Introduction

Understanding costly cooperation, i.e. why and under what conditions would someone pay a cost so that someone else receives a benefit, is still a major problem in evolutionary biology. Among the key factors that can lead to cooperation is discrimination between cooperative and uncooperative partners1,2. Such discrimination is based on the behavior of others as experienced in direct interactions (e.g. in direct reciprocity3), or on their behavior towards third parties that is then translated into some kind of reputation as, for example, in indirect reciprocity4,5. In indirect reciprocity, helping someone or refusing to do so and even punishing someone for not helping, builds up a reputation that is likely to influence others within a social group6,7,8,9. Humans have shown cooperative behavior in various kinds of experimental indirect reciprocity games, i.e. they can base their helping behavior on the reputation of others10,11,12,13,14,15,16,17,18. In addition, cooperative behaviors have been shown to be influenced by a number of implicit and explicit features that induce players to care about their reputation within their social group19, such as eye-like spots in the background20 or salience of group identity21. However, the computational algorithms that humans use in such games are not understood and it is unclear how humans integrate the various characteristics that define their environment.

A particularly important feature of many environments is that they are not stable. Climate, resource availability and the presence of predators or diseases are among the most common sources of environmental stochasticity that affect survival and reproduction. Adversity and stochasticity of the environment (defined as the mean and variance in environmental quality, respectively) have been shown to increase cooperation in plants and animals, for example, with rising elevation and physical stress in mountain areas22, with living in semiarid savanna habitats and high temporal variability in rainfall23, with increasing predation risks, especially in environments that provide little protection24,25, or with growing uncertainty about a nearby predator’s intentions26,27. These results are intriguing from an evolutionary point of view, because the costs of unreciprocated cooperation and hence the risks linked to a generous act, may increase with the level of environmental stress28. Theoretical analyses of the problem concluded that increased environmental adversity and uncertainty can indeed lead to higher levels of cooperation in groups of selfish individuals28,29. Cooperation seems to be one way to counterbalance unforeseen fitness decrease due to environmental conditions29.

In humans, both environmental adversity and stochasticity seem to increase within-group solidarity and resource sharing30,31. However, it is still unclear whether and how indirect reciprocity is affected by the different forms of environmental stochasticity in social interactions (e.g. environment quality, payoff structure or frequency of interactions). Here we focus on stochasticity in loss of resources.

Methods

Ethics statement

All participants were recruited from a pool of volunteers of the Department of Economics of the University of Lausanne using ORSEE32. Participants were first year students from all fields of the University of Lausanne and the Swiss Federal Institute of Technology in Lausanne. The experiments were approved by the ethics committee of the University of Lausanne on the use of human subjects in research. Each participant signed an informed consent describing the nature of the experiment before entering the laboratory. Participants were told that their anonymity would be ensured throughout the game, as their decisions could not be linked with their real identity, neither by the other participants, nor by the experimenter. The experiments were carried out in accordance with the approved guidelines.

A total of 144 participants were distributed to 16 separate groups of 9. In order to play anonymously within groups, players were asked to choose a plug from an impenetrable tangle of cables, connect it to a box and choose one of 9 isolated cubicles in juxtaposition from where they could all see the same screen that displayed the details of the game. To reveal a choice, players could secretly push one of two buttons inside the box. The buttons were connected via cables and a switchboard to a green and a red light, respectively11,18. These lights (i.e. decisions) were only revealed to the experimenter, who then entered the decisions in the computer in order to show them on the general display and to compute the players’ decision history (see Supplementary Material). Player IDs were distributed (and later gains paid out) in a procedure that ensured full anonymity, following the procedure dos Santos et al.18 used. The experimenter then read the game instructions (supplementary material) while they were also displayed on the main screen. Each player received an initial endowment of 35 Swiss francs (CHF) that was the starting capital for the game. They were told that they would, after the game had finished, be paid out whatever was left of this or gained to it, in addition to a guaranteed show-up payment of 10 CHF. No information was given about the total number of interactions that would be played.

Eight groups each played a pair-wise indirect reciprocity game in a “Stable” or “Stochastic” treatment. At each interaction, one player was put in the “Unlucky” role and lost 4 CHF (Stable) or either 3 or 5 CHF (Stochastic). Another player, put in the “Passer-by” role, had to decide whether or not to reduce this loss to 1 CHF (i.e. to help the Unlucky) by accepting a cost of 1 CHF to herself33. Then a new pair of players was put in these two roles. Players were told that the same pair would never play in the reversed role, i.e. direct reciprocity was not possible (as a consequence, each player could only be in the Passer-by role for 4 of the group members and in the Unlucky role for the other 4 group members). At each interaction, the Unlucky’s history of giving or not giving in the Passer-by role (i.e. her reputation) was graphically displayed with a pile of circles of 2 different sizes and 2 different colors (supplementary material): giving something (not giving) was indicated with a blue (yellow) circle and giving something to an Unlucky who lost 3 (5) was indicated by a small (large) circle. Giving or not giving to an Unlucky who lost 4 was indicated by a medium sized circle. On the display, the history of giving or not giving could potentially comprise 25% more circles than the total number of rounds that were actually played in order to avoid that players could infer the total number of rounds, i.e. to avoid potential end-game effects. We decided to display the full history of the Unlucky’s helping behavior in the role of the Passer-by to avoid introducing assumptions about how humans process information about previous choices of others.

Each player played 24 times in each role. Hence, each player was paired 6 times with each recipient or donor. In the Stochastic treatment, each player was 12 times the Unlucky with a 3 CHF loss and 12 times the Unlucky with a 5 CHF loss. Also, each player played 12 times as the Passer-by with an Unlucky losing 3 CHF and 12 times with an Unlucky losing 5 CHF, i.e. the experimental design was fully balanced with respect to the kind of losses experienced in both roles. The order of the type of losses was randomized and participants were not made aware of the balanced nature of the design.

The participants’ payoff during the game was not displayed in order to avoid potential envy effects. In total, each of the 9 players of a group had 48 interactions, i.e. the total number of pairwise interactions was 216 (i.e. 48*9*0.5). In order to avoid negative balances, all players (including the observers) received 0.25 CHF after each interaction. Therefore, at the end of the game, each player had received a total of 54 CHF (i.e. 216*0.25) in addition to their payoff during the game and the show-up payment. This amount was added gradually during the game to avoid potential effects of high initial endowments on the players’ decisions.

The statistical analyses were carried out with R 2.10.134. We used the ‘lme4’ package35 for linear (LMM) and logistic mixed-effect model (GLMM) analyses. Whenever LMM were used, the group identity was included as a random effect. To control for the robustness of the results using LMMs, we re-fitted these models as described in Campell and Walters36, using linear regressions with robust standard errors (with group identity as cluster) and the ‘sandwich’ package37. P-values obtained with this method are denoted by prob. The Passers-by’s probability of giving was analyzed using GLMM with group and individual as random effects.

In the Stable treatment, the Unlucky’s reputation at a given interaction was computed as her cooperation frequency minus the group mean cooperation frequency until that interaction in order to correct for group and time effects. Qualitatively similar results were obtained using the absolute cooperation frequency, however higher AICs were found using the latter, suggesting that the models’ quality of fit was lower (Supplementary Table 2).

In the Stochastic treatment, the Unlucky’s reputation was computed analogously (i.e. based on the frequency of blue circles). We did not split this variable into one reputation towards Unluckies suffering a small loss and one reputation towards Unluckies suffering a large loss as these two variables were correlated (corrected for group and round effects: Spearman’s rank correlation coefficient rho = 0.36, p < 0.0001). In order to further examine their combined effect on the Passer-by’s decision, we first computed the Unlucky’s reputation as her cooperation frequency towards Unluckies suffering a large loss and added to the GLMM a variable ‘Discrimination’ representing the difference in cooperation frequency between when Unluckies were suffering a large loss and when they were suffering a small loss (a positive difference would mean that the focal player helped more often Unluckies suffering a small loss than those suffering a large loss). The variable ‘Discrimination’ had only an additive effect (GLMM: discrimination, 2.29 ± 0.39 SE, p < 0.001), the interaction with reputation towards Unluckies suffering a large loss was not significant (GLMM: −0.68 ± 0.71 SE, p = 0.33). We therefore favored the simpler model with the overall cooperation frequency.

Results

We found high proportions of helping in both treatment conditions (Stable: mean = 76.3%, range = 55–95%; Stochastic: mean = 70.1%, range = 45–88%) and no significant treatment effects on mean group cooperativeness (t-test on group means: t14 = 1.0, p = 0.33) or on the players’ final earnings (LMM: t = −0.68, p = 0.50, prob = 0.48). In the Stochastic treatment, the frequency of helping was higher if the Unlucky lost 5 CHF (635/864 donations; 73.5%) than if she lost 3 CHF (576/864 donations; 66.7%; paired t-test on group means, t7 = −3.67, p = 0.008; see Table 1 for an individual-based test). The overall efficiency gains from helping a needy partner (by reducing her loss) did not differ between treatments (t-test on group means, t14 = 0.68, p = 0.51).

Table 1 Indirect reciprocity under Stable and Stochastic conditions. Logistic regression on the Passer-by’s probability of giving in (a) Stable and (b) Stochastic conditions in function of the Unlucky’s reputation (i.e. helping frequency, relative to group and current interaction in order to correct for group and time effects) and current loss.

The Unlucky’s reputation strongly influenced the Passer-by’s decisions in both, the Stable and the Stochastic treatments (Table 1a,b). A large loss in the Stochastic treatment increased the Passer-by’s probability of helping (Table 1b), but did not significantly affect the use of reputation (see the non-significant interaction between reputation and amount of loss in Table 1b). Whether the Passer-by was helped in the previous interaction did not seem to influence her decision in the Stable treatment (Supplementary Table 1a). In the Stochastic treatment however, this previous interaction may have affected the use of reputation, as Passer-bys who had not received were less likely to give, particularly to more generous Unluckies (Supplementary Table 1b; Supplementary Figure 1). The type of loss (i.e. large or small) suffered by the Passer-bys in their previous interaction seemed to have no effect here (Supplementary Table 1b).

Figure 1 shows the relationship between the players’ generosity and their earnings over time. As expected, the correlation between generosity and earnings was negative at the start of a game (reflecting the immediate costs of generosity). Over time, the Passer-bys’ tendency to reward a reputation of being generous increasingly compensated for the costs of generosity in both treatments (Fig. 1). However, the return on investment into reputation was steeper in the Stochastic than in the Stable treatment, as shown by the positive relationship between final earnings and final helping frequency at the end of the 24 rounds in the Stochastic treatment (LMM on final helping frequency corrected for group effects: slope = 12.1 ± 5.96 SE, p = 0.044, prob = 0.033) but not in the Stable treatment (slope = −5.83 ± 7.33 SE, p = 0.43, prob = 0.31; slope difference between Stable and Stochastic = −17.94 ± 9.45, p = 0.06, prob = 0.028. Not correcting for possible group effects led to qualitatively similar results (Fig. 2).

Figure 1
figure 1

Pearson’s correlation coefficients r between cooperation frequency and earnings over time under Stable (open symbols) and Stochastic conditions (filled symbols).

Correlation coefficients in the shaded area are significantly different from zero at p < 0.05, two-tailed.

Figure 2
figure 2

Regressions of cooperativeness on final earnings (Swiss francs) in the Stable treatment (open symbols, dashed line) and the Stochastic treatment (filled symbols, solid line).

See text for statistics.

The underlying factor for the difference in return on investment into reputation between our treatments is likely due to the fact that more selfish players within groups seem to have received help less often under Stochasticity than under Stable conditions, as shown by explorative analyses based on a post-hoc categorization of players into ‘selfish’, ‘medium’ and ‘generous’ reputation (Supplementary Figures S1). As a consequence, it seems that players categorized as selfish lost higher amounts when in the Unlucky role under Stochasticity than under Stable conditions (Supplementary Figures S2).

Discussion

We tested whether adding stochasticity on future economic losses incurred by individuals playing an indirect reciprocity game affected cooperation and/or the use of information on group members’ past behaviors. We found similar cooperation levels between stable environments, where losses endured by individuals were perfectly predictable and stochastic environments, where losses varied (while overall losses were always kept constant by the experimental set up). Also, donations turned out to be more frequent to those who had been previously generous to others under both treatments, confirming previous observations under experimental and field conditions10,11,12,13,14,15,16,17. However, when deciding to help needy group members, people were differently influenced by their partners’ past behaviors with others. Under stable conditions, the tendency to reward generosity only allowed generous players to compensate for the cost of helping others, as there was no correlation between reputation (i.e. information on past behaviors with others) and final earnings. In other words, investing into a good reputation did not generate enough benefits for generous group members to outperform more selfish ones. Under stochastic conditions, however, selfish players within groups were helped relatively less often and therefore finished with lower payoffs than more generous group members. As a consequence, the steepness of the return on investment critically depended on the environment: investing into a good reputation paid back earlier under stochastic than under stable conditions.

Our findings suggest that people are less forgiving with selfish members of their group when harmful events in the environment are unpredictable. One explanation could be that people merely expected higher levels of cooperation from others and hence behaved more severely with selfish group members. However, our participants were not only more severe with uncooperative players, but also, not being helped affected their decisions with future partners (a concept known as ‘generalized reciprocity’ or ‘paying it forward’38,39). An alternative explanation could be that interacting in an unpredictable environment elicited (more) stress in our participants than under stable conditions. In fact, it is well known in the psychological literature that unpredictability about future aversive events can be a major factor of stress for humans40, which could in turn affect decision making41,42. It has also been shown that people prefer predictable over unpredictable unpleasant stimuli and that both conditions induce different types of neurobiological responses43,44. Anthropological studies have shown that solidarity between group members is higher in unpredictable environments30. It is possible that cognitive mechanisms were selected in early humans to adjust their cooperative expectations in stressful conditions29. In our experiments, the more stressful nature of a stochastic environment might have led players to perceive differently both uncooperative players and not receiving help when in need, which eventually led to different behaviors. An interesting line of research would be to test whether other factors of stress, e.g. time pressure45, also affect the use of reputation in a similar way. It would also be interesting to see if relative cooperation frequency (i.e. score within a group) is indeed more important in indirect reciprocity than the absolute cooperation frequency, as suggested by the higher AICs we found for the models using relative reputation scores. If so, this would further support the hypothesis that humans generally assess their partners’ relative quality and generosity in biological markets46,47.

At the ultimate level, our results suggest that stochasticity could be a catalyzer for the evolution of cooperation through indirect reciprocity. In fact, the evolution of cooperation through a reputation system requires that the costs of investment into a good reputation (i.e. the immediate costs of being generous) have to be, on average, well compensated by the effects the reputation has on the behavior of future social partners5, either within the indirect reciprocity game itself or when transferred to other contexts such as, for example, Prisoner’s Dilemma-type direct reciprocity games11,48. Hence, if individuals have already in place a hardwired psychological mechanism that makes them behave differently under stressful conditions (and which evolved for other reasons, e.g. coping with the environment), this could also affect their social interactions. Future theoretical work should investigate whether being less forgiving with selfish group members under environmental stochasticity would actually be adaptive and in turn lead to the evolution cooperation more effectively.

Our analysis concentrated on whether or not the displayed information was taken into account and disregarded any other possible reputation-updating rules. We cannot exclude that players took higher-order information in account like, for example, the reputation of their partner’s previous recipients49. However, a previous experiment with a similar set-up (i.e. all interactions were observed by everybody) specifically tested for such higher-order strategies and did not find them to play a significant role50. Considering the number of interactions to observe and remember in our experiment, we believe it would probably have been cognitively too demanding and hence unlikely, to frequently use higher-order information.

There is increasing evidence that adding different kinds of randomness to systems can have dramatic effects on the evolution of social behavior in various other contexts28,29,51. Stochastic evolutionary game theory can, for example, explain the extraordinary high levels of fairness that humans often display in Ultimatum Games52,53, or the evolution of the kind of overconfidence that seems very widespread in humans54. Indeed, randomness and uncertainty play important roles in human psychology and recent experiments demonstrated that increased uncertainty led to higher offers in the Ultimatum Game52 and higher levels of trust in a Trust Game55. The finding that stochasticity in losses also increases the value of reputation in indirect reciprocity seems to fit well into this overall pattern and suggests that randomness can be an important driver also for the evolution of reputation-based behavioral strategies.

Additional Information

How to cite this article: dos Santos, M. et al. Stochasticity in economic losses increases the value of reputation in indirect reciprocity. Sci. Rep. 5, 18182; doi: 10.1038/srep18182 (2015).