Introduction

Sustainability fuels the risk of eco-opportunism that increases the level of transaction costs in supply chains. Thus, sustainability is a serious organizational challenge in complex and global distribution systems. However, the corporate sector provides the essential entrepreneurial tools for sustainable change. Management must encourage, nurture, and safeguard sustainable development while economizing transaction costs. Failure to facilitate effective organizational structures will undermine long-term sustainable economic growth. We need to acquire more insight into how organizations can promote institutional change to support sustainable growth. Transaction cost economics (TCE) offers perspectives on the relationship between the assessment of sustainability and inter-organizational design. The evaluation of sustainable institutions cannot be isolated to a single transaction but includes the network of dyadic formations responsible for the product lifecycle (PLC) in the new circular economy [1, 2]. A product lifecycle–institutional structure therefore requires inter-organizational management from the exploration, development, and production of raw materials to the post-consumption reverse-distribution operation, primarily of unsold products, and product recirculation. Consequently, the organization of sustainability requires an inter-organizational nexus of contracts approach to product lifecycle management capable of assessing the performance of the entire life of a product [3]. Evaluation of sustainability requires that firms document, control, and monitor operations throughout the exploration and production process and along the supply chain. The extent of monitoring of distribution systems therefore exceeds intra-organizational and inter-organizational transactions in an increasingly growing and complex global business environment. However, monitoring is grounded in the contract to control the product or service functions, often in an international multi-agency network context. One example of the emerging network approach is the sportswear industry, which responded to the Greenpeace “Detox Challenge” aimed at Nike and Adidas operations in third-world countries. The campaign stopped their worldwide network contractors dumping toxic chemicals into waterways. Sustainability management that safeguards the network of firms against such eco-opportunism requires an extended level of analysis that moves from the isolated dyadic approach rooted in the classic TCE analyses of transactions to the level of network of transactions within the system of multiple economic agents (see Table 1). Consequently, the theoretical focus on dyadic analyses must be supported by macro-level aspects of product lifecycle network (PLC network) analyses in the light of the coming evolution of sustainability.

Table 1 Eco-opportunism of circular economy versus the classic form of opportunism in economics

Sustainable Management

Sustainable performance is a complex three-dimensional concept leading to an ambiguous evaluation of performance. Performance ambiguity produces difficult and costly performance evaluation [4]. Consequently, sustainable performance evaluation increases costs to reveal the true value of inter-organizational exchange [5]. Sustainability not only expands performance ambiguity of the inter-organizational dyad but also increases performance ambiguity throughout the product lifecycle system in supply chains. However, received TCE theory is the framework in which to define, monitor, and enforce contracts [6, 7]. This is a profound reasoning behind mainstream management theory, economic exchange, and strategic change. Still, management literature presents different options for inter-organizational structures, such as franchising (the right to represent another company and brand), sales agency (the right to represent a company), or salespersons (transferring ownership of an item), to operate in the market. Thus, the traditional level of dyadic analysis avoids potential harmful eco-opportunism and the subsequent transaction costs to safeguard the interests of all parties within the product lifecycle network — consumers, stakeholders, and society in general. Received TCE theory illustrates the normative interests of the firm that might have the right to harm the environment through agent-contracts with eco-opportunistic operations. The waste markets in the computer industry lead to hazardous and dangerous recycling processes, e.g., in West Africa. Oil spill from oil exploration, development, and production along the Niger delta is another example. Increased global warming intensifies the problem of incomplete contracts among the various parties within the product lifecycle network. The new era of environmental protectionism constraints contracts and brings new contextual aspects to its theoretical offspring. Therefore, transaction cost theory must support a dyadic level of analysis with a network approach that includes combined elements of ecological, social, and financial performance. Antecedents such as cultural, political, and legal constraints add transaction costs to the PLC network. Sustainability creates performance ambiguity, both dyadic and within the entire network of organizations. Sustainability extends the level of asymmetric information in global supply chains and production systems, as the sustainable quality of products is difficult and costly to evaluate. Standardized sustainable quality through “green” brands introduces information asymmetry to the market. Without institutional frameworks that safeguard sustainability to consumers in the marketplace, markets for sustainable products will deteriorate into markets for “lemons” because consumers can no longer separate sustainable from unsustainable production [8]. The complexity of performance measurement leads to costs of evaluating the real effort in the overall product lifecycle system. Business strategy argues that outcome performance can indicate efforts whenever it is less costly to observe and evaluate. This explains, for instance, the application of sales-based monitoring systems in franchising [9]. However, sustainability breaks down the observability of both behavior-based hierarchical monitoring systems and outcome-performance monitoring systems.

TCE defines a hierarchical market as two ends of the governance continuum [10]. A hierarchical system is any form of centralized decision-making, organizational control, and monitoring systems to influence agent behavior. Sustainable management operates market-based frameworks such as quota systems (i.e., green certificates or CO2 quotas, taxes, or transferable permits). One important market-based approach is emissions trading, for instance, the European Union Emission Trading Scheme. Markets might promote solutions to environmental problems if it would be possible to internalize the negative costs of pollution or CO2 emission. When regulation of pollution to protect the environment changes the relationships between the polluting companies, it also triggers innovative processes to scale up the development of low-carbon technology to reduce the costs of pollution reduction [11]. Contracts defined through environmental regulations transfer costs to the polluter along with entrepreneurial incentives to innovate new technology. Also, countries that respond to environmental challenges by defining regulations gain a first-mover advantage because industry, rather than using incremental and linear product differentiation, will innovate to become cost leaders. In markets where it is cheap to pollute, industry will continue to differentiate instead of innovating. Furthermore, some of the most important countries in the world regarding biodiversity, eco-systems, and vulnerable environmental aspects are also among the most corrupt and probably disposed to eco-opportunism. For instance, important rainforest countries, i.e., Congo and Brazil, also have significant crime and serious corruption problems.

Organization for Sustainability

The development of global markets cuts switching costs and provides rich information to buyers and sellers. Consequently, the new era of global markets reduces potential opportunism and transaction costs and facilitates economic performance. Sustainability, however, in the light of eco-opportunism combined with information impactedness (Table 1) would encourage more monitoring, contractual relationships, and integration. The product lifecycle perspective to achieve sustainability supports the dyadic forms of traditional opportunism with a new formula of “eco-opportunism”: the combined ecological, social, and financial “self-interest-seeking behavior with guile” [10]. We extend the opportunism concept to include hidden actions and information to breach financial, social, and ecological dimensions of the product lifecycle network of contracts (Table 1).

From Opportunism to Eco-opportunism

The dyadic level of analysis is a necessary but not sufficient condition for sustainable management. The dyadic concept incorporates the potential exploitation of asymmetrical information within the bilateral system. Opportunism represents the calculated behavior behind hidden information. The classic concept of opportunism includes efforts to deceive the other party to the transaction (Table 1). In the conventional TCE model, we assume that more opportunism is involved in transactions under more complex conditions. Opportunism reflects conflicts of interests between parties in the relationship, and while opportunism relates to dyadic relationships, eco-opportunism relates to all information asymmetry within the entire product lifecycle network of economic agents (Table 1). Eco-opportunism comprises double-sided moral hazards in the overall product lifecycle system [12] and relates not only to the single dimension of economic performance but also includes indices into a three-dimensional sustainability concept. The complexity of the threefold sustainability concept produces information asymmetry and encourages the development of the eco-opportunism.

Transaction Costs of Eco-opportunism

The classic TCE model proposes that transaction costs following potential bilateral opportunism affect performance ex post. The survival of the most efficient institutional structures indicates that contracts affect transaction costs and performance [13]. Consequently, the dyadic contract nurtures the long-time survival of the product lifecycle–institutional structure. The costs of alternative inter-organizational structures affect performance [14]. The economic interests of the principal are manifested in the inter-organizational design and ex post performance [15]. Sustainability, however, is connecting the overall economic interests of all parties along the product lifecycle–institutional structure in a supply chain and production system (Table 1) [16]. Eco-opportunism therefore affects both levels of analysis and the conventional dimensions of transaction costs [17]. So, long-term survival is no longer solely a question of the economic organization that produces financial performance but requires that the product lifecycle–institutional structure includes measurable sustainable performance. Figure 1 illustrates that eco-opportunism increases potential transaction costs substantially when the network of multiple organizations in a supply chain must coordinate transactions to achieve circularity. A circular economy, for instance, farm-to-fork, is complex, difficult to control and costly to coordinate, and conventional linear management hesitates to change [18]. Transaction costs such as bargaining, monitoring, maladaptation, free-riding, and shirking costs are important problems that the green transition to a circular economy must face in supply chains. A circular organization of transactions that involve all organizations in a supply chain results in higher transaction costs to safeguard sustainability (Fig. 1). The linear organization, however, protects the interests only of the two parties in a transaction with little or no attention to social or environmental aspects.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Costs of eco-opportunism transforming linear organizations to circular organizations stimulating more integration and control

Uncertainty

Reacting to the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, IPCC, “climate-related risks involve decision-making in a changing world, with continuing uncertainty about the severity and timing of climate-change impacts and with limits to the effectiveness of adaptation” [19]. The driving force in the process that develops transaction costs is the “horizon of opportunism” [10], which is influenced by external uncertainty in the business environment. The architecture of the product lifecycle–institutional structure should protect the organizational network in a supply chain against such hidden and costly “self-interest-seeking behavior” in the system [10]. The ownership to the “product” will however accumulate all external costs related to its lifecycle in the hands of the principal. Not only will CO2 emissions, pollution, and social dimensions accumulate costs related to the production, but the sustainability concept will also affect the costs of opportunism at all stages of the product lifecycle process. The behavioral uncertainty is not connected only to the inter-firm relationship but also to the entire network. Sustainable management directs a strong focus on the sustainable uncertainty provided by the stakeholder groups surrounding the product lifecycle network. A myriad of interest groups engages in various aspects of the product lifecycle, and the product lifecycle–institutional structure must evaluate the potential risk they present. The defensive approach to see only the framework presented by the local legal system is no longer sustainable. Contractors or sub-contractors are strong contributors to the supply chain structure, but they may have private interests in a complex world of free markets. The Nestle “horsemeat” scandal in 2013 showed that intermediate markets within the product lifecycle–institutional structure could be invaded by opportunistic activity operating within the production under the Nestle brand that imposed transaction costs on firms at the other end of the institutional distribution network system. H&M, Gap, and Adidas were focused on because of worker rights in production firms in Cambodia. In 2013, a building collapsed in Bangladesh, killing more than 1100 people inside who were producing clothes for eco-certified brands such as Tesco, Walmart, and Benetton. Established brands and firms are no longer hidden from the transaction costs of eco-opportunism by contractors, sub-contractors, or distant partners at the other end of their global institutional network.

Theoretical Implications

The organization of sustainability of operations and transactions in a product lifecycle system is related to the ability to monitor and evaluate performance and to determine the true value of the objects of exchange [20]. Sustainability is a complex performance concept and is therefore costly to evaluate because of its multidimensionality and the technologies involved. When a company rewards sustainability performance and punishes poor sustainability, TCE theory provides some analytical implications. As the performance ambiguity of sustainability outcomes becomes more difficult to evaluate, markets fail because transaction costs exceed the costs of bureaucratic solutions [10]. Transaction cost theory therefore suggests that the complexity of performance evaluation leads to increased transaction costs and thus more inter-organizational control [21]. Previous empirical research has revealed that as unobservable or un-measurable non-sales activities become important, firms choose to integrate their operations [22]. Therefore, sustainable performance leads to greater integration of the partnerships in the supply chains [23].

Market Failures, Eco-specific Assets, and Natural Resources

Historically, market failures due to resource scarcity combined with specific investments have encouraged vertical control and integration. The “Seven Sisters” that controlled 85% of the oil market prior to the 1973 oil crisis were all vertically integrated [24, 25]. Climate change will, however, continue to produce market failures that challenge the conventional organizational structure within the product lifecycle. Climate change produces market failures and jeopardizes specific investments that firms need to safeguard.

Linear business models are often focused on activities downstream toward the consumers. The conventional motivation is the final transaction between the business and its consumers, and the conventional business model reflects a linear process in the supply chain toward consumption that ends in junkyards or ovens. It reflects firms as a coalition of vertical organizational interests bringing products from producer to consumer. The linear model has been described as a “marketing channel” [26], or a network [27] where organization related to post-consumption has not been a strategic issue for firms. The conversion from linear to circular institutional structures is evident in the electricity power industry, as we can see in Table 2. Electricity companies’ conversion to a circular economy is reflected in the fuel mix between coal (non-renewable) and renewable energy sources such as hydro, wind, solar, or other circular energy sources. Enel SPA, one of the top circular electricity generation companies, has 33% of its total fuel as renewable, while another large electricity company, RWE AG, is fueled 61% by coal, and Dominion Resource Inc. produces only 3% renewable energy. Like the tobacco industry 50 years before, the electricity generation industry is forced by stakeholders and investors to change their business models from linear to circular organizational structures. For example, institutional investors, such as the world’s largest investment fund The Government Pension Fund of Norway, have now decided to move away from coal, and the second largest investment fund in the USA, The California State Teachers Retirement System, has started to evaluate the same.

Table 2 The percentage of renewable energy (circularity) and coal (linearity) of nine of the largest international power-producing companies 31.12.20141

Another example of circular strategy is McDonalds, which fuels its trucks with its own cooking oil. Unilever is committed to changing from a linear to a circular organization and intends to “reduce environment footprint and increase positive social impact” and to “double sales and increase long-term profit” [28].

The circular economy is a concept imported from life sciences further to understand production and market systems in an organizational network. The core idea is that business systems imitate organic mechanisms in nature [29]. The circular organizational model is technically prepared and designed to exploit waste produced during the PLC and incorporate it back into the value chain. Biological waste should be cultivated to circulate it back into the environment. The other dimension of a circular organizational model involves the technical components. Technical components, metals, and toxic or other recyclable elements should be prepared to re-enter the production and distribution system. New regulations in the EU hold the car and electronics companies accountable for the lifecycle of their products. Furthermore, by removing biological and technical components (e.g., minerals), it is also possible to eliminate the risk of toxic elements arising from the product lifecycle.

Toward an Ecological Theory of the Firm

We argue that only a one-dimensional dyadic perspective will marginalize the future relevance of transaction cost theory. The traditional concepts of the received theory must be brought into an ecological context to explain the current development of future institutional structures. Sustainability causes new forms of market failures as well as market contexts based on social and environmental dimensions. A vital new approach adds two essential aspects to received theory: (1) a macro product lifecycle level of strategic analysis of institutional networks, and (2) a triple dimensional performance concept that includes economic, ecological, and social elements. Based on this understanding of the new context, we develop seven propositions that frame some relevant empirical efforts for strategic analysis based on transaction cost theory as portrayed in Fig. 2.

Fig. 2
figure 2

The ecological theory of organizing the transition from linear to circular economy

Sustainability and Performance Ambiguity

We propose that the multidimensional concept of sustainability increases the level of performance ambiguity, which is the difficult and complex measurement of exchange in question [5, 30]. Despite formidable work to measure and analyze sustainable development, the three basic dimensions of economic, environmental, and social conditions have been criticized [31]. Sustainable strategies relate to the triple bottom-line performance of ecological, social, and economic dimensions that together produce a vague and complex concept [32]. To systematically find and apply adequate information to assess sustainable strategies is difficult. Sustainability therefore leads to increased performance ambiguity. Thus, we propose that:

  • P1: Sustainability increases the level of performance ambiguity.

Information Asymmetry

Sustainable management is now a crucial element of conventional business wisdom. However, simultaneously, there is a problem that sustainable production is based on information from the entire network of economic agents within the product lifecycle network, from exploration to recycling in a supply chain. The owner of a brand in the fashion market cannot focus only on the market context but needs information about recycling systems as well as the social aspects of production, freshwater input, and carbon footprint. Sustainability creates a new dynamic, complex, and uncertain demand for information throughout the product lifecycle network. Global sourcing has further complicated the flow and validation of information. Therefore, sustainability drives an ongoing process of information asymmetry. The agents within the product lifecycle network gain information superiority through the sustainable management strategy. We therefore propose that:

  • P2: Sustainability increases the level of asymmetric information throughout the product lifecycle network of economic agents.

Ecological Uncertainty

Ecological uncertainty is one of the driving components of the ecological theory of organizations. The river Nile is an ancient example of how uncertainty affects institutions. Egypt is the oldest and most stable civilization because of long-standing stable access to sustainable freshwater through the river Nile. The uncertain water supply upstream in the nine other countries of the Nile delta has produced environmental uncertainty, resulting in problems for the stability of governance systems. Egypt therefore has been portrayed as a stable institutional structure, while the civilizations upstream, although culturally similar, has historically been unstable [33]. Several external environmental factors contribute to stability or uncertainty.

Increases in ocean temperatures and greater weather variations will change substantially the physical conditions of infrastructures within inter-organizational networks. The speed and impact of change in the business environment varies between industrial sectors and geographical areas. Inter-organizational responses to ecological uncertainties must face “the dynamics of vulnerability and exposure and their linkages with socioeconomic processes, sustainable development, and climate change” [19] emphasized by the IPCC [34]. The IPCC considers five crucial ecological risks, as presented in Table 3. Ecological risks produce inter-organizational response to uncertainty. IPCC [19] dimensionalizes the ecological risks to which inter-organizational networks must actively respond: (1) unique and threatened systems, (2) extreme weather events, (3) distribution of impacts, (4) global aggregate impacts, and (5) large-scale singular events. The development of integrated global inter-organizational networks leads to ecological uncertainty that single agents in this system must deal with.

Table 3 Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, IPCC, [19] risk dimensions of ecological uncertainty

Organizations must handle ecological uncertainties that affect the complexity and dynamics of the organizational structure [35]. Ecological uncertainty is an external force that constrains the availability of resources and affects the internal power structures in organizations, which then strive to absorb and neutralize ecological uncertainty within the global network of exchange [36]. Internationalization of inter-organizational networks therefore exposes supply chains to the serious effects of climate change. The global nature of sourcing and production of components intensifies the impact of climate change. As we have seen during the flood in Thailand in 2011, the distribution chains of Toyota, Honda, Samsung, and Lenovo were hit, leading to negative downstream effects in their supply chains. Investments in specific assets must consider not only potential behavioral opportunism but also the changing external conditions caused by climate change and resource depletion followed by potential eco-opportunism. The lack of a sustainable product lifecycle structure leads to eco-system loss and resource depletion because of eco-opportunism. Ecological uncertainty may lead to irreversible damage to biological diversity and the extreme long-term climate effects of CO2 emissions. Uncertainties change the factual aspect of the inter-organizational relationships and contracts throughout the networks. Both implicit and explicit contracts become incomplete or obsolete. The IPCC Report on climate change [19] Impacts, Adaptation, and Vulnerability (part 2) pointed out that ecological uncertainty leads to limited evidence and that “Studies estimating the global cost of adaptation are characterized by shortcomings in data, methods, and coverage.” Ecological uncertainty therefore develops informational impactedness that decision-makers must overcome [37]. Consequently, we propose that:

  • P3: Ecological uncertainty increases the level of asymmetric information throughout the product lifecycle network of economic agents.

Information Asymmetry and Eco-opportunism

Williamson [37] proposed that information asymmetry fosters opportunism. The risk of self-interest-seeking behavior is entangled with difficulties and complexity in observing an agent’s behavior. When contexts of information asymmetry appear, there is a behavioral risk of opportunism. However, eco-opportunism may characterize many markets. The “markets for lemons” [27] such as “greenwashing” might be a typical eco-opportunism situation under information asymmetry. For instance, the “horsemeat scandal” in 2013 illustrated eco-opportunism under a “market for lemons” situation. Beef sold in Europe contained, in some cases, 100% horsemeat. The scandal revealed the lack of traceability in the supply chain. One illustration of eco-opportunism also includes “show-room” factories built to fool other companies in the supply chain that production is sustainable. Eco-opportunists show clean production facilities with healthy and happy employees, while the production takes place somewhere else. We therefore conclude that sustainable strategies are affected by informational asymmetry through the threat of eco-opportunism:

  • P4: Informational asymmetry increases the incentives for eco-opportunism in supply chain networks.

Performance Ambiguity and Eco-opportunism

Performance ambiguity encourages eco-opportunism [5]. Difficult, complex, heterogeneous, and multidimensional indices of sustainable performance measures will motivate eco-opportunism even more. As early as in the United Nations Conference on Environment and Development, UNCED, the UN emphasized the essential role of the development of sustainable performance indications that “improve the information basis for decision-making at all levels” [38]. Thereafter, there have been reported huge efforts into the development of performance measurement indications. The compendium of sustainable development indication initiatives includes more than 500 performance indication measures of sustainable development [39]. The ambiguous and inconsistent application of performance measurement indications creates a window that encourages eco-opportunism. Therefore, we propose:

  • P5: Performance ambiguity increases eco-opportunism.

Eco-opportunism and Transaction Costs

Eco-opportunism is the self-interest-seeking behavior that has collective effects on the entire product lifecycle network in the shadow of sustainable development. Greenwashing brands, or companies, are well known examples of eco-opportunistic behavior. The global emission from fossil energy companies responsible for 9.8 gigatons of carbon emissions in 2013 did not constrain them from communicating sustainable behavior through “green” brands, web pages, and other “green” initiatives. However, eco-opportunism has attracted more negative attention from non-governmental organizations, the media, and society in general. Thus, economic agents tend to monitor and control their inter-organizational contracts to safeguard their environmental, social, and economic preconditions. Specialist consultancies and agencies monitor and control sustainable development upstream and downstream in the product lifecycle network. Sustainability creates the potential for eco-opportunism that is costly to monitor and control. We therefore propose that:

  • P6: Eco-opportunism leads to increased transaction costs.

Transaction Costs and Transition from Linear to Circular Institutional Structures

Transaction costs are related to the level of control existing through the institutional structure [5]. Transaction costs are the costs of organizing and verifying the true value of inter-organizational exchange [10] within the product lifecycle–institutional structure. When costs of organizing exchange in the market exceed those of bureaucratic exchange, management strategy chooses more integrated institutional alternatives. Monitoring, bargaining, maladaptation, shirking, and free-riding costs are all contract-related costs affected by sustainable strategies [17]. Sustainability manifests that the transaction costs of organizing the overall lifecycle structure will determine the institutional structure. Low transaction costs of assessing the true value of the sustainable exchange result in less need for inter-organizational control. Sustainability, however, produces a more complex situation where the value of the exchange in question is more costly to assess than is the more conventional dyadic exchange. Consequently, the parties’ involvement in monitoring, bargaining, and coordination increases. These transaction costs affect the institutional structure of the overall product lifecycle, and so the increased transaction costs associated with circular economy should therefore lead to greater integration and control [10]. Thus, we propose that:

  • P7: Transaction costs related to coordination and control lead to increased integrated circular organizations.

Conclusions

Future contact with, impact of, and responses to social and environmental systems are substantial. Thus, it is crucial to investigate the interactive effects between social, environmental, and financial systems, and potential uncertainties. Inter-organizational lifecycle networks of firms are crucial catalysts in promoting and developing a circular economy. Management research must draw attention to the circular interaction between human and environmental systems. The linear business model is obsolete, outdated, and simplistic, and is a dangerous instrument to solve future environmental challenges, as is the conventional linear management theory of the firm. Strategic implications based on transaction cost theory should extend the level of analysis from dyads to institutional supply chain networks. Through the lens of TCE, we have analyzed how the institutional organization safeguards the parties against the potential risk of eco-opportunism. Transaction costs caused by increased performance ambiguity are related to the new concept of sustainability.

The recent developments of environmental hazards concerning biological eco-systems, water, resources, the atmosphere, and related social problems are closely interwoven with the strategic problems of the institutional formation of organizations. Specific sustainable assets must fit social structures, the environment, and the economy, and should form future circular organizations. The product lifecycle network should become the new level of forthcoming strategic analysis. We conclude that TCE presents a constructive approach to the analysis of the strategic formation of institutional structures that can respond to eco-opportunism, eco-uncertainty, information asymmetry, transaction costs, and performance ambiguity. It is urgent to redesign organizational networks into circular institutional structures to facilitate low-carbon growth. Climate-affecting gases can be long-lived and difficult to reduce, biological diversity reductions are irreversible, and social developments are crucial catalytic instruments to develop a sustainable world. I hope this theoretical review inspires management research in circular and sustainable economy.