Skip to main content
Log in

Product quality and endogenous firm objectives

  • In Honor of Shin-Kun Peng
  • Published:
Asia-Pacific Journal of Regional Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the endogenous operational objectives of firms in a Cournot duopoly under the consideration of vertical product differentiation. We consider a three-stage game, where the owners of the duopoly simultaneously decide the operational objectives of their managers to be profit maximization or revenue maximization at the first stage, and then, based on the objectives, the managers simultaneously choose the quality of their products at the second stage, and compete in quantities at the final stage. The equilibrium results show that, for high heterogeneity of consumers’ quality tastes or restrictive quality improving technology, both firms choose to maximize revenues and produce goods with identical quality. For low heterogeneity of consumers’ quality tastes or superior quality improving technology, both firms choose to maximize profits and produce different quality. For the intermediate level of the heterogeneity of quality tastes and quality improving technology, both firms choose different objectives, and the firm maximizing revenues provides a high-quality product, while the firm maximizing profits provides a low-quality one.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In the literature on management authorization, Vickers (1985) and Fershtman and Judd (1987) indicated that, the design of incentive schemes and strategic delegation can achieve the objectives of enterprise owners.

  2. Tabeta and Wang (1996a, b) discovered that, in the international automobile market, American and Japanese automobile manufacturers adopt different operational strategies in competition: Japanese firms prefer “revenue maximization”, while American firms prefer the operational objective of “profit maximization”.

  3. Tirole (1988) shows that a pioneer offers the higher-quality product and earns more profits. By contrast, in Jing (2006) and Amaldoss and Shin (2011), they show that a firm may produce a lower-quality product if its relative cost efficiency is higher, and if the size of the low-end market is moderately large, respectively.

  4. The parameter range ensures the equilibrium demand and profits are nonnegative, which will be explained later.

  5. This setting implies an assumption of an uncovered market. Under the condition that one consumer can only purchase at most one unit of product, the demand for gross products in an uncovered market will be less than the total population of consumers, hence, some consumers will choose not to consume.

  6. From the perspective of management authorization, operational objectives are chosen as the contracts between firm owners and managers, which are connected with the managers’ salaries and their operational objectives. The objective function of an incentive contract between owners and managers is normally linear combination of profits and revenues \(w = \alpha \pi + \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)R\), where w is salary, \(\pi\) and \(R\) are firms’ profits and revenues, and \(\alpha\) is the decision-making parameter. \(\alpha = 0\) means owners require managers to pursue revenue maximization, and \(\alpha = 1\) means owners require managers to pursue profit maximization. Moreover, due to the complexity of endogenous product quality, following the settings of Fershtman (1985), Blinder (1993), Mavrommati (2012), Rtischev (2012) and Lin and Sun (2013), this paper only consider the binary choices of the objectives of “profit maximization” and “revenue maximization”.

  7. Because \(\overline{s} \ge s_{1} \ge s_{2} > 0\) and \(1.5 \le \overline{\theta } /\overline{s} \le 2.2\), we obtain \(\left[ {2s_{1}^{2} - s_{2}^{2} + 2\left( {s_{2} - 2s_{1} } \right)\overline{\theta } } \right] < 0\) and \(\left[ {24s_{1}^{3} - 10s_{1}^{2} s_{2} + 4s_{1} s_{2}^{2} + s_{2}^{3} - 2\left( {8s_{1}^{2} - 2s_{1} s_{2} + s_{2}^{2} } \right)\overline{\theta } } \right] < 0\).

  8. Note that Motta (1993) did not consider the possible impact of quality improving technology restrictions on product quality. Upon bringing in quality improving technology restrictions, we show that, the product quality of both high-quality and low-quality firms will be impacted by the upper limit of quality as shown in Table 1.

References

  • Amaldoss W, Shin W (2011) Competing for low-end markets. Marketing Sci 30:776–788

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blinder AS (1993) A simple note on the Japanese firm. J Japanese Int Econ 7:238–255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chambers C, Kouvelis P, Semple J (2006) Quality-based competition, profitability, and variable costs’. Manage Sci 52:1884–1895

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fershtman C (1985) Internal organizations and managerial incentives as strategic variables in competitive environment. Int J Ind Organ 3:245–253

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fershtman C, Judd KL (1987) Equilibrium incentives in oligopoly. Am Econ Rev 77:927–940

    Google Scholar 

  • Heifetz A, Shannon C, Spiegel Y (2007) What to maximize if you must. J Econ Theory 133:31–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jing B (2006) On the profitability of firms in a differentiated industry. Marketing Sci 25:248–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin R-Y, Sun C-H (2013) Endogenous objective and quantity competition in an oligopoly model. Soochow J Econ Bus 80:1–25

    Google Scholar 

  • Mavrommati A (2012) A Stackelberg duopoly with binary choices of objective. Econ Bull 32:843–853

    Google Scholar 

  • Motta M (1993) Endogenous quality choice: price vs. quantity competition. J Ind Econ 41:113–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rtischev D (2012) Strategic commitment to pursue a goal other than profit in a Cournot duopoly. Gakushuin Econ Pap 49:133–142

    Google Scholar 

  • Tabeta N, Wang R (1996a) Relative revenue-maximizing strategy under Cournot duopolistic competition: the case of US–Japan bilateral auto-trade. Working paper series (Nanyang Technological University, School of Accountancy and Business, SABRE Centre, Singapore), no 8–96. http://malcat.uum.edu.my/kip/Record/utm.u419471

  • Tabeta N, Wang R (1996b) Who will be the winner when a profit-maximizer meets a revenue-maximizer? The case of US–Japan auto trade. Working paper series (Nanyang Technological University, School of Accountancy and Business, SABRE Centre, Singapore), no. 19–96. http://malcat.uum.edu.my/kip/Record/utm.u450156

  • Tirole J (1988) The theory of industrial organization, Cambridge. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 96–106

    Google Scholar 

  • Vickers J (1985) Delegation and the theory of the firm. Econ J 95:138–147

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wauthy X (1996) Quality choice in models of vertical differentiation. J Ind Econ 44:345–353

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yi-Ling Cheng.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

We would like to express gratitude to Wen-jung Liang, Chia-hung Sun, Cheng-hau Peng, and Chin-sheng Chen for their helpful suggestions to the draft of the manuscript. Also, we appreciate the valuable comments from participants of the 2014 Joint Conference of the Taiwan Economic Association and the Taiwan Association of Efficiency and Productivity.

Appendix 1

Appendix 1

The profits of firms in each case can be written as:

$$\varPi_{1}^{\text{PP}} = \frac{{\overline{s} }}{{128\overline{\theta } }}\left[ {4757\overline{s}^{2} + 18\overline{\theta } \left( {3a + 10\overline{\theta } } \right) - 3\overline{s} \left( {71a + 660\overline{\theta } } \right)} \right],$$
$$\varPi_{2}^{\text{PP}} = \frac{{\overline{s} }}{{128\overline{\theta } }}\left[ {1583\overline{s}^{2} + 2\left( {a - 2\overline{\theta } } \right)\overline{\theta } - \overline{s} \left( {71a + 292\overline{\theta } } \right)} \right],$$
$$\varPi_{1}^{\text{RR}} = \frac{1}{18}\overline{\theta } \left( {2\overline{\theta } - 3} \right),$$
$$\varPi_{2}^{\text{RR}} = \frac{1}{18}\overline{\theta } \left( {2\overline{\theta } - 3} \right),$$
$$\varPi_{1}^{\text{RP}} = \frac{{3\overline{s} }}{{32\overline{\theta } }}\left[ {456\overline{s}^{2} + 3\overline{\theta } \left( {3b + 5\overline{\theta } } \right) - 2\overline{s} \left( {19b + 87\overline{\theta } } \right)} \right],$$
$$\varPi_{2}^{\text{RP}} = \frac{{\overline{s} }}{{32\overline{\theta } }}\left[ {432\overline{s}^{2} + \left( {b - \overline{\theta } } \right)\overline{\theta } - 36\overline{s} \left( {b + 2\overline{\theta } } \right)} \right],$$
$$\varPi_{1}^{\text{PR}} = \frac{{\overline{s} }}{{32\overline{\theta } }}\left[ {432\overline{s}^{2} + \left( {b - \overline{\theta } } \right)\overline{\theta } - 36\overline{s} \left( {b + 2\overline{\theta } } \right)} \right],$$
$$\varPi_{2}^{\text{PR}} = \frac{{3\overline{s} }}{{32\overline{\theta } }}\left[ {456\overline{s}^{2} + 3\overline{\theta } \left( {3b + 5\overline{\theta } } \right) - 2\overline{\theta } \left( {19b + 87\overline{\theta } } \right)} \right].$$

Assume \(k = \frac{{\overline{\theta } }}{{\overline{s} }}\), where \(1.5 < k < 2.2\). Then, substituting the above into (7)–(12), the equilibrium can be derived as follows.

The condition for Case (PP) to be the equilibrium:

$$\begin{aligned} \varPi_{1}^{\text{PP}} - \varPi_{1}^{\text{RP}} & = \frac{{\overline{s}^{2} }}{128k}\left[ { - 715 + 456\sqrt {\left( {36 - k} \right)\left( {4 - k} \right)} - 213\sqrt {\left( {71 - 2k} \right)\left( {7 - 2k} \right)} } \right. \\ & \quad \left. { + 54k\left( {2 - 2\sqrt {\left( {36 - k} \right)\left( {4 - k} \right)} + \sqrt {\left( {71 - 2k} \right)\left( {7 - 2k} \right)} } \right)} \right] > 0, \\ \end{aligned}$$

where \(\varPi_{1}^{\text{PP}} - \varPi_{1}^{\text{RP}} > 0\) if \(1.5 < k < 1.529\):

$$\begin{aligned} \varPi_{2}^{\text{PP}} - \varPi_{2}^{\text{PR}} & = \frac{{\overline{s}^{2} }}{1152k}\left[ {14311 - 639\sqrt {\left( {71 - 2k} \right)\left( {7 - 2k} \right)} - 2k\left( {1282 + 82k} \right.} \right. \\ & \quad \left. {\left. { - 9\sqrt {\left( {71 - 2k} \right)\left( {7 - 2k} \right)} } \right)} \right] > 0, \\ \end{aligned}$$

where \(\varPi_{2}^{\text{PP}} - \varPi_{2}^{\text{PR}} > 0\) if \(1.5 < k < 1.531\).

Accordingly, Case (PP) is the equilibrium if \(1.5 < k < 1.529\).

The condition for Case (RP) to be the equilibrium.

Because \(\varPi_{1}^{\text{RP}} - \varPi_{1}^{\text{PP}} = - \left( {\varPi_{1}^{\text{PP}} - \varPi_{1}^{\text{RP}} } \right)\), we may obtain \(\varPi_{1}^{\text{RP}} - \varPi_{1}^{\text{PP}} > 0\) when \(1.529 < k < 2.2\). Besides, no deviation condition for Firm 2 is written as:

$$\begin{aligned} \varPi_{2}^{RP} - \varPi_{2}^{RR} & = \frac{{\overline{s}^{2} }}{288k}\left\{ {\left[ {9\sqrt {\left( {36 - k} \right)\left( {4 - k} \right)} - 41k - 600} \right]k} \right. \\ & \quad \left. { - 324\left[ {\sqrt {\left( {36 - k} \right)\left( {4 - k} \right)} - 12} \right]} \right\} > 0, \\ \end{aligned}$$

where \(\varPi_{2}^{\text{RP}} - \varPi_{2}^{\text{RR}} > 0\) if \(1.5 < k < 2.031\).

Accordingly, Case (RP) is the equilibrium, if \(1.529 < k < 2.031\).

The condition for Case (PR) to be the equilibrium.

Because of \(\varPi_{1}^{\text{PR}} - \varPi_{1}^{\text{RR}} = \varPi_{2}^{\text{RP}} - \varPi_{2}^{\text{RR}}\) and \(\varPi_{2}^{\text{PR}} - \varPi_{2}^{\text{PP}} = \varPi_{1}^{\text{RP}} - \varPi_{1}^{\text{PP}}\), the condition of Case (PR) to be the SPNE is the same with that of Case (RP): \(1.529 < k < 2.031\).

The condition for Case (RR) to be the equilibrium.

First, \(\varPi_{1}^{\text{RR}} - \varPi_{1}^{\text{PR}} = \frac{{\left( { - 2 + k} \right)\overline{s}^{2} }}{18k} > 0\), where \(\varPi_{1}^{\text{RR}} - \varPi_{1}^{\text{PR}} > 0\) if \(2 < k < 2.2\).

Besides, since \(\varPi_{2}^{\text{RR}} - \varPi_{2}^{\text{RP}} = - \left( {\varPi_{2}^{\text{RP}} - \varPi_{2}^{\text{RR}} } \right)\), we obtain \(\varPi_{2}^{\text{RR}} - \varPi_{2}^{\text{RP}} > 0\) if \(2.031 < k < 2.2\).

Accordingly, Case (RR) is the equilibrium if \(2.031 < k < 2.2\).

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cheng, YL., Kao, HH. Product quality and endogenous firm objectives. Asia-Pac J Reg Sci 3, 813–830 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s41685-019-00122-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s41685-019-00122-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation