Introduction

In sexually reproducing species, sex roles have traditionally been labeled as female choice and male competition1,2. Male mate choice first drew attention from research on species with reversed sex roles in courtship and mate choice3 whereby males evolve a strategy of providing the majority of parental care investment instead of females4. An increasing number of empirical studies have shown, however, that male mate choice also exists in species with traditional sex roles5,6. Theoretically, male preferences are selected against due to the high level of competition over attractive females7,8,9, with a sufficiently large variation in female fecundity and/or quality (i.e., female viability) necessary to overcome the competitive cost and generate male preferences with traditional sex roles5,6,7,10. The current evolutionary theory, therefore, suggests that the conditions required for the evolution of male mate choice are much more constrained than those for the evolution of female choice8.

Very few studies have examined the possibility of male preferences driving the evolution of costly female traits11. Additionally, it has been proposed that direct fitness benefits associated with female traits (e.g., high fecundity or quality) may be essential for the evolution of female traits in nature7,12,13,14,15,16. For example, males may show preferences for females with a large body size, which should be highly correlated with increased female fecundity5,17. Other empirical studies have suggested that signaling traits such as plumage coloration in birds18,19, coloration in fish20, or sexual swellings in primates21 that are related to male choice may directly indicate female quality. It is noteworthy that, in contrast to the ubiquitous female choice for male traits, there are very few empirical examples of male preferences for female traits, which we suggest may be related to the conventional mindset that a female trait can only evolve when it is correlated with fecundity or quality. In this study, we explore how the male preferences and female traits may evolve without such a limitation.

In previous sexual selection models, male mate choice has been widely assumed to take effect during the pre-pairing period, i.e., choosy males exhibit divergent mating tendencies for females with or without the preferred signaling traits9. In this case, although choosy males are more likely to mate with their preferred females, not everyone succeeds due to male−male competition7. Furthermore, the general assumption in those models has been that choosy males would show no difference in post-pairing behavior regardless of when they mate with preferred or unpreferred females. We suggest that this assumption is an unnecessarily restrictive condition applied to previous models. In many animals (e.g., in birds and mammals) the reproductive stage of the life cycle does not end at copulation as males still need to ensure their own sperm fertilizes the eggs and perhaps provide paternal care in order to acquire fitness22. However, males may be cuckolded during the post-pairing period, resulting in multiple paternity23,24,25. Thus, males may face a post-pairing trade-off between seeking additional mating and investment in breeding within social pair, including mate guarding26, providing incubation feeding27, vigilance28, and different forms of paternal care22. Some empirical studies have indicated that males within a population may vary extensively in additional mating efforts29, or even have the flexibility to take the initiative to vary their effort allocation between additional mating and reproduction within social pair30. This mechanism of post-pairing male choice-generating sexual selection for female traits has comparatively seldom been studied31 or considered by theoretical models that explore the evolution of male mate choice (but see refs. 15,32).

In this study, we develop population genetic models to demonstrate that male preferences and female mating signals could evolve and be much more easily maintained than previously expected if choosy males vary in both pre- and post-pairing behaviors. Specifically, we assume that when choosy males form pair bonds with the unpreferred females, the underlying instinctive preference would drive those males to allocate greater effort to seek additional mating post-pairing. We further show that a costly female trait could evolve from direct selection originating from a post-pairing trade-off between male strategies, and that a costly male preference can still evolve to a polymorphic equilibrium. Our models represent an important extension of existing theory, which highlights the possibility of underestimating the pervasiveness of male preferences and female traits in nature due to their detection being hindered by the polymorphism. Because only a portion of males would have preferences, detecting the preference would require a larger sample size and repeated measurements in e.g., binary choice experiments, which are commonly used to detect mating preference. Similarly, as only a portion of females would express the signal in the population, a relatively limited sample size or sampling bias along with measurement or treatment may significantly affect the empirical results (e.g.,33), although some types of signals (e.g., plumage or coloration) may be easy to detect regardless. Perhaps the biggest challenge would be when trying to detect both the signal and the preference while the nature of the signal is uncertain (e.g., some feature of a complex vocalization). Each signal would need to be repeatedly presented to multiple males.

Results

Trade-off between mate guarding and seeking additional mating

Unlike previous modeling studies on male mate choice (e.g., refs. 7,9), we include a post-pairing stage into our population genetic models that allows choosy males to have different strategies during this period. We assume that when a female chooses a male mate, reproduction occurs during which the male mate faces different post-pairing trade-offs. We first consider an intuitive trade-off between allocating effort to seeking additional mating and defending within-pair paternity (e.g., through mate guarding24,34,35 or territory defense36). In this model, males contribute nothing but gametes to the offspring (which can be interpreted as all males contributing equally in paternal care).

We assume two loci denoted P and T in our model. The first locus P determines the male preference, while T determines the expression of a female signaling trait. Specifically, we assume P2 males have a preference to mate with T2 females pre-pairing. However, it does not mean that all P2 males would mate with their preferred T2 females due to the competition with other males. And if T1 females choose to mate with P2 males, the preference for T2 females might drive those P2 males to reduce their investment in breeding within social pair (e.g., reducing their effort to mate guarding or paternal care as we explored in this study), which in turn enables them to have more effort to seeking additional matings.

We consider a pre-pairing life stage similar to previous models7,9. The life cycle starts by male courtship. We assume that males with the preference P2 allele are 1 + a times more likely to court preferred females (T2) than unpreferred (T1) females (at a ratio of (1 + a):1, respectively). All males compete for limited mating opportunities in the population depending on their courtship efforts (see Eqs. 4, 5 in “Methods”). For analytical tractability, we assume polygyny in our model to ensure all females having equal mating success, and the females choose their mate based on the male’s courtship effort. Empirical studies have indicated that polygynous species may also engage in EPCs, causing the males to face a severe risk of cuckoldry in nature (e.g.,37,38).

After mating, a post-pairing life stage occurs, during which both males and females may engage in EPCs. We assume the ratios of within-pair offspring produced by females of different genotypes are determined by their male mates’ mate guarding investment. Specifically, P1 males (i.e., without preferences) would allocate a fixed effort to mate guarding, by which their female mates would engage in EPCs also at a fixed probability (denoted by α). For those females that have EPCs, we further assume that they would produce a proportion β of extra-pair offspring. Therefore, the female mates of P1 males can produce extra-pair and within-pair offspring at expected proportions of αβ and 1 − αβ, respectively. For analytical simplicity, we use a parameter θ (instead of 1 − αβ) to represent the proportion of within-pair offspring that can be fertilized by P1 males, implying that their female mates would produce a proportion 1 − θ of extra-pair offspring in general. For P2 males, we assume they would have a variable post-pairing behavior that depends on the phenotypes of their social mates. When they mate with unpreferred T1 females, P2 males are prone to reduce their mate guarding effort to seek additional matings15, and as a result, can only fertilize a reduced proportion (θ − Δθ) of within-pair offspring (see Eq. 6 in “Methods”). However, they would act in a similar way to P1 males when they mate with the preferred T2 females.

We also assume P1 males would allocate fixed effort to seek EPCs (denoted by e), so do P2 males when they mate with the preferred T2 females. For P2 males that mate with unpreferred T1 females, however, they can spend additional effort (e.g., longer time and/or more energy) to seek EPCs (denoted by e + Δe), because of their reduced mate guarding investment. After within-pair and extra-pair copulations, females then begin to produce offspring. We delineate the full model construction processes and the detailed model analysis in the Methods.

Contrary to previous modeling outcomes that consider only a pre-pairing life stage7, our model reveals a line of neutrally stable polymorphic equilibria (Fig. 1 and Supplementary Fig. 1) whereby male preference and the female trait could evolve and be maintained polymorphically when the following condition is met (detailed description of each symbol can be found in Table 1):

$$\frac{\varDelta e}{e} > \frac{\varDelta \theta }{1-\theta }$$
(1)

where \(\frac{\varDelta e}{e}\) represents the relative increase in fitness gained from additional mating by P2 males when they mate with unpreferred T1 females, and\(\frac{\varDelta \theta }{1-\theta }\) represents the relative loss of paternity. The equilibria of this model represents a balance between the competition for preferred T2 females, which selects against choosy P2 males7, and the selection for P2 males due to their potential for increased extra-pair paternity from additional mating to outperform within-pair paternity loss when they mate with unpreferred T1 females. Thus, an increased value of \(\frac{\varDelta e}{e}\) generally has a positive effect on the equilibrium frequencies of both the P2 and T2 alleles (Fig. 1a).

Fig. 1: The stable internal equilibria of the two-locus models for the male preference P2 and female trait T2, allele frequencies when choosy males have a trade-off between mate guarding and seeking additional mating.
figure 1

a Effect of the relative increase in fitness gained from additional mating by P2 males (\(\frac{\varDelta e}{e}\)). The three lines in this graph represent different values of \(\varDelta e\). b Effect of different strengths of male preference (a). The parameters behind those lines satisfy \(\frac{\varDelta e}{e} > \frac{\varDelta \theta }{1-\theta }\), where \(\frac{\varDelta e}{e}\) represents the relative increase in fitness gained from additional mating by P2 males when they mate with unpreferred T1 females, \(\frac{\varDelta \theta }{1-\theta }\) represents the relative loss of paternity. For both panels, \(e\) = 0.8, \(\varDelta \theta =0.1\), and θ = 0.8. We set a = 1 in (a) and \(\varDelta e=0.7\) in (b).

Table 1 Detailed description of each symbol used in the models.

From condition (1), we can see that male preference (a) has no effect on determining the existence of stable polymorphic equilibria. However, a stronger male preference (a) can effectively hinder the evolution of male preference and female trait (i.e., resulting in lower equilibrium frequencies of P2 and T2, see Fig. 1b). Intuitively, when male preference (a) is stronger, the effect of direct negative selection on the male preference would be increased. Additionally, since choosy P2 males will be less likely to mate with unpreferred T1 females in this case (i.e., under a stronger male preference), it thus may lead to a much lower chance of benefitting from additional mating, further resulting in a reduced stable frequency of the male preference P2 allele (Fig. 1b).

Simulations indicated that initial frequencies of the P2 and T2 alleles determine the evolutionary outcome in this basic model (Supplementary Fig. 1). The near vertical evolutionary trajectories mean that very little evolution occurs in the female T2 trait allele because all females have the same mating success regardless of the locus T. The female trait evolves only because of the indirect selection from the genetic correlation between the female trait and the male preference9, as we find that a positive linkage disequilibrium between the loci P and T arises soon (Supplementary Fig. 2). Furthermore, we numerically confirmed that the linkage disequilibrium between the two loci at the line of polymorphic equilibria is always positive. The alleles P2 and T2 (and P1 and T1) are therefore associated along this line. Two mechanisms contribute to this association. First, P2 males show preferences to mate T2 females pre-pairing, resulting in nonrandom mating (i.e., it would be more likely to have P2 male-T2 female pairs than random mating). Second, when P2 males mate with unpreferred T1 females, they would reduce their guarding effort to look for extra-pair mating, resulting in a portion of offspring produced by the social pair (i.e., P2 male-T1 female) being replaced by extra-pair paternity (which could be with P1 males), while the P2 males get a chance to produce extra-pair offspring with T2 females through extra-pair mating. These two mechanisms thus enable P2 males to have a higher probability of producing offspring with T2 females than with T1 females, resulting in the positive linkage disequilibrium.

Trade-off between paternal care investment and seeking additional mating

Here we also consider another possible post-pairing trade-off for males, which is between seeking additional mating and providing paternal care to ensure offspring survival and quality22. In this model, we assume males of all genotypes allocate the same effort to mate guarding, and thereby females will have the same probability to be involved in EPCs. For simplicity, we assume all females produce a proportion θ of within-pair offspring and a proportion 1 − θ of extra-pair offspring. For choosy P2 males, we assume they will reduce their care investment in reproduction within social pair by a proportion, δ, when they mate with unpreferred T1 females, which translates to a reduction in fecundity. As a trade-off, they can allocate more efforts (i.e., e + Δe) to seeking additional mating (see “Methods”). In this case, the T2 female trait allele is more beneficial than the T1 allele due to the fecundity selection caused by male preference, i.e., T1 females (those without the trait) will suffer from a direct fitness loss when they mate with P2 males.

In this model, we find that the male preference locus always remains polymorphic when

$$\frac{\varDelta e}{e} > \frac{b\delta \theta }{(1+b)(1-\theta )}$$
(2)

is met. Moreover, the T2 female trait allele always becomes fixed within the population (Fig. 2b). Similar to the condition (1) in our first model, we can see that condition (2) also examines the fitness change in P2 males when paired with T1 females. The expression on the left-hand side represents the relative increase in extra-pair fitness due to increased effort. The expression on the right-hand side represents the relative loss in within-pair fitness due to reduced parental investment. When the condition is not met, both male preference and female trait can still evolve when the initial frequencies of the P2 and T2 alleles are relatively high (Fig. 2a). In both cases, a high frequency of preference is maintained only when both the preference and the trait alleles start at relatively high frequencies, with the preference locus evolving downward for the majority of starting conditions (Fig. 2). This is because under a higher frequency of the P2 allele, choosy P2 males not only face stronger competition pre-pairing, but also are more likely to gain a smaller amount of fitness from additional matings due to reduced paternal care investment by the social father, while their loss of within-pair fecundity remains constant. We also find that when the condition (2) is met, the frequency of the P2 allele would generally increase under a small initial value (Fig. 2b). In this case, relatively low competition for additional mating might enable choosy P2 males to gain enough fitness from EPCs to outcompete the selection on pre-pairing mate preference and the paternity loss of within-pair fecundity.

Fig. 2: The stable equilibria for the male preference P2, and female trait T2 allele frequencies when choosy males have a trade-off between care investment and seeking additional mating.
figure 2

a When condition (2), i.e., \(\frac{\varDelta e}{e} \, < \, \frac{b\delta \theta }{(1\,+\,b)(1\,-\,\theta )}\) is met, the model may evolve to an equilibrium point on the line of \({t}_{2}=1\) or on the line of \({p}_{2}=0\), depending on the initial frequencies. b When \(\frac{\varDelta e}{e} > \frac{b\delta \theta }{(1+b)(1-\theta )}\) is met, it would always evolve to an equilibrium point on the line of t2 = 1. The arrowhead curves show the evolutionary trajectories under different initial states (p2 and t2 are set as 0.1, 0.5, and 0.9, respectively). We set \(\varDelta e=0.1\) in (a) and \(\varDelta e=0.8\) in (b). For all runs, the other parameters are: \(e=0.8\), \(a=1.5\), \(\varDelta \theta =0.1\), \(\delta =0.1\), \(b=0.8\), and \(\theta =0.8\). .

Costly female trait can evolve in some conditions

Since expressing a signaling trait is costly to females39, we investigate whether such a costly female signal can also evolve through post-pairing behavior of choosy males. Specifically, we assume T2 females would suffer from a viability cost7, denoted by a coefficient sf. The life cycle starts with a viability selection on females (see “Methods”) and follows the same processes from the previous two models.

Firstly, the female trait allele is always lost from the population when there is a trade-off between mate guarding and seeking additional matings for choosy males (Supplementary Fig. 3). Under the trade-off between care investment within social pair and seeking additional matings, however, both male preference and the costly female trait can still be maintained polymorphically under certain parameter values. Specifically, a relatively large reduction in care investment by P2 males that mate with T1 females (i.e., δ) and/or a low cost of female trait suffered by T2 females (i.e., sf) play fundamental roles in driving the evolution, i.e., requiring

$$\delta \, > \, {s}_{f}(1+1/b)$$
(3)

otherwise the female trait cannot evolve (Fig. 3; Supplementary Note 1). From the above condition, we can deduce that the female viability cost (i.e., sf) needs to be lower than \(\frac{b\delta }{1\,+\,b}\), which represents the relative change of offspring produced in a single pair of T1 female and P2 male due to the reduction in paternal care. Under condition (3), there will always be a neutrally stable line of equilibria on t2 = 1 (see Supplementary Fig. 4a), enabling the evolution of both male preference and the female trait.

Fig. 3: The conditions required for local stability of different cases of equilibrium when males with a preference trade-off between care investment and seeking additional mating, and the female trait is costly.
figure 3

The equilibria are given in the form of (p2, t2, D), where p2 and t2 represent the frequency of the allele P2 and S2 at each equilibrium, and D represents the corresponding linkage disequilibrium. Regions indicated in blue represent the conditions for local stability of (0, 0, 0). Equilibrium (1, 0, 0) is stable in the red color region. The region indicated in yellow represents the conditions required for local stability of an equilibrium point of (\(\frac{\varDelta e(1\,+\,b)(1\,-\,\theta )\,-\,be\delta \theta }{\varDelta eb\delta }\), 0, 0). The brown region in the left panel (when \({s}_{f} < 1-\theta\) is satisfied) represents the conditions for a stable polymorphic equilibrium. The vertical black line shows the threshold value of δ when \(\delta ={s}_{f}(1+1/b)\). In the region on the right side of this line, the model may also evolve to an equilibrium point on the line of \({t}_{2}=1\) depending on the initial frequencies (e.g., Supplementary Fig. 4a). Detailed conditions required for different equilibria stability can be found in the Supplementary Note 1. Numerical results of the internal equilibrium (allele frequencies and linkage disequilibrium between the two loci P and T) can be found in the Supplementary Fig. 5. We set \({s}_{f}=0.05\) and \(\theta =0.7\) in (a), \({s}_{f}=0.2\) and \(\theta =0.85\) in (b). The other parameters are: \(b=0.8\), \(e=0.8\).

Furthermore, when the relative fitness increase of \(\frac{\varDelta e}{e}\) is larger than \(\frac{b\delta \theta }{(1\,+\,b)(1\,-\,{s}_{f}\,-\,\theta )}\) (and sf < 1 − θ is met), the model may also reach a stable polymorphic equilibrium (the brown color region in Fig. 3a illustrates when the male preference and female trait are kept polymorphic in the population). In this instance, the evolutionary outcome is either an equilibrium point on the line of t2 = 1, or the polymorphic equilibrium point, depending on the initial frequencies (Supplementary Fig. 4a).

We find that the linkage disequilibrium between the P and T loci is always positive at the polymorphic equilibrium (Supplementary Fig. 5). It thus represents that the alleles P2 and T2 (and P1 and T1) are still associated under the trade-off between male paternal care and seeking additional mating. Note that in this model, P2 males would reduce their paternal care investment when they mate with unpreferred T1 females, resulting in a declined number of surviving offspring. Therefore, in combine with nonrandom mating pre-pairing, P2 males can also have a higher probability of producing offspring with T2 females, but a lower probability with T1 females than do P1 males, resulting in a positive linkage disequilibrium. In addition, numerical analysis indicates that the parameter space that allows the existence of the stable polymorphic equilibrium is larger when the strength of male preference (a) is higher (Supplementary Fig. 5).

Male mate choice with a viability cost can evolve

The costs of preferences have long been known to influence evolutionary outcomes in sexual selection models whereby some extra benefit from mate choice is required to enable the evolution of a costly female choice40,41. Here we also investigate whether male preference and female trait can still evolve when both are costly. For simplicity, we assume choosy P2 males also suffer from a viability cost7, denoted by a coefficient of sm and that viability selection for the male preference happens before sexual selection (see “Methods”). The subsequent sexual selection and reproduction processes are the same as the previous basic models.

Intriguingly, we found that the model may still have a stable polymorphic equilibrium under the post-pairing trade-off between care investment within social pair and seeking additional mating (Fig. 4). Similar to the model with costly female traits described in the previous section, a relatively large reduction in care investment and a very low cost of the female trait are essential in generating a polymorphic equilibrium, i.e., requiring \(\delta \, > \, {s}_{f}(1+1/b)\), and \({s}_{f} \, < \, 1-\theta\) (see Supplementary Note 2 for detailed conditions required for the stabilities of different equilibria). Furthermore, when the gain in fitness from additional mating is relatively large compared to the loss of within-pair paternity and viability costs, the polymorphic equilibrium would become the only stable point (illustrated by the brown color regions in Fig. 4a, b; and see Supplementary Note 2). When the cost of male preference (sm) is also limited, satisfying \((1-{s}_{f})(1-{s}_{m}) > \theta\), then polymorphic equilibrium can be achieved under a limited reduction in care (δ), and also under a small increase in effort toward additional mating (Δe) (Fig. 4a, comparing to Supplementary Fig. 6), which should be biologically meaningful. Furthermore, either a higher proportion of paternity loss (i.e., under a smaller value of θ) or lower costs to male preference (sm) and/or female trait (sf) can effectively extend the parameter range that favors a stable internal equilibrium generally (Supplementary Fig. 7). As before, we find that the linkage disequilibrium between the P and T loci is still positive at the polymorphic equilibrium (Supplementary Fig. 8). Numerical analyses also indicate that a weak male preference (a) can have a dramatically positive effect on the equilibrium frequency of the allele T2 (Supplementary Fig. 8).

Fig. 4: The conditions required for local stability of different cases of equilibrium when males with a preference trade-off between care investment and seeking of additional mating, and both male preference and female trait are costly.
figure 4

The color definitions for local stabilities are the same as Fig. 3. Regions indicated in blue, red and yellow represent the conditions for the local stability of equilibria (0, 0, 0), (1, 0, 0) and (\(\frac{\varDelta e(1\,+\,b)(1\,-\,{s}_{m})(1\,-\,\theta )\,-\,e(b\delta \theta \,+\,{s}_{m}(1\,+\,b\,-\,b\delta \theta ))}{(\varDelta e(1\,-\,{s}_{m})\,-\,e{s}_{m})({s}_{m}(1\,+\,b(1\,-\,\delta ))\,+\,b\delta )}\), 0, 0), respectively. The stable polymorphic equilibrium exists in the brown color region in (a) and (b). Detailed conditions required for local stability of different equilibria can be found in Supplementary Note 2. Numerical results of the internal equilibrium (allele frequencies and linkage disequilibrium between the two loci P and T) can be found in the Supplementary Fig. 8. We set \({s}_{f}=0.05\), \({s}_{m}=0.05\) and \(\theta =0.7\) in (a), \({s}_{f}=0.05\), \({s}_{m}=0.25\) and \(\theta =0.8\) in (b), \({s}_{f}=0.17\), \({s}_{m}=0.05\) and \(\theta =0.85\) in (c), and \({s}_{f}=0.15\), \({s}_{m}=0.15\) and \(\theta =0.9\) in (d). The other parameters are: \(b=0.8\), e = 0.8, \(a=2\).

Discussion

Following the inclusion of male post-pairing behavior into our sexual selection model, we show that male preferences and female traits can evolve even without direct benefits for female traits, such as the higher female fecundity and/or quality11. Furthermore, both costly male preference and costly female trait may evolve and remain polymorphic when choosy males face a trade-off between care investment within social pair and seeking additional mating22. These findings suggest that male mate choice might be more common than expected in nature.

Cuckoldry (or indeed the existence of extra-pair offspring) plays a fundamental role in driving the evolution of male mate choice in our model. EPCs have long been detected in different animal taxa and mating systems, occurring in approximately 90% of investigated avian species42, and several other animal taxa, such as mammals (e.g., refs. 43,44,45,46), including humans47. Therefore, considering post-pairing behavior in assessing the evolution of male mate choice should be relevant to a wide range of species. The commonly accepted principle of cuckoldry is that the social father loses some paternity but can also potentially gain some extra paternity from engaging in additional mating with females that are already paired48. Whether cuckoldry is advantageous or disadvantageous to males thus depends on net yields15,32.

In our models, the potential gain (and loss) are dependent on the frequencies of male preference and female trait alleles, which in turn leads to different evolutionary equilibria. On one hand, the total potential available fitness from EPCs in the population depends on the frequencies of the alleles P2 and T1, because choosy P2 males would either reduce mate guarding effort (resulting in an increased ratio of extra-pair offspring produced, i.e., from 1 − θ to \(1-(\theta -\varDelta \theta )\) in the first trade-off) or paternal care (resulting in a smaller number of survival extra-pair offspring, i.e., from \((1+b)(1-\theta )\) to \([1+b(1-\delta )](1-\theta )\), see Eq. 8 in the second trade-off) when they mate with unpreferred T1 females. On the other hand, the extra-pair fitness gained by males of different genotypes is also frequency-dependent. For example, if the proportion of P2-T1 (male−female) mating types increases, the competition for additional mating would become more severe, because more males would allocate increased additional effort to seek EPCs.

In this study, we also show that a costly female trait can evolve when choosy males face a post-pairing tradeoff between care investment within social pair and seeking additional mating; in this case, T1 females, which do not have the trait, would suffer from a fitness loss when they choose P2 males. Thus there is the potential for the viability cost of the female trait to be offset by male choice. We suggest that even if the female trait is not correlated to direct fitness benefits, post-pairing male mate choice may drive the evolution of that trait. Furthermore, we note that relatively less costly traits (e.g., subtle characters) play essential roles in driving the evolution of female traits (see condition 3), which is consistent with several empirical studies on different animal taxa, in which female ornaments (or signals) have been reported to be relatively subtle11.

For example, during breeding seasons, female two-spotted gobies (Gobiusculus flavescens) have orange bellies20, and female spotted plateau lizards (Sceloporus virgatus) have orange throat patches49. Both traits have been empirically confirmed to be related to male choice. In contrast to the flashy colors commonly displayed in males of many other fish or lizard species, the female traits expressed by G. flavescens and S. virgatus are more subtle11. Given our model shows that female traits could be easy to evolve if it is not costly, a possible reason for these more subtle traits could be that they are costly. Given that females have to provide bulk of resources for developing offspring, a female may suffer more fecundity cost than a male when expressing the same trait16. Alternatively, female ornaments have also been explained as a genetically correlated by-product of sexual selection on males39,50. For instance, ornaments in female birds generally share the basic features of male ornaments in the same species, which may indicate a common genetic basis51. In this case, our modeling results highlight the possibility that males may easily evolve the preferences for these by-products, allowing females to overcome the costs for expressing the ornament traits instead of evolving towards sex-specific expression. This seems to suggest that the mating preferences of the two sexes may target the same ornament52, and that mutual mate choice may be present in sexually monomorphic species, which is not where researchers typically look for sexual selection. In reality, this pattern of subtle female ornamentation may have escaped our attention historically31, leading to a further underestimation of the pervasiveness of male preferences in driving the evolution of costly female traits.

The evolution of male preferences may be constrained by different costs5, such as the predation risk during mate searching and assessment, the inaccurate assessment of potential mates10, and a low probability of future matings53. In their sexual selection model, Servedio and Lande7 indicated that a viability cost to choosy males would accelerate the loss of the allele for male preference or prevent its spread when choosy males court more. Our results, however, reveal that both a costly male preference and costly female trait could evolve to a polymorphic equilibrium in the population (Supplementary Fig. 4b). We note that some empirical studies did find that both the abundance of female morphs and male preference varies among different populations (e.g.,54). This is consistent with our model prediction because different populations might evolve into various polymorphic equilibria. Further empirical investigation is required to verify how widespread this possibility may be.

It is noteworthy that our model hinges on the assumption that the pre-pairing male mate choice and the post-pairing guarding behavior or the paternal care investment are determined by the same locus. While it seems reasonable to us that when a male is paired with a unpreferred female, he would be more likely to seek out other mating opportunities. Several recent empirical studies on birds have found that supergenes can determine the reproductive morphs or behavioral phenotypes associated with mating, e.g., in ruff (Philomachus pugnax)55,56, and white-throated sparrow (Zonotrichia albicollis)57,58. We recommend further study focusing specifically on whether the pre-pairing choice and the post-pairing strategies are determined by the same locus, as well as theoretical studies on whether a linkage between the pre- and post-pairing behavior can evolve. Also worth noting is that we have conservatively assumed that females cannot receive benefits from EPCs in our models according to some recent studies (e.g.,59,60); however, if there are additional benefits for females42, it should further promote the evolution of male preferences and female traits in our model framework.

Our results extend the current understanding of the direction of sexual selection and suggests the possibility that male preferences and female traits are more widespread in nature, only awaiting to be tested empirically. It has been suggested that in many animals cuckoldry may be an important source of selection pressure on behaviors or morphologies in both sexes15,32, thus the mechanism proposed by our models may be relevant in many species. We suggest that understanding the evolutionary consequences of the effect of cuckoldry deserves more attention. Finally, we note that our models are framed focusing on male choice; the evolutionary dynamics of mutual mate choice considering both pre- and post-pairing behavior remains to be explored, as male and female mate choice may behave very differently in determining the evolutionary results7.

Methods

Basic models

We constructed a haploid two-locus population genetic model with non-overlapping generations to assess the evolution of male mate choice and a female signaling trait. One locus P determines a male preference, while the other, T determines a female trait. Each locus has two alleles, which results in four genotypes P1T1, P1T2, P2T1, and P2T2, with frequencies denoted by x1, x2, x3, and x4. Since P2 males would court their preferred females more vigorously, the proportion of effort spent in courtship by males of genotype j with females of genotype i can be derived as follows:

$${M}_{ij}=\frac{{x}_{i}{x}_{j}(1+da)}{{y}_{j}}$$
(4)

where d = 1if i is even (i.e., females that have the allele T2) and j is 3 or 4 (i.e., males that have the allele P2) and d = 0 otherwise, and\(\,{\sum }_{ij}^{}{M}_{ij}=1\). Because males of different genotypes should only differ in their allocation of courtship effort, not the total amount of effort, for each male genotype j the proportion of effort spent on each female genotype should sum to the male genotype frequency, i.e., \({\sum }_{i}{M}_{ij}={x}_{j}\). We can then solve for the normalization term \({y}_{j}={\sum }_{i}{x}_{i}(1+da)\).

Subsequently, females choose their social mates among those courting males in proportion to the frequency and courtship effort of each male genotype in the population. As per previous models7, we assume that all females mate and have an equal mating rate. Then we have the proportion of each mating type as

$${F}_{ij}=\frac{{M}_{ij}}{{z}_{i}}.$$
(5)

where \({z}_{i}={\sum }_{j}{M}_{ij}/{x}_{i}\).

A post-pairing trade-off between mate guarding and seeking additional mating

During post-pairing stage, we firstly considered a trade-off between mate guarding (i.e., protecting within-pair paternity) and seeking additional mating for males. In this model, the proportions of within-pair offspring produced by females of genotype i that mate with males of genotype j (denoted by Θij) are determined by male guarding investment, thus

$${\varTheta }_{ij}=\theta -k\varDelta \theta,$$
(6)

where k = 1 if j = 3 or 4 and i is odd, otherwise k = 0 (see in the main text). Correspondingly, the efforts for seeking EPCs by males of genotype j that mate with females of genotype i are \({E}_{ij}=e+k\varDelta e\), where k =1 if j is 3 or 4 and i is odd, otherwise k = 0. We assume the fecundity benefits gained from EPCs by males of different genotypes are directly determined by their effort on seeking EPCs15. Thus, the proportions of extra-pair offspring sired by males of different genotypes in the population are

$${\rho }_{j}=\frac{{\sum }_{i}{F}_{ij}{E}_{ij}}{{\sum }_{ij}{F}_{ij}{E}_{ij}},$$
(7)

After combining the pre- and post-pairing life stages in our model, we obtain two 4 × 4 matrices representing the proportions of surviving within-pair (\({O}_{ij}^{wp}\)) and extra-pair offspring (\({O}_{ij}^{ep}\)) between each combination of parental genotypes, that is,

$${O}_{ij}^{wp}=\frac{{F}_{ij}{\varTheta }_{ij}{\phi }_{ij}}{{\sum }_{ij}{F}_{ij}{\phi }_{ij}},$$
(8a)
$${O}_{ij}^{ep}=\frac{{\rho }_{j}{\sum }_{j}{F}_{ij}{\phi }_{ij}(1-{\varTheta }_{ij})}{{\sum }_{ij}{F}_{ij}{\phi }_{ij}}$$
(8b)

where ϕij represents the number of surviving offspring produced by a single pair in which the male has the j genotype and the female has the i genotype. Note that ϕij is the same for all mated pairs in this model, and thus is set to a unit (i.e., 1). The proportion of total surviving offspring between each genotype is therefore \({O}_{ij}={O}_{ij}^{wp}+{O}_{ij}^{ep}\). Recombination and segregation follow mating (both within-pair and extra-pair) for two loci in haploids. Recombination rates are assumed for simplicity to be 0.5 between the two loci (i.e., free recombination). Recursion equations were used to compute the allele frequencies of P2 and T2, and the linkage disequilibria between the loci P and T in the next generation. Details of the recursion equations and numerical analyses of all model versions can be archived in Mathematica files on Zenodo (https://doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.5717486).

Another trade-off between paternal care and seeking additional mating

In our second post-pairing trade-off scenario for choosy males, the trade-off occurs between seeking additional mating and providing paternal care to the breeding within social pair. For analytical simplicity, we assume each female produces a proportion θ of within-pair offspring and a proportion 1 − θ of extra-pair offspring. During offspring production in this model, we assume the number of surviving offspring (ϕij) produced by females of genotype i with males of genotype j is directly determined by the investment from their social parents61: \({\phi }_{ij}=1+b{m}_{ij}\). In this equation, the first term (i.e., 1) represents the surviving offspring due to the care provided by the female parent, while the second term (i.e., bmij) represents the surviving offspring due to the care provided by the male parent. We can treat b as a coefficient of the relative effect of male investment in reproduction within social pair, compared to female, and mij is the expected effort of male parent. Choosy P2 males will reduce their care investment when their social mates are unpreferred (i.e., T1 females), resulting in a lower level of paternal care efforts as \({m}_{ij}=1-\delta\), where δ represents the care investment reduction by P2 males in reproduction within social pair when they mate with unpreferred T1 females. In this case, T1 females that mate with P2 males would suffer from a fitness loss (i.e., their fitness is \(1+b(1-\delta )\) instead of 1 + b) comparing to T2 females and other T1 females that mate with P1 males. The number of surviving offspring ϕij of each mating type thus becomes:

$${\phi }_{ij}=1+b(1-k\delta )$$
(9)

where k = 1 if j = 3 or 4 and i is odd, otherwise k = 0.

Similarly to our first model, we assume P2 males that mate with T1 females can have additional effort (i.e., \(e+\varDelta e\)) to seek EPCs as a trade-off for the reduced paternal care investment. The other processes like courtship, pairing, recombination and segregation remain the same as our first model, i.e., calculating the proportions of courtship effort and mating types following the Eqs. 4, 5, respectively; calculating the proportions of extra-pair offspring sired by males of different genotypes using the Eq. 7; and finally calculating the offspring number using the Eq. 8. Note that we used the Eq. 9 as the surviving offspring number \({\phi }_{ij}\) in Eq. 8 in this model.

Costly female trait

In the above models, the female trait is assumed to be costless9. For our next model, we would like to know whether male preferences and female traits can still evolve when such traits confer a cost to female viability7. Specifically, we assume that T2 females that have a trait would suffer from a viability cost (denoted by a coefficient of \({s}_{f} > 0\))7. Therefore, we have four updated genotype frequencies for females denoted as \({x}_{i}^{{\prime} }\) (i ranges from 1 to 4):

\({x}_{i}^{\prime}=\frac{(1-{b}_{f}{s}_{f}){x}_{i}}{1-{b}_{f}{t}_{2}}\), where bf = 1 when i is even, and bf = 0 otherwise; t2 represents the allele frequency of the female trait. The viability selection happens before sexual selection and all other processes like sexual selection, recombination and segregation are the same as our previous basic models. The two trade-offs described in the above two subsections are both considered here.

Costly male mate choice

In order to investigate the effect of a cost of male preference in our model, we assume that choosy P2 males would also suffer from a viability cost (denoted by a selection coefficient of \({s}_{m} > 0\)) during their searching for or evaluating the mates7. Then, the frequency of each male genotype j before sexual selection would be

\({x}_{j}^{\prime}=\frac{(1-{b}_{m}{s}_{m}){x}_{j}}{1-{b}_{m}{p}_{2}}\), where \({b}_{m}=1\) if \(j=3\) or 4 (i.e., males have the P2 allele), otherwise \({b}_{m}=0\). The sexual selection, recombination, and segregation processes are the same as our basic models. As we have found that the male trade-off between mate guarding and seeking additional mating cannot give rise to the evolution of both male choice and costly female traits (see Supplementary Fig. 3), we only considered the trade-off between paternal care and seeking additional mating in this model.

Reporting summary

Further information on research design is available in the Nature Research Reporting Summary linked to this article.