Skip to main content
Log in

The Political Economy of Tax Coordination as a Bargaining Game Between Bureaucrats and Politicians

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In the public finance literature, the view prevails that taxcompetition among countries gives rise to an underprovision ofpublic goods and that coordinated tax increases are thereforedesirable. Public choice arguments, in contrast, suggest thattax coordination may not be in the interest of thetaxpayers/citizens because imperfections of the politicalprocess (political distortions) may lead to a waste of taxmoney. According to this view, tax competition is a desirablecheck on the power to tax whereas tax coordination would onlyrelax the budget constraint of an inefficient public sector.The present paper integrates the underprovision argument andthe public choice view into a common theoretical framework.The government is assumed to consist of politicians andbureaucrats with diverging interests. Fiscal policy ismodelled as the outcome of a bargaining game between thebureaucrats and the politicians. It turns out that coordinatedtax increases always raise the provision of public goods butalso increase the cost of political distortions. The effect onthe welfare of the representative citizen may be positive ofnegative, depending in particular on the distribution ofbargaining power between bureaucrats and politicians.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Besley, T. and Coate, S. (1996). Sources of inefficiency in a representative democracy: A dynamic analysis. Manuscript.

  • Besley, T. and Coate, S. (1997a). An economic model of representative democracy. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112: 85–114.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T. and Coate, S. (1997b). Lobbying and welfare in a representative democracy. Discussion Paper No. TE/97/334. September 1997. London School of Economics.

  • Brennan, G. and Buchanan, J.M. (1977). Towards a tax constitution for Leviathan. Journal of Public Economics 8: 255–273.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G. and Buchanan, J.M. (1980). The power to tax: Analytical foundations for a fiscal constitution, Cambridge et al.: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breton, A. (1974). The economic theory of representative government. Chicago: Aldine.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breton, A. (1996). Competitive governments: An economic theory of politics and public finance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breton, A. and Wintrobe, R. (1975). The equilibrium size of a budget maximizing bureau. Journal of Political Economy 83: 195–207.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M. and Lee, D.R. (1994). On a fiscal constitution for the European Union. Journal des Economistes et des Etudes Humaines 5: 219–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bucovetsky, S. and Wilson, J.D. (1991). Tax competition with two tax instruments. Regional Science and Urban Economics 21: 333–350.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deacon, R.T. (1979). The expenditure effect of alternative public supply institutions. Public Choice 34: 381–398.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P.A. and Mirrlees, J.A. (1971). Optimal taxation and public production I: Production efficiency. American Economic Review 61: 8–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, J. and Keen, M. (1996). Tax competition and leviathan. European Economic Review 40: 113–134.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B.S. and Eichenberger, R. (1996). To harmonize or compete?: That's not the question. Journal of Public Economics 60: 335–349.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review 84: 833–850.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haufler, A. (1997). Factor taxation, income distribution and capital market integration. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 99: 425–446.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A. (1982). Declining industries and political-support protectionist motives. American Economic Review 72: 1180–1187.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huizinga, H. and Nielsen, S.B. (1997). Capital income and profit taxation with foreign ownership of films. Journal of International Economics 42: 149–165.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keen, M. and Marchand, M. (1997), Fiscal competition and the pattern of public spending. Journal of Public Economics 66: 33–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kehoe, P.J. (1989). Policy cooperation amongst benevolent governments may be undesirable. Review of Economic Studies 56: 289–296.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mehay, S.L. and Gonzales, R.A. (1985). Economic incentives under contract supply of local governmental services. Public Choice 46: 79–86.

    Google Scholar 

  • Migué, J.L. and Bélanger, G. (1974). Toward a general theory of managerial discretion. Public Choice 17: 27–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D.C. (1989). Public Choice II. Cambridge et al.: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D.C. (1997). Federalism and the European Union: A constitutional perspective. Public Choice 90: 255–280.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nash, J.F. (1950). The bargaining problem. Econometrica 18: 155–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, J.F. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative government. Chicago: Aldine.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W.A. (1994). Bureaucracy and public economics. Hants and Vermont: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. Journal of Law and Economics 19: 211–240.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salin, P. (1990). Comment on Vito Tanzi and A. Lans Bovenberg: Is there a need for harmonizing capital income taxes within EC countries? In H. Sieber (Ed.), Reforming capital income taxation, 198–205. Tübingen: Mohr.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salmon, P. (1991). Checks and balances and international openness. In A. Breton, G. Gianluigi and P. Salmon (Eds.), The competitive state: Villa Colombella papers on competitive politics, 169–184. Dordrecht: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, F. (1992). The federal and fiscal structures of representative and direct democracies as models for a European Federal Union: Some ideas using the public choice approach. Journal des Economistes et des Etudes Humaines 3: 403–437.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sinn, H.W. (1987). Capital income taxation and resource allocation. North-Holland et al.: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tollison, R.D. (1982). Rent seeking: A survey. Kyklos 35: 575–602.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1982). A (partial) rehabilitation of the public interest theory. Public Choice 42: 89–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vaubel, R. (1986). A public choice approach to international organization. Public Choice 51: 39–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wildasin, D.E. (1989). Interjurisdictional capital mobility: fiscal externality and a corrective subsidy. Journal of Urban Economics 25: 193–212.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zodrow, G.R. and Mieszkowski, P. (1986). Pigou, Tiebout, property taxation, and the underprovision of local public goods. Journal of Urban Economics 19: 356–370.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Fuest, C. The Political Economy of Tax Coordination as a Bargaining Game Between Bureaucrats and Politicians. Public Choice 103, 357–382 (2000). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1005073716922

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1005073716922

Keywords

Navigation