Introduction

The concept of energy-return-on-energy-investment (EROEI, or more simply EROI) of human societies has been the subject of much research since its formulation in the 1970s (Dupont et al. 2018; King and van den Bergh 2018; Hall 2017; Masnadi et al. 2018; Court and Fizaine 2017). The EROI is the ratio of the quantity of energy delivered by a given process to the quantity of energy consumed in that same process; it measures the accessibility of a resource–the higher the EROI, the greater the amount of net energy delivered to society that can support tasks other than energy extraction necessary for economic growth (Hall et al. 2014). Several scholars, such as King (2014) and Brandt et al. (2013), point out that this definition is rather ‘lose’ nd that a clear distinction should be made between gross energy return ratio (GERR, i.e., the gross energy output divided by the energy consumed due to supply of final invested energy) and net energy return ratios (NERR, i.e., the energy that only goes to final consumption divided by the energy consumed due to supply of final invested energy).Footnote 1 For the remainder of this article, we avoid the term EROI, and use ERR only when the distinction between GERR and NERR is either unnecessary or unclear when citing other studies.

A Link Between the Minimum Energy Return Ratio of Society and Its Energy Conversion Efficiency

Debeir et al. (2013) describe a simple link between the minimum ERR required for society and its aggregate energy conversion efficiency.Footnote 2 Below is a personal translation of this statement, from pages 51 to 52, in the context of agrarian societies.

“In terms of energy, society ‘invests’ a certain energy quantity and ‘harvests’ a given food-energy quantity, obviously greater than the initially invested energy. Hence, the ratio

$$P = \frac{{{\text{Harvested}}\;{\text{energy}}}}{{{\text{Invested}}\,{\text{energy}}}},$$

measures the energy productivity of society. For its part, the population returns to the biosphere a fraction of this consumed food energy in the form of work. The efficiency of such a conversion is measured by the following ratio:

$$E = \frac{{{\text{Returned}}\,{\text{energy}}}}{{{\text{Consumed}}\,{\text{energy}}}}$$

[...] Every society must comply with the following: the energy conversion efficiency must be at least the inverse of the energy productivity of the food production system. If we take the cycle: subsistence \(\rightarrow\) human energy \(\rightarrow\) subsistence, and with the example of a society in which the conversion efficiency would be \(E=5/100\), meaning that, when this society has 100 kilocalories of subsistence, it cannot re-invest more than 5 kilocalories in its predatory or productive activities. To enable this society to at least simply reproduce, the energetic productivity P must be greater than 100/5, otherwise the energy potentially re-invested in the next cycle will not be capable of supplying enough subsistence for the needs of society. This reproduction condition is expressed by the following general inequality:

$$P>\frac{1}{E}. ''$$

One might argue for the unclear definition of the different concepts used in the above quotation from Debeir et al. (2013, pp. 51, 52). Indeed, as shown in Fig.  1, ‘harvested’ and ‘consumed’ energy correspond to final food energy generated by the photosynthetic conversion of primary solar energy; whereas ‘invested’ and ‘returned’ energy correspond to useful muscle energy resulting from the human body conversion of final food energy.Footnote 3 So, to be clear, the ‘energy productivity P’, described by Debeir et al. (2013, pp. 51, 52) in the context of an agrarian society, corresponds to the gross quantity of final food energy that society is able to generate per unit of invested useful muscle energy; in other words, it corresponds to the \(GERR_{F/U}=\frac{F_{tot}}{U_{in}}\) of society.Footnote 4 Moreover, in the context of agrarian societies, the energy ‘conversion efficiency E’ of Debeir et al. (2013, pp. 51, 52) corresponds to the aggregate efficiency of humans and draft animals to convert final food energy into muscle useful work, i.e., \(E=\frac{U_{tot}}{F_{tot}}=\frac{U_{else}+U_{in}}{F_{tot}}\). This final-to-useful energy conversion efficiency is conventionally described as \(\eta _2\), while, as shown in Fig.  1, \(\eta _1\) would designate the primary-to-final efficiency of the sun-to-food energy conversion process. Finally, one can reformulate the last relation of the above quotation of Debeir et al. (2013, pp. 51, 52) as follows: the minimum gross energy return ratio of an agrarian society is equal to the inverse of its final-to-useful energy conversion efficiency, i.e., \(GERR_{min,F/U} \equiv \left( \frac{F_{tot}}{U_{in}}\right) _{min} =\frac{1}{\eta _2}\).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Representation of the agrarian society described by Debeir et al.(2013, pp. 51, 52). For graphical convenience, losses at each stage are not represented. Source author

Goal and Organization of the Paper

It appears that there is no definition or estimation of the minimum societal requirement ERR that uses Debeir et al.’s (2013, pp. 51, 52) analysis. Although this might appear surprising given the apparent simplicity of this relation, distinguishing conversion efficiency at different stages (primary, final, and useful) means that the minimum ERR required for society is dependent on the system boundary. Moreover, the exergy concept is perhaps a more appropriate concept than energy for assessing the biophysical dynamics of society [see Appendix A and the recent synthesis of Brockway et al. (2018)]. Accordingly, in exergy terms, primary-to-final, final-to-useful, and primary-to-useful conversion efficiency are respectively designated by \(\varepsilon _1\), \(\varepsilon _2\), and \(\varepsilon\) (see Appendix B). Taking stock of these different concepts, this article seeks to reformulate Debeir et al. (2013, pp. 51, 52) in a more pragmatic way.

"Methodology" section shows that several minimum exergy return ratios (ExRR) can be computed in relation to different exergy conversion efficiencies. Data availability presented at the end of this methodological section restricts the possibilities of estimations for the different minimum exergy returns ratios. Nevertheless, "Result" section presents the long-run estimates of the minimum exergy return ratios of the European Union(EU)-15 countries, the USA, Japan, and the world. "Discussion" section discusses these results in the context of economic growth fluctuations and economic development levels. Finally, "Summary and Perspectives" section  delivers the contributions and opportunities for future research.

Methodology

Analytical Approach

It is possible to systematize to all societies the analysis developed by Debeir et al. (2013, pp. 51, 52) in the special case of agrarian societies by drawing on the literature related to exergy (see Appendix A and B). Figure 2 is a graphical generalization of Fig.  1 in exergy terms. One can then theoretically compute three minimum gross exergy return societal requirement ratios (\(GExRR_{{{\text{min}}}}\)) as shown in Fig.  2, namely

$$GExRR_{{{\text{min}},P/F}} = \left( {\frac{{P_{{{\text{tot}}}} }}{{F_{{{\text{tot}}}} }}} \right)_{{{\text{min}}}} = \frac{1}{{\varepsilon _{1} }},$$
(1)
$$GExRR_{{{\text{min}},F/U}} = \left( {\frac{{F_{{{\text{tot}}}} }}{{U_{{{\text{direct,up}}}} + U_{{{\text{embodied,up}}}} + U_{{{\text{direct,down}}}} + U_{{{\text{embodied,down}}}} }}} \right)_{{{\text{min}}}} \quad = \frac{1}{{\varepsilon _{2} }},$$
(2)
$$GExRR_{{{\text{min}},P/U}} = \left( {\frac{{P_{{{\text{tot}}}} }}{{U_{{{\text{direct,up}}}} + U_{{{\text{embodied,up}}}} + U_{{{\text{direct,down}}}} + U_{{{\text{embodied,down}}}} }}} \right)_{{{\text{min}}}} = \frac{1}{\varepsilon }.$$
(3)

where \(GExRR_{{{\text{min}},P/F}}\) gives the minimum number of primary exergy that the upstream energy sector must generate per unit of invested (\(\hbox {direct} + \hbox {embodied}\)) final exergy, \(GExRR_{{{\text{min}},F/U}}\) gives the minimum number of final exergy that the energy sector must return per unit of direct invested (\(\hbox {direct} + \hbox {embodied}\)) useful exergy, and \(GExRR_{{{\text{min}},P/U}}\) gives the minimum number of primary exergy that the upstream energy sector must yield per unit of invested (\(\hbox {direct} + \hbox {embodied}\)) useful exergy.

Data

Several time series have been computed for exergy conversion efficiency.Footnote 5 Serrenho et al. (2014) estimate the aggregate final-to-useful exergy efficiency (\(\varepsilon _2\)) of the European Union(EU)-15 countries from 1960 to 2009, and these authors have extended this analysis up to 1856 for Portugal (Serrenho et al. 2016) (Fig.  3).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Exergy flows between the (upstream and downstream) energy sector and the rest of society. For graphical convenience, losses at each stage are not represented, nor is the primary energy self-consumed by the upstream sector. Source author

Warr et al. (2010) estimated the aggregate primary-to-useful exergy conversion efficiency (\(\varepsilon\)) for the USA, UK, Austria, and Japan from 1900 to 2000 and updated Austria’s 1900 to 2012 values in Eisenmenger et al. (2017). Brockway et al. (2014) also updated the US and UK primary-to-useful exergy conversion efficiency values (\(\varepsilon\)) from 1960 to 2010. Despite several differences in methodologies,Footnote 6 we used Brockway et al. (2014)’s trends to extend Warr et al. (2010)’s data for the USA and UK from 2000 to 2010. De Stercke (2014) performed the same assessment of the aggregate primary-to-useful exergy conversion efficiency (\(\varepsilon\)) for the world economy from 1900 to 2014 (Fig.  4).

Brockway et al. (2015) estimated China’s primary-to-useful exergy conversion efficiency (\(\varepsilon\)) between 1971 to 2010 using a similar methodology to Brockway et al. (2014). We chose not to show these data on Fig.  4 for the sake of methodological consistency. Serrenho et al. (2016) and De Stercke (2014) also determined the primary-to-final exergy conversion efficiency (\(\varepsilon _1\)) for Portugal (1856–2009) and the world economy (1900–2014) respectively. Nevertheless, up to recent decades, these estimates are really close to unity because of the relative importance of food and feed (i.e., fodder for draft animals) whose primary energy estimates are conventionally equated entirely to final energy, meaning that the conversion efficiency of solar primary energy into final chemical energy of photosynthetic plants of around 4% is not accounted for. Hence, estimates of primary-to-final exergy conversion efficiency only make sense when non-food energy forms are dominant.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Aggregate final-to-useful exergy conversion efficiency (\(\varepsilon _2\)) of the EU-15 countries (1856–2009 for Portugal, 1960–2009 for all others). Source data from Serrenho et al. (2014, 2016)

Fig. 4
figure 4

Aggregate primary-to-useful exergy conversion efficiency (\(\varepsilon\)) of the USA (1900–2010), UK (1900–2010), Austria (1900–2012), Japan (1900–2000), and the world (1900–2014). Source data from Warr et al. (2010), Brockway et al. (2014), De Stercke (2014) and Eisenmenger et al. (2017)

Results

Estimates of the \(GExRR_{min,F/U}\) of the EU-15 Countries

Eq. (2) and data in Fig.  3 allowed the calculation of the \(GExRR_{{{\text{min}},F/U}}\) for the EU-15 countries. Portugal, with its data providing a long time-span, delivers the most interesting insight. Figure 5d shows the consistency of Portugal’s \(GExRR_{{{\text{min}},F/U}}\) from the 1850s to the 1920s at approximately 15–16. It then follows a decreasing sigmoid shape and declined towards a value of 5. The results also show other countries follow a similar pattern from 1960 to 2009 with Luxembourg being a notable exception. One can observe this consistent decrease towards a minimum final exergy quantity of around 5 units that the energy sector of these countries must yield per unit of invested useful exergy.

Estimates of the \(GExRR_{{{\text{min}},P/U}}\) of the USA, UK, Austria, Japan, and the World

We can easily compute the \(GExRR_{{{\text{min}},P/U}}\) of the USA (1900–2010), UK (1900–2010), Austria (1900–2012), Japan (1900–2000), and the world (1900–2014) by combining Eq. (3) with the data presented in Fig.  4. Figure 6 shows that the minimum primary exergy yielded by USA, UK, Austria, and Japan per unit of invested useful exergy declined between 1900 and 2010s from about 25 to 6 following decreasing sigmoid-shape trends. The \(GExRR_{{{\text{min}},P/U}}\) for the world economy has a very similar sigmoid declining trend.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Minimum final exergy return on useful exergy investment (\(GExRR_{{{\text{min}},F/U}}\)) of the EU-15 countries (1856–2009 for Portugal, 1960–2009 for all others). Source author’s computation

Fig. 6
figure 6

Minimum primary exergy return on useful exergy investment (\(GExRR_{{{\text{min}},P/U}}\)) of the USA (1900–2010), UK (1900–2010), Austria (1900–2012), Japan (1900–2000), and the world (1900–2014). Source author’s computation

Discussion

Comparison with Other Studies Providing a Minimum ERR Required for Society

Four previous studies discuss potential values for minimum societal ERR. Hall et al. (2009) suggested a technical minimum ERR of 3 for oil at the well-head and 5 to support complex societies, but concluded that a minimum ERR around 12–15 for primary energy is probably necessary to sustain modern lifestyles. Weißbach et al. (2013) give a minimum ERR of 7 required for OECD countries although the underlying calculation is not provided. Lambert et al. (2014) used nonlinear correlations between ERR and the Human Development Index (HDI) in cross sectional data to claim that contemporary societies require a societal minimum ERR of 15 for primary energy to reach an HDI of at least 0.7. Finally, Fizaine and Court (2016) used an indirect approach based on energy expenditures to show that the USA required its primary energy to be supplied with a (yearly) GERR above 11 for economic growth. This econometric result indicates a GERR primary energy requirement of around 12–15 to support a growing modern economy. These four studies concern primary energy, and there is seemingly no study that estimates the final stage minimum ERR for society. However, two recent articles assessing the point of use return ratio of final energy for two different countries can provide some answers on this subject. Feng et al. (2018) estimated the NERR of China’s final energy production sector declined from 11 to 5.5 between 1987 and 2012. Brockway et al. (2019) estimated that the NERR of fossil fuels at the final stage declined from 6 to 5.4 between 1995 and 2011. These results suggest a minimum ERR requirement between approximately 4 and 5 for the final energy supply of industrialized societies.

Theoretically, the minimum ERR estimate of 11–15 should compare favorably with the \(GERR_{{{\text{min}},P/F}}=1/\varepsilon _1\) of Eq. (1). Unfortunately, as stressed in subsection 2.2, the quality of current \(\varepsilon _1\) estimates prevent a meaningful calculation of the \(GExRR_{{{\text{min}},P/F}}\). The \(GExRR_{{{\text{min}},P/U}}\) estimated in this article has a sufficiently different boundary that it prevents direct comparison with Hall et al. (2009), Weißbach et al. (2013), Lambert et al. (2014), and Fizaine and Court (2016). With the present methodology it is not possible to calculate a final stage energy minimum ERR that would correspond to the boundaries of Feng et al. and Brockway et al. (2019). Both Feng et al. and Brockway et al. (2019) estimate final energy return per final energy input unit, whereas the exergy output from Eq. (2) is also at the final stage but the exergy inputs at the denominator correspond to useful exergy.

ERR Dynamics and Economic Growth

There has been no attempt so far to calculate the ’real’ exergy return ratio in the past for a given energy system or society. We cannot directly compare our ‘minimum required’ GExRR estimates from the previous section with real GExRR to assess societal exergy constraints. Nevertheless, our results suggest that as technical change enhances the conversion efficiency of primary-to-final and final-to-useful en/exergy processes, the societal minimum E/ExRR decreases irrespective of the boundary under consideration (Figs.  5, 6).Footnote 7 This could explain why the decline in GERR of oil and gas global productions identified by Court and Fizaine (2017) did not cause significant economic degrowth. In other words, improvements in en/exergy conversion efficiency between the 1940s and the 1970s (Figs.  3, 4) compensated for fossil energy system decreases in en/exergy surpluses, and allowed the global economy to grow at 3.0% per year between 1950 and 1970.

However, the rate of global economic growth slowed down after the 1970s.Footnote 8 Some may see this slowdown as a deficiency compared to the 1950–1970s time period; others may argue that we are reverting to the previous low growth trend. Either way, there is no consensus on what caused this global macroeconomic slowdown that is more apparent in more economically-developed countries compared to less economically-developed countries (Gordon 2015; Summers 2015). That greater efficiencies in en/exergy conversion have been harder to get since the mid-1970s (see Figs.  3, 4) could account for this global economic slowdown. While the minimum E/ExRR required for modern societies have been stable since the mid-1970s (Figs.  5, 6), actual E/ExRR prevailing for energy systems have decreased worldwide (Court and Fizaine 2017; Masnadi et al. 2018). This could have caused a tightening exergy constraint on economic growth. Further work is needed to estimate the actual exergy return ratios in that period to determine the validity of this hypothesis. Confirming whether actual ExRR decreased over this period would reinforce the high level of correlation between annual gains in the UK and Ghana’s aggregate exergy conversion efficiency and economic growth identified by Heun and Brockway (2019).

Finally, it is worth pointing out that the historical slowing down in exergy efficiency improvements are due to (i) the limits reached in thermal processes that are physically constrained by the Carnot limit, and (ii) the increasing prevalence of less efficient processes, such as air-conditioning, particularly in most economically-developed countries (Brockway et al. (2014) refer to this phenomenon as a ‘dilution effect’). Significant opportunities for exergy efficiency improvements exist at the end-use stage. One could therefore expect that future increases in aggregate exergy conversion efficiency would decrease the societal requirements for exergy return ratios. This could alleviate the net en/xergy constraint of society. But using currently untapped efficiency improvements would not necessarily mitigate the global energy resource and climate change dilemmas because of different and potentially large rebound effects [see Broberg et al. (2015), Brockway et al. (2017), and Bye et al. (2018)].

A Possible Correlation Between the Useful Exergy Return on Useful Exergy Investment of Society and Levels of Economic Development

Return ratios analyses based on exergy could overcome the problem posed by the absence of a correlation between the aggregate ERR of society and its level of economic development when comparing foraging, agrarian, and industrial societies. It is clear that one cannot directly relate higher levels of economic development with higher ERR because foraging and traditional farming societies can present similar ERR values to modern industrial societies. For instance, Smil (2017, pp. 36, 37) claimed that foraging societies have typical gathering returns around 10–20 final food-energy units per useful muscle-energy unit invested, similar to those of hunting large animals. Similarly, Smil (2017, pp. 44, 45) reported that many early agricultural societies yielded 15–20 final food-energy units per unit of useful muscle-energy investment. We could postulate that the overall level of economic development of a society is correlated with the discrepancy between the ‘actually prevailing’ and ‘minimum required’ useful exergy return on useful exergy investment of its energy system. This is visually represented in Fig.  7. Such a gap between required and prevailing useful exergy return per invested unit of useful exergy would correspond to an ‘available surplus of useful exergy’ that could act as a good proxy for the level of economic development. Further research is still needed to confirm this proposition.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Hypothetical evolutions of actually prevailing and minimum required useful exergy return on useful exergy investment. Source author (the curves are purely hypothetical and do not correspond to empirical data)

Summary and Perspectives

This article drew upon a concept devised by Debeir et al. (2013, pp. 51, 52) to show that several minimum exergy returns ratios can be calculated in relation to different levels of exergy conversion efficiency. Current data availability restricts estimation possibilities to the \(GExRR_{{{\text{min}},F/U}}\) of the European Union(EU)-15 countries, and the \(GExRR_{{{\text{min}},P/U}}\) of the USA, UK, Austria, Japan, and the world. Our results indicate a consistent sigmoid-shaped decline for all these minimum gross ExRR. Our methodology and the resulting \(GE/ExRR_{{{\text{min}}}}\) estimates suggest that, as technical change enhances the conversion efficiency of primary-to-final and final-to-useful exergy processes, the minimum ExRR required for society decreases irrespective of the boundary under consideration.

We discussed those estimates in relation to previous ERR studies. It appears that improvements in exergy conversion efficiency between the 1940s and the 1970s compensated for concurrent decreasing exergy surpluses of the fossil energy system. However after this period, while the minimum modern society ExRR requirement has stabilized, actual ExRR prevailing for energy systems have continue to globally decrease. This decrease in the growth of exergy conversion efficiency since the mid-1970s could have constrained economic growth and could partly explain the global economic slowdown of the last 40 years.

Overall, this article indicates that analyses of return ratios based on exergy and not energy might deliver more insightful outcomes compared to standard economic indicators such as GDP growth rates. Therefore, greater attention and investment should be directed toward estimating the final or useful exergy returns on useful exergy investment of energy systems. The calculation of such exergy return ratios would give a more precise understand of the effect of the exergy constraint on economic growth.