Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

How Can We Keep Direct Democracy and Avoid “Kolotoumba”

Comment on “Proposals for a Democracy of the Future” by Bruno Frey

  • Research Paper
  • Published:
Homo Oeconomicus Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The issue of divisive referendums, which Professor Frey identifies as one of the problems of “Democracy of the Future”, is a special case of emerging tribalism (division into non-communicating competitive groups in political and social life). This article proposes an alternative institutional solution to address tribalism in both direct and representative democracy. It introduces competition for agenda setting in referendums such that more inclusive solutions emerge; it also proposes the adoption of an electoral system that multiplies the options of the public both in direct and representative democracy in order to further empower the general public.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Exceptions from this statement are cases where the position is not considered a privilege that people seek (jury duty), or has side payments like body of electors which could be corrupted (as in Venetian elections). Finally, while a lottery as the final stage of voting is a system that produces strategy-proof electoral system according to Gibbard’s Theorem it is not clear why one would want such system (Gibbard 1973).

  2. The word is in quotation marks, because in multidimensional spaces the probability that there will be a median in all dimensions is zero, but one could consider some other central location like the center of the yolk (Ferejohn et al. Ferejohn et al. 1984).

  3. The text said: “Should the text submitted by the European Commission, the European Central Bank, and the IMF to the Eurogroup of 25/06/15 and composed by two parts representing their complete proposal be accepted?” (the titles (alone) of the two parts in English and Greek follow, and can be seen in the photocopy below

    http://www.tanea.gr/news/greece/article/5253525/ayto-einai-to-pshfodeltio-toy-dhmopshfismatos-ths-5hs-ioylioy/

    The interested reader should notice that the negative response endorsed by the government is presented on top.

  4. The results of the recent election in Catalonia, where a majority of voters supported the side of remaining in Spain, is forcing a kolotoumba of the separatists, since a referendum would not support their goals.

  5. The typical demonstration goes like this: 1. assume that the preferences have a certain profile; 2. assume that voters vote in a certain way. Under these conditions some paradoxes follow. See the debate between Saari, and Van Newenhizen (1988) on the one hand and Brams et al. (1988) on the other.

  6. Actually, if we take into account the fact that each person may use a different voice volume to support each candidate, this is a form of “range” voting, similar to the way the jury scores Olympic athletes today. But approval voting is a special category of range voting.

  7. With no success, but given the US record of electoral system change it is not disappointing or even surprising. Actually, it would be a re-introduction because, as stated in Tsebelis (2014), “Approval voting has been the most stable electoral system in the history of our country (1864–1920). It was imported from Eptanisa, which got it from the Venetian Empire.”.

  8. The interested reader can see a model of this electoral system. By changing names and percentages of parties one can calculate the results for their own country. Visit https://sites.lsa.umich.edu/tsebelis/data/ and click on “Multiple Vote Electoral System”.

References

  • Brams, S., Fishburn, P., & Merrill, S. (1988). The responsiveness of approval voting: Comments on Saari and Van Newenhizen. Public Choice, 59, 121–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felsenthal, D. S “Review of Paradoxes Afflicting Procedures for Electing a Single Candidate” In Felsenthal & Machover, (Eds.). (2012). Electoral systems: Paradoxes, assumptions, and procedures. P 19-91 Springer Science & Business Media, New York.

  • Ferejohn, J. A., McKelvey, R. D., & Packel, E. W. (1984). Limiting distributions for continuous state Markov voting models. Social Choice and Welfare, 1(1), 45–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S. (2017). Proposals for a democracy of the future. Homo Oeconomicus, 34, 1–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerber, E. R. (1996). Legislative response to the threat of popular initiatives. American Journal of Political Science, 40(1), 99–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibbard, Allan. (1973). Manipulation of voting schemes: A General Result. Econometrica., 41(4), 587–601.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hug, S., & Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players and referendums around the world. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 14(4), 465–515.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laslier, J. F., & Sanver, M. R. (Eds.). (2010). Handbook on approval voting. New York: Springer Science & Business Media.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. G. (1995). Fiscal effects of the voter initiative: Evidence from the last 30 Years. Journal of Political Economy, 103(3), 587–623.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, John G. (2000). Fiscal effects of the voter initiative in the first half of the Twentieth Century. Journal of Law and Economics, 43, 619–644.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGhee, E., & Shor, B. (2017). Has the Top Two Primary Elected More Moderates? Perspectives on Politics, 15(4), 1053–1066.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nurmi, Hannu. (1999). Voting Paradoxes and How to Deal with Them. Berlin, Heidelberg and New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Plutarch (1888). Lycurgus. In A. H. Clough (Ed.), J. Dryden (Trans.), Lives of illustrious men. Boston: Little, Brown and Co.

  • Regenwetter, Michel, & Grofman, Bernard. (1998). Approval voting, borda winners, and condorcet winners: Evidence from Seven Elections. Management Science, 44, 520–533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saari, D. G., & Van Newenhizen, J. (1988). The problem of indeterminacy in approval, multiple, and truncated voting systems. Public Choice, 59, 101–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players: How political institutions work. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (2014). The Greek constitution from a political science point of view. Greek Political Science Review, 42, 145–172.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to George Tsebelis.

Additional information

A derogatory Greek term for summersault, which in this case means an unexpected U-turn. First used for the transformation of the Greek population’s NO vote in the 2015 referendum into a resounding YES by PM Tsipras.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Tsebelis, G. How Can We Keep Direct Democracy and Avoid “Kolotoumba”. Homo Oecon 35, 81–90 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s41412-018-0069-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s41412-018-0069-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation