeneity of Exchange Rate Regimes,” in Understanding Interdependence: The Macroeconomics of the Open Economy, ed. by Peter Kenen (Princeton, New Jersey, Princeton University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen, Barry, and Jeffry A. Frieden, 1993, “The Political Economy of European Monetary Unification: An Analytical Introduction,” Economics & Politics, Vol. 5, No. 2, pp. 85–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, Jeffrey, 1995, “Monetary Regime Choice for a Semi-Open Economy,” in Capital Controls, Exchange Rates and Monetary Policy in the World Economy, ed. by Sebastian Edwards (New York, Cambridge University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, Jeffrey, 1999, “No Single Currency Regime is Right for All Countries or at All Times,” Essays in International Finance No. 215 (Princeton, New Jersey, Princeton University Press).

  • Frieden, Jeffry, 1991, “Invested Interests: The Politics of National Economic Policies in a World of Global Finance,” International Organization, Vol. 45, No. 4 (Autumn), pp. 425–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frieden, Jeffry, 1997, “Monetary Populism in Nineteenth-Century America: An Open Economy Interpretation,” Journal of Economic History, Vol. 57, No. 2 (June), pp. 367–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frieden, Jeffry, 2002, “Real Sources of European Currency Policy: Sectoral Interests and European Monetary Integration,” International Organization, Vol. 56, No. 4 (Autumn), pp. 831–860.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frieden, Jeffry, Piero Ghezzi, and Ernesto Stein, 2001, “Politics and Exchange Rates: A Cross-Country Approach to Latin America,” in The Currency Game: Exchange Rate Politics in Latin America, ed. by Jeffry A. Frieden and Ernesto Stein (Baltimore, Johns Hopkins University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Gabel, Matthew, 1998, “International Economics and Mass Politics: Market Liberalization and Public Support for European Integration,” American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 42, No. 3 (July), pp. 936–953.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gärtner, Manfred, 1997, “Who Wants the Euro—and Why? Economic Explanations of Public Attitudes towards a Single European Currency,” Public Choice, Vol. 93, No. 3, pp. 487–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh, Atish, Anne-Marie Gulde, Jonathan D. Ostry, and Holger C. Wolf, 1997, “Does the Nominal Exchange Rate Regime Matter?” NBER Working Paper No. 5874 (January) (Cambridge, Massachusetts, National Bureau of Economic Research).

  • Hefeker, Carsten, 1995, “Interest Groups, Coalitions and Monetary Integration in the Nineteenth Century,” Journal of European Economic History, Vol. 24, No. 3 (Winter), pp. 489–536.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hefeker, Carsten, 1997, Interest Groups and Monetary Integration: The Political Economy of Exchange Regime Choice (Boulder, Colorado, Westview Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kenen, Peter, 1969, “The Theory of Optimum Currency Areas,” in Monetary Problems in the International Economy, ed. by Robert Mundell and Alexander Swoboda (Chicago, University of Chicago Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, Michael W., and Nancy P. Marion, 1997, “Explaining the Duration of Exchange-Rate Pegs,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 54, No. 2 (December), pp. 387–404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leblang, David, 2002, “The Political Economy of Speculative Attacks in the Developing World,” International Studies Quarterly, Vol. 46, No. 1 (March), pp. 69–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy Yeyati, Eduardo, and F. Sturzenegger, 2005, “Classifying Exchange Rate Regimes: Deeds vs. Words,” European Economic Review, Vol. 49, No. 6 (August), pp. 1603–1635.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayda, Anna Maria, and Dani Rodrik, 2005, “Why Are Some People (and Countries) More Protectionist Than Others?” European Economic Review, Vol. 49, No. 6 (August), pp. 1393–1430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKinnon, Ronald I, 1963, “Optimum Currency Areas,” American Economic Review, Vol. 53, No. 4 (September), pp. 717–725.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mundell, Robert A, 1961, “A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas,” American Economic Review, Vol. 51, No. 4 (September), pp. 657–664.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart, Carmen M., and Kenneth Rogoff, 2004, “The Modern History of Exchange Rate Arrangements: A Reinterpretation,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 119, No. 1, pp. 1–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose, Andrew, 2000, “One Money, One Market: Estimating the Effect of Common Currencies on Trade,” Economic Policy, Vol. 15, No. 30 (April), pp. 9–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheve, Kenneth F, 2004, “Public Inflation Aversion and the Political Economy of Macroeconomic Policymaking,” International Organization, Vol. 58, No. 1 (Winter), pp. 1–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheve, Kenneth F, and Matthew J. Slaughter, 2001, “What Determines Individual Trade-Policy Preferences?” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 54, No. 2, pp. 267–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simmons, Beth, 1994, Who Adjusts? (Princeton, New Jersey, Princeton University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Tavlas, George, 1994, “The Theory of Monetary Integration,” Open Economies Review, Vol. 5, No. 2, pp. 211–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tomz, Michael, Jason Wittenberg, and Gary King, 2003, CLARIFY: Software for Interpreting and Presenting Statistical Results Version 2.1, Harvard University. Available via the Internet: http://gking.harvard.edu.

  • Végh, Carlos, 1992, “Stopping High Inflation: An Analytical Overview,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 39 (September), pp. 626–695.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank, 2000, World Business Environment Survey (Washington, World Bank).

Download references

Authors

Additional information

*J. Lawrence Broz is an associate professor in the Department of Political Science at the University of California, San Diego; Jeffry Frieden is a professor in the Department of Government at Harvard University; and Stephen Weymouth is a Ph.D. student in the Department of Political Science at the University of California, San Diego. The authors thank Justin Wolfers and Barry Eichengreen for helpful comments. They also thank participants at the IMF's Eighth Annual Jacques Polak Research Conference, Washington, November 15–16, 2007.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Broz, J., Frieden, J. & Weymouth, S. Exchange Rate Policy Attitudes: Direct Evidence from Survey Data. IMF Econ Rev 55, 417–444 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1057/imfsp.2008.16

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/imfsp.2008.16

JEL Classifications

Navigation