Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Defining cost-effective ways to improve ecosystem services provision in agroecosystems

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Review of Agricultural, Food and Environmental Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Mitigating climate change through the adoption of environmental-friendly agricultural practices also affects biodiversity and the provision of other non-marketed ecosystem services (hereafter, ES). In this paper, we investigate a method to identify cost-effective strategies to improve the provision of these ES. We model the link between agricultural practices and the provision of ES, to illustrate the general antagonism between agricultural production and the provision of non-marketed ES, as well as synergies among the latter. We run efficiency analyses on the simulated agroecological data to explore the interactions among ES and identify efficient bundles of ES. Improving the provision of non-marketed ES comes at a cost in terms of production. The bundle of ES provided by an alternative management option has an opportunity cost corresponding to the profit loss compared to the most profitable management option. We determine which strategy costs less to improve the provision of non-marketed ES: to adopt a given set of agroecological practices over the whole agricultural area, or to dedicate only a part of the landscape to the provision of the non-marketed ES. This result is helpful to determine if agroenvironmental policies should target large areas with uniform low requirements, or several smaller areas with higher environmental conditions. It can be used to determine cost-effective ways to mitigate climate change through agricultural practices reducing greenhouse gases emissions and increasing carbon storage in soil while maintaining other ES.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

All data is included in the Appendix.

Code availability

Available on request.

Notes

  1. We consider the composition of the landscape, but not its structure (spatial arrangement).

  2. The case of agricultural regions with heterogeneous soil quality will be considered in future research.

  3. The case of spatial interactions will be considered in future research.

  4. Small Agricultural Regions (SAR) correspond to homogeneous agricultural areas in France. The whole metropolitan area is divided into 713 SAR.

  5. Studying biological control is out of the scope of the present paper. It would require to include spatial spillovers and to consider the spatial structure of the landscape. Such an investigation is part of future research.

  6. This set is understood here as the space delimited by the linear combinations of all bundles. This definition of the production possibility set is somewhat particular, but we explain it in the “Efficient bundles of ES and associated management options” section below.

  7. This specification is invariant to translations, which allows us to translate the values for climate regulation and soil fertility in order to get rid of negative values.

  8. Data envelopment analysis determines the efficiency scores only for homogeneous landscapes. Heterogeneous landscapes only serve for determining the efficiency of homogeneous landscapes

  9. This is of course an approximation, as farmers may consider other criteria than profit (working time, tediousness, environmental preferences, etc.) or behave sub-optimally. We, however, consider the maximisation of profit as a rather good approximation of farmer’s behaviour for our research question, and it corresponds to the logic behind common agroenvironmental policies in the EU.

  10. This is also in line with the principles of agroenvironmental subsidies in the EU, which aim at compensating foregone profit, encompassing both reduced production and additional costs incurred by the agricultural practices.

  11. The current European budget for agro-environmental policies is too small to cover all the land concerned by their implementation. Over the period 2007–2012, only 25% of the agricultural area was covered by agro-environmental schemes in the EU (Duval et al., 2016), although maximising the provision of ES probably means enrolling a greater area.

  12. We thus run a directional data envelopment analysis which direction is given by the variation of non-marketed ES of each option with respect to the statu quo.

  13. Efficient bundles are the same as in the previous data envelopment analysis run, only the scores and composition of efficient benchmarks change, because we now consider differences to the statu quo and not absolute levels of ES.

  14. The model can run on multiple locations and time. We use it mostly considering a single piece of land at a given time in this paper, except for the sensitivity analysis of the agronomic context and for the dynamic computation of initial soil organic matter.

References

Download references

Funding

This paper is part of the flagship project API-SMAL (Agroecology and Policy Instruments for Sustainable Multifunctional Agricultural Landscapes) of the LabEx BASC, granted by the French National Research Agency (ANR) as part of the “Investissements d’Avenir” Programme (ANR-11-LABX-0034).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

BL designed the research, developed and run the model, interpreted the results, and contributed to the writing. VM designed the research, commented the model and results interpretation, and wrote the final draft of the paper. All authors approved the final manuscript and consent for publication.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Vincent Martinet.

Ethics declarations

Ethics declarations

Not applicable.

Consent to participate

Not applicable.

Consent to publication

Not applicable.

Competing interests

The authors declare no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A. Agroecological model: mathematical details

A.1 Notations

We denote a particular field/area by the index x and a particular time by the index t.Footnote 14 Management options are denoted by k. They correspond to a combination of agricultural practices. At each time, each field/area has a management option denoted by k(x,t).

Control variables correspond to agricultural practices. We consider the following practices:

  • The land use U = {G; C}, corresponding to the choice between grassland or cropland

  • pesticide intensity, with three levels: FTI = {0; 1; 2} (no pesticides, medium, or high use)

  • fertiliser intensity: F = {0; 1; 2; 3; 4} (from no fertiliser to high input)

  • presence of non-crop habitat such as grass or flower strips: NCH = {0; 1} (no; yes)

  • biomass input such as crop residues or cover crops: BI = {0; 1} (no; yes)

  • tillage regime: T = {0; 1} (conventional tillage; conservation/reduced tillage)

A management option k(x,t) is thus a combination within the set U × FTI × F × NCH × BI × T. Grassland options always coincide with no pesticide use, no fertiliser input, no NCH, no biomass input and no tillage. Considering all possible combinations, we obtain 122 management options.

There is a single state variable in the model, the soil organic matter SOMx(t).

A.2 Equations for ES assessment

Soil organic matter and nitrogen

The evolution of soil organic matter SOMx(t) is given by

$$ SOM_{x}(t+1) = SOM_{x}(t) - (m_{k(x,t)} + \lambda_{k(x,t)}) SOM_{x}(t) + I_{k(x,t)} $$
(2)

The mineralisation rate mk(x,t) and the organic matter leaching rate λk(x,t) depend on the management option k. So does the input of organic matter Ik(x,t), which is the sum of crop residues and non-harvested part of the plants.

The total available (mineral) nitrogen is

$$ N_{x,t} = \frac{c_3}{c_2} \cdot m_{k(x,t)} SOM_{x}(t) + f_{k(x,t)} + LN_{k(x,t)} $$
(3)

where c3 and c2 are conversion parameters to calculate the amount of nitrogen in soil organic matter, fk(x,t) is the mineral nitrogen from applied fertiliser, and LNk(x,t) is the mineral nitrogen stemming from livestock (if relevant).

Nitrogen emitted as nitrous oxide is proportional to total mineral nitrogen

$$ N_{Ax,t} = \beta N_{x,t} $$
(4)

with β is the rate of denitrification.

Crops take up part of the nitrogen available for plants, i.e. Nx,tNAx,t. Up to a certain amount N, nitrogen uptake by crops is proportional to the nitrogen available. Above this threshold, the nitrogen uptake slows gradually down as nitrogen available for plants increases.

$$ \left\{\begin{array}{ll} N_{Px,t} = \gamma (N_{x,t} - N_{Ax,t}) & \text{ for } N_{x,t} - N_{Ax,t} < N^{\ast} \\ N_{Px,t} = \gamma N^{\ast} + \frac{\gamma(N_{x,t} - N_{Ax,t}- N^{\ast})}{1 + \epsilon(N_{x,t} - N_{Ax,t} -N^{\ast})} & \text{ for } N_{x,t} - N_{Ax,t}\ge N^{\ast} \end{array} \right. $$
(5)

where γ is the nutrient use efficiency, and N and 𝜖 parameters determining the shape of this hyperbolic function.

Eventually, the remaining nitrogen NWx,t is leached to water bodies:

$$ N_{Wx,t} = N_{x,t} - N_{Ax,t} - N_{Px,t} $$
(6)

Greenhouse gases

Greenhouse gases come from 4 sources: emission of nitrous oxide NAx,t, changes in soil organic carbon stock ΔSOCx,t, fossil fuel burning FCk, and methane emitted by livestock methanek(x,t).

$$ GHG_{x,t}=g_1 c_4 N_{Ax,t} + FC_{k(x,t)} +{\Delta} SOC_{x,t} + g_2 . \text{methane}_{k(x,t)} $$
(7)

where g1 is the global warming potential of nitrous oxide and c4 the conversion parameter of nitrogen into nitrous oxide, and g2 is the global warming potential of methane.

The change in soil organic carbon is proportional to the change in soil organic matter, with c3 the carbon content of organic matter:

$$ {\Delta} SOC_{x,t} = SOC(t+1)-SOC(t) = c_3 (SOM_{x}(t+1) - SOM_{x}(t)) \\ $$
(8)

It is an indicator of carbon storage.

Plant growth - production

In cropland, potential yield Y1x,t depends nitrogen intake NPx,t and soil quality Qx

$$ Y_{1x,t} = Q_x (1-\exp^{-n_2 N_{Px,t}}) $$
(9)

with n2 the marginal effect of nitrogen on yield.

Non-crop habitats reduce cultivated area and thus the potential yield after accounting for the area really cultivated is

$$ Y_{2x,t} = Y_{1x,t}(1-e \cdot NCH_{k(x,t)}) $$
(10)

with e the proportion of the field dedicated to non-crop habitat.

Eventually, damage due to pests reduces yield, the final yield equals.

$$ Y_{3x,t} = Y_{2x,t}(1-D_{k(x,t)}) $$
(11)

Pests and damage Dk(x,t) are supposed to be proportional. Pests feed on crop, so that their carrying capacity depends on the yield, and thus damage is expressed as a fraction of yield. This fraction only depends on the intensity of pesticides.

Crop residues are proportional to crop yield.

$$ Y_{Rx,t} = \rho Y_{3x,t}(1 - BI_{k(x,t)}) $$
(12)

where BI is the binary associated to the crop residue restitution, which equals 1 if crop residues are left on the field.

Water quality

Water quality over the landscape is given by

$$ W_t= \min \{PL_{t} ; NL_{t} ; ML_{t} \} (1-w \sum\limits_x {NCH_{k(x,t)}}) $$
(13)

where PLt, NLt, and MLt are functions expressing pollutant loads in the landscape and w the reduction of pollutants export due to semi-natural elements (in percentage).

Water quality score of the landscape for pesticides:

$$ PL_{t} = \frac{{\sum}_x{FTI_{k(x,t)}} - \underline{PL}}{\overline{PL} - \underline{PL}} $$
(14)

with \(\underline {PL}\) and \(\overline {PL}\) minimum and maximum levels of pesticide load over the landscape. Here the minimal load is achieved when no farmer uses pesticides and maximal if every farmer uses pesticides.

Water quality score of the landscape for nutrients:

$$ NL_{t} = \frac{{\sum}_x {N_{Wx,t}} - \underline{NL}}{\overline{NL} - \underline{NL}} $$
(15)

Again, \(\underline {NL}\) and \(\overline {NL}\) describe the minimal and maximal nutrient loads of the landscape. \(\overline {NL}\) corresponds to a landscape with high levels of fertilisers, soil organic matter, and conventional tillage.

Water quality score of the landscape for organic matter:

$$ ML_{t} = \frac{{\sum}_x {ML_{x,t}} - \underline{ML}}{\overline{ML} - \underline{ML}} $$
(16)

with MLx,t = λk(x,t)SOMx(t) the amount of soil organic matter leached on field x. \(\underline {ML}\) and \(\overline {ML}\) describe the minimal and maximal organic matter loads of the landscape. \(\overline {ML}\) corresponds to a landscape with high levels soil organic matter and soil loss.

Pollination

Pollination source score

$$ PS_{x,t} = HF_{k(x,t)} \cdot HN_{k(x,t)} \cdot PM_{k(x,t)} $$
(17)

with HFk(x,t) the suitability in terms of floral resources, depending on the management k (land-use, pesticide intensity, non-crop habitat), HNk(x,t) the suitability in terms of nesting which depends only on management option k (land-use, pesticide intensity, non-crop habitat), and PMk(x,t) a multiplier representing the decreased mortality of pollinators in fields with medium intensity or no pesticides.

A.3 Parameter values

Table 3

Appendix B. Agronomic contexts

The following table summarises the characteristics of the 10 agronomic contexts that we considered, with the exogenous soil quality index Q (representing the potential yield) and the corresponding soil organic matter (SOM), defined as the equilibrium value reached by the dynamic Eq. 2 under the more profitable management option for each agronomic context.

Table 4

Note that, although the decreasing stock of soil organic matter has an opposite effect on yield than the increasing soil quality, the effect of soil quality dominates the impact of soil organic matter, so that the yield increases in a monotonous way across agronomic contexts.

Appendix C. Output of the simulations*

figure a
figure b
figure c

Appendix D. Efficient bundles of ecosystem services in all agronomic contexts

figure d

Appendix E. Output of the cost-effectiveness analysis

figure e
figure f
figure g

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Langlois, B., Martinet, V. Defining cost-effective ways to improve ecosystem services provision in agroecosystems. Rev Agric Food Environ Stud 104, 123–165 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s41130-023-00190-w

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s41130-023-00190-w

Keywords

Navigation