Advertisement

Erfolge und Probleme der modernen (Mainstream‑)Makroökonomik

  • Rüdiger BachmannEmail author
Aufsätze

Zusammenfassung

Nach einer Beschreibung und kritischen Würdigung des DSGE Paradigmas in der Makroökonomik werden neuere Entwicklungen der Makroökonomik in den Bereichen Daten, empirische Methoden, Modellklassen, Schocktypen sowie thematische Neuerungen vorgestellt. Abschließend wird auf fundamentalere Kritiken an der modernen Makroökonomik eingegangen und diese kritisch diskutiert.

Schlüsselwörter

DSGE Mikrofundierung Makroökonomik Kritik Pluralismus 

Successes and problems of modern (mainstream) macroeconomics

Abstract

After an exposition of the DSGE paradigm in macroeconomics, new developments in macroeconomics in terms of data, empirical methods, model classes, shock types, and themes are presented. In conclusion, more fundamental critiques of modern macroeconomics are discussed.

Keywords

DSGE Microfoundations Macroeconomics Critique Pluralism 

Notes

Danksagung

Mein herzlicher Dank gilt Benjamin Born für wertvolle Kommentare.

Literatur

  1. Acemoglu, D., Carvalho, V., Ozdaglar, A., & Tahbaz-Salehi, A. (2012). The network origins of aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica, 80(5), 1977–2016.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Aguiar, M., & Hurst, E. (2007). Measuring trends in leisure: the allocation of time over five decades. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(3), 969–1006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Aguiar, M., & Hurst, E. (2016). The Macroeconomics of Time Allocation. In J. Taylor & H. Uhlig (Hrsg.), Handbook of Macroeconomics (Bd. 2, S. 203–253). Amsterdam, Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  4. Aguiar, M., Bils, M., Charles, K., & Hurst, E. (2018). Leisure luxuries and the labor supply of young men. Princeton: Mimeo.Google Scholar
  5. Alesina, A., & Fuchs-Schündeln, N. (2007). Good bye Lenin (or not?): the effect of communism on people’s preferences. American Economic Review, 97(4), 1507–1528.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Angeletos, G.-M., & Lao, J. (2013). Sentiments. Econometrica, 81(2), 739–779.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Angeletos, G.-M., & Lian, C. (2016). Incomplete information in macroeconomics: accommodating frictions in coordination. In J. Taylor & H. Uhlig (Hrsg.), Handbook of macroeconomics (Bd. 2, S. 1065–1240). Amsterdam, Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  8. Antenucci, D., Cafarella, M., Levenstein, M., Ré, C., & Shapiro, M. (2014). Using social media to measure labor market flows. University of Michigan: Mimeo.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Arellano, C., Bai, Y., & Kehoe, P. (2018). Financial frictions and fluctuations in volatility. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report.Google Scholar
  10. Auerbach, A., & Gorodnichenko, Y. Y. (2012). Measuring the output responses to fiscal policy. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 4(2), 1–27.Google Scholar
  11. Bachmann, R. (2017). Zur aktuellen Pluralismusdebatte in der Ökonomik: Ansichten eines wohlwollenden Pluralismusskeptikers. Wirtschaftsdienst, 2017/12, 843–846.Google Scholar
  12. Bachmann, R. (2018). Ordoliberalism from the perspective of a US-trained macroeconomist. In M. Dold & T. Krieger: (Hrsg.), Ordoliberalism before, during and after the Eurozone crisis: between realpolitik and economic utopia. Im Erscheinen.Google Scholar
  13. Bachmann, R., & Bai, J. (2013). Politico-economic inequality and the comovement of government purchases. Review of Economic Dynamics, 16(4), 565–580.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Bachmann, R., & Bayer, C. (2013). Wait-and-see‘ business cycles? Journal of Monetary Economics, 60(6), 704–719.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Bachmann, R., & Bayer, C. (2014). Investment dispersion and the business cycle. American Economic Review, 104(4), 1392–1416.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Bachmann, R., & Elstner, S. (2015). Firm optimism and pessimism. European Economic Review, 79, 297–325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Bachmann, R., & Ma, L. (2016). Lumpy investment, lumpy inventories. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 48(5), 821–855.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Bachmann, R., & Moscarini, G. (2012). Business cycles and endogenous uncertainty. University of Notre Dame: Mimeo.Google Scholar
  19. Bachmann, R., & Sims, E. (2012). Confidence and the transmission of government spending shocks. Journal of Monetary Economics, 59(3), 235–249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Bachmann, R., & Zorn, P. (2018). What drives aggregate investment? Evidence from German survey data. CEPR-DP 12710.Google Scholar
  21. Bachmann, R., Bayer, C., Merkl, C., Seth, S., Stüber, H., & Wellschmied, F. (2017a). Worker Churn and Employment Growth at the Establishment Level. University of Notre Dame: Mimeo.Google Scholar
  22. Bachmann, R., Berg, T., & Sims, E. (2015). Inflation expectations and readiness to spend: cross-sectional evidence. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 7(1), 1–35.Google Scholar
  23. Bachmann, R., Caballero, R., & Engel, E. (2013a). Aggregate implications of lumpy investment: new evidence and a DSGE model. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 5(4), 29–67.Google Scholar
  24. Bachmann, R., Elstner, S., & Sims, E. (2013b). Uncertainty and economic activity: evidence from business survey data. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 5(2), 217–249.Google Scholar
  25. Bachmann, R., Hristov, A., & Elstner, S. (2017b). Surprise, Surprise – Measuring Firm-Level Investment Innovations. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 83, 107–148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Bachmann, R. und G. Braunberger (2018). Ökonomen im Gespräch (1): Rüdiger Bachmann über die moderne Makroökonomik, DSGE-Modelle und die Rolle von Theorie und Empirie in der VWL. Interview Fazit Blog, Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung online, 2. Mai 2012.Google Scholar
  27. Bai, Y., Rios-Rull, V., & Storesletten, K. (2017). Demand shocks as technology shocks. University of Rochester: Mimeo.Google Scholar
  28. Baker, S., Bloom, N., & Davis, S. (2016). Measuring economic policy uncertainty. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 131(4), 1593–1636.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Barsky, R., & Sims, E. (2011). News shocks and business cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics, 58(3), 273–289.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Barsky, R., House, C., & Kimball, M. (2007). Sticky price models and durable goods. American Economic Review, 97(3), 984–998.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Basu, S., & Bundick, B. (2017). Uncertainty shocks in a model of effective demand. Econometrica, 85(3), 937–958.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Basu, S., & House, C. (2016). Allocative and remitted wages: new facts and challenges for Keynesian models. In J. Taylor & H. Uhlig (Hrsg.), Handbook of macroeconomics (Bd. 2, S. 297–354). Amsterdam, Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  33. Beaudry, P., & Portier, F. (2006). Stock prices, news and economic fluctuations. American Economic Review, 96(4), 1293–1307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Beaudry, P., Galizia, D., & Portier, F. (2016). Putting the cycle back into business cycle analysis. NBER Working Paper 22825.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Berger, D., & Vavra, J. (2015). Consumption dynamics during recessions. Econometrica, 83(1), 101–154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Bernanke, B., Gertler, M., & Gilchrist, S. (1999). The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework. In J. Taylor & M. Woodford (Hrsg.), Handbook of macroeconomics. Amsterdam, Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  37. Blanchard, O. (2008). The state of macro. NBER-WP 14259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Blanchard, O. (2018). On the future of macroeconomic models. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 34(1–2), 43–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Blanchard, O., & Perotti, R. R. (2002). An empirical characterization of the dynamic effects of changes in government spending and taxes on output. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1329–1368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Blanchard, O., & Quah, D. (1989). The dynamic effects of aggregate demand and supply disturbances. American Economic Review, 79(4), 655–673.Google Scholar
  41. Bloom, N. (2009). The impact of uncertainty shocks. Econometrica, 77(3), 623–685.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Bloom, N. (2014). Fluctuations in uncertainty. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 28(2), 153–176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Boneva, L., Braun, R., & Waki, Y. (2016). Some unpleasant properties of loglinearized solutions when the nominal rate is zero. Journal of Monetary Economics, 84, 216–232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Born, B., & Pfeifer, J. (2014). Policy risk and the business cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics, 68, 68–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Bowles, S., & Carlin, W. (2017). A new paradigm for the introductory course in economics. VOXEU Portal. 7. September 2017Google Scholar
  46. Brunnermeier, M., Eisenbach, T., & Sannikov, Y. (2013). Macroeconomics with financial frictions: a survey. In Advances in economics and Econometrics, tenth world congress of the Econometric society (Bd. 2, S. 3–96). New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Burgess, S., Lane, J., & Stevens, D. (2000). Job flows, worker flows, and churning. Journal of Labor Economics, 18(3), 473–502.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Caballero, R. (2010). Macroeconomics after the crisis: time to deal with the pretense-of-knowledge syndrome. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24(4), 85–102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Caballero, R., Engel, E., & Haltiwanger, J. (1995). Plant-level adjustment and aggregate investment dynamics. Brookings Paper of Economic Activity 1995/2.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Calvo, G. (1983). Staggered prices in a utility-maximising framework. Journal of Monetary Economics, 12(3), 383–398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Carlstrom, C., & Fuerst, T. (1997). Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuations: a computable general equilibrium analysis. American Economic Review, 87(5), 893–910.Google Scholar
  52. Carroll, C., & Dunn, W. (1997). Unemployment expectations, jumping (S,s) triggers, and household balance sheets. In B. Bernanke & J. Rotemberg (Hrsg.), NBER macroeconomics annual (S. 165–229).Google Scholar
  53. Cavallo, A., Cruces, G., & Perez-Truglia, R. (2017). Inflation expectations, learning and supermarket prices: evidence from field experiments. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 9(3), 1–35.Google Scholar
  54. Challe, E., Matheron, J., Ragot, X., & Rubio-Ramirez, J. (2017). Precautionary saving and aggregate demand. Quantitative Economics, 8, 435–478.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Chari, V. (2010). Testimony before the committee on science and technology, subcommittee on investigations and oversight, U.S. house of representatives Google Scholar
  56. Chari, V., Kehoe, P., & McGrattan, E. (2007). Business cycle accounting. Econometrica, 75(3), 781–836.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. Chodorow-Reich, G. (2014). The employment effects of credit market disruptions: firm-level evidence from the 2008–9 finanical crisis. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(1), 1–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M., & Evans, C. (2005). Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy, 113(1), 1–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M., & Trabandt, M. (2018). On DSGE models. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 32(3), 113–140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. Clarida, R., Gali, J., & Gertler, M. (1999). The science of monetary policy: a new Keynesian perspective. Journal of Economic Literature, 37, 1661–1707.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Cochrane, J. (2017). The new-Keynesian liquidity trap. Journal of Monetary Economics, 92, 47–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  62. Coibion, O., & Gorodnichenko, Y. (2012a). Why are target interest rate changes so persistent? American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 4(4), 126–162.Google Scholar
  63. Coibion, O., & Gorodnichenko, Y. (2012b). What can survey forecasts tell us about information rigidities? Journal of Political Economy, 120(1), 116–159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. Comin, D., & Gertler, M. (2006). Medium-term business cycles. American Economic Review, 96(3), 523–551.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  65. Curdia, V., & Woodford, M. (2010). Credit spreads and monetary policy. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 42, 3–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  66. D’Acunto, F., Hoang, D., & Weber, M. (2016). The effect of unconventional fiscal policy on consumption expenditure. NBER Working Paper 22563.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  67. Davis, S., & van Wachter, T. (2012). Recessions and the costs of job loss. Brookings paper of economic activity 2012 (2).Google Scholar
  68. Davis, S., Faberman, J., & Haltiwanger, J. (2006). The flow approach to labor markets: new data sources and micro-macro links. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(3), 3–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  69. Davis, S., Faberman, J., Haltiwanger, J., Jarmin, R., & Miranda, J. (2010). Business volatility, job destruction, and unemployment. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2(2), 259–287.Google Scholar
  70. Davis, S., Faberman, J., & Haltiwanger, J. (2012). Labor market flows in the cross-section and over time. Journal of Monetary Economics, 59(1), 1–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  71. Davis, S., Haltiwanger, J., & Schuh, S. (1996). Job creation and destruction. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  72. De Carvalho, C. (2006). Heterogeneity in price stickiness and the real effects of monetary shocks. The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, Frontiers, 6(3), 1–58.Google Scholar
  73. Den Haan, W., Rendahl, P., & Riegler, M. (2017). Unemployment (fears) and deflationary spirals. Journal of the European Economic Association, 16(5), 1281.  https://doi.org/10.1093/jeea/jvx040.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  74. Doepke, M., & Tertilt, M. (2016). Families in macroeconomics. In J. Taylor & H. Uhlig (Hrsg.), Handbook of macroeconomics (Bd. 2, S. 1789–1891). Amsterdam, Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  75. Doepke, M., & Zillibotti, F. (2017). Parenting with style: altruism and paternalism in Intergenerational preference transmission. Econometrica, 85(5), 1331–1371.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. Doms, M., & Dunne, T. (1998). Capital adjustment patterns in manufacturing plants. Review of Economic Dynamics, 1(2), 409–429.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  77. Eichenbaum, M., Jaimovich, N., & Rebelo, S. (2011). Reference prices, costs and nominal rigidities. American Economic Review, 101(1), 234–262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  78. Erosa, A., & Ventura, G. (2002). On inflation as a regressive consumption tax. Journal of Monetary Economics, 49(4), 761–795.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  79. Fallick, B., & Fleischman, C. (2004). Employer-to-employer flows in the U.S. Labor market: the complete picture of gross worker flows. The federal reserve board discussion paper 2004–34.Google Scholar
  80. Farmer, R. (2016). Not keen on more chaos in macroeconomics. Roger Farmer Blog. 4. Oktober 2016Google Scholar
  81. Fernandez-Villaverde, J., Guerron-Quintana, P., Kuester, K., & Rubio-Ramırez, J. (2015). Fiscal volatility shocks and economic activity. American Economic Review, 105(11), 3352–3384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  82. Fernandez-Villaverde, J., Rubio-Ramirez, J., & Schorfheide, F. (2016). Solution and estimation methods for DSGE models. In J. Taylor & H. Uhlig (Hrsg.), Handbook of macroeconomics (Bd. 2, S. 527–724). Amsterdam, Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  83. Fuchs-Schündeln, N., & Hassan, T. (2016). Natural experiments in macroeconomics. In J. Taylor & H. Uhlig (Hrsg.), Handbook of macroeconomics (Bd. 2, S. 923–1012). Amsterdam, Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  84. Gabaix, X. (2011). The granular origins of aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica, 79, 733–772.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  85. Gabaix, X. (2014). A sparsity model of bounded rationality. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(4), 1661–1710.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  86. Gertler, M., & Karadi, P. (2011). A model of unconventional monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 58, 17–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  87. Ghironi, F. (2018). Macro needs micro. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 34(1–2), 195–218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  88. Gilchrist, S., Schönle, R., Sim, J., & Zakrajsek, E. (2018). Inflation dynamics during the financial crisis. American Economi Review, 107(3), 785.  https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20150248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  89. Gilchrist, S., Sim, J., & Zakrajsek, E. (2017). Uncertainty, financial frictions, and investment dynamics. New York University: Mimeo.Google Scholar
  90. Golosov, M., & Lucas, R. (2007). Menu costs and Phillips Curves. Journal of Political Economy, 115(2), 171–199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  91. Guimaraes, B., & Sheedy, K. (2011). Sales and monetary policy. American Economic Review, 101(2), 844–876.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  92. Gust, C., Herbst, E., Lopez-Salido, D., & Smith, M. (2017). The empirical implications of the interest-rate lower bound. American Economic Review, 107(7), 1971–2006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  93. Guvenen, F., & Smith, A. (2014). Inferring labor income risk and partial insurance from economic choices. Econometrica, 82(6), 2085–2129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  94. Guvenen, F., Ozkan, S., & Song, J. (2014). The nature of countercyclical income risk. Journal of Political Economy, 122(3), 621–660.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  95. Hansen, S., McMahon, M., & Prat, A. (2017). Transparency and deliberation within the FOMC: a computational linguistics approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 133(2), 801.  https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjx045.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  96. Hassler, J., Krusell, P., & Smith, A. (2016). Environmental macroeconomics. In J. Taylor & H. Uhlig (Hrsg.), Handbook of macroeconomics (Bd. 2, S. 1893–2008). Amsterdam, Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  97. Heathcote, J., & Perri, F. (2017). Wealth and volatility. Reserv Bank of Minneapolis: Mimeo.Google Scholar
  98. Heathcote, J., Perri, F., & Violante, G. (2010). Unequal we stand: an empirical analysis of economic inequality in the United States, 1967–2006. Review of Economic Dynamics, 13, 15–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  99. Heathcote, J., Storesletten, K., & Violante, G. (2009). Quantitative macroeconomics with heterogeneous households. Annual Review of Economics, 1, 319–354.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  100. Heise, A. (2016). Pluralismus in den Wirtschaftswissenschaften – Klärungen eines umstrittenen Konzepts. IMK Studies 47–2016.Google Scholar
  101. Ilut, C., & Schneider, M. (2014). Ambiguous business cycles. American Economic Review, 104, 2368–2399.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  102. Jaimovich, N., & Rebelo, S. (2009). Can news about the future drive the business cycle? American Economic Review, 99(4), 1097–1118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  103. Jaimovich, N., & Rebelo, S. (2010). Behavioral theories of the business cycle. Journal of the European Economic Association, 5(2–3), 361–368.Google Scholar
  104. Jaimovich, N., & Siu, H. (2009). The young, the old, and the restless: demographics and business cycle volatility. American Economic Review, 99(3), 804–826.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  105. Jones, C. (2016). The facts of economic growth. In J. Taylor & H. Uhlig (Hrsg.), Handbook of macroeconomics (Bd. 2, S. 3–67). Amsterdam, Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  106. Jorda, O. (2005). Estimation and inference of impulse responses by local projections. American Economic Review, 95(1), 161–182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  107. Justiniano, A., Primiceri, G., & Tambalotti, A. (2017). Credit supply and the housing boom. Northwestern University: Mimeo.Google Scholar
  108. Kaplan, G. (2012). Moving back home: insurance against labor market risk. Journal of Political Economy, 120(3), 446–512.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  109. Kaplan, G., & Menzio, G. (2016). Shopping externalities and self-fulfilling unemployment fluctuations. Journal of Political Economy, 124(3), 771–825.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  110. Kaplan, G., & Violante, G. (2014). A model of the consumption response to fiscal stimulus payments. Econometrica, 82(4), 1199–1239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  111. Kaplan, G., Moll, B., & Violante, G. (2018). Monetary policy according to HANK. American Economic Review, 108(3), 697–743.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  112. Keen, S. (2013). A monetary Minsky model of the great moderation and the great recession. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 86, 221–235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  113. Khan, A., & Thomas, J. (2008). Idiosyncratic shocks and the role of nonconvexities in plant and aggregate investment dynamics. Econometrica, 76(2), 395–436.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  114. Khan, A., & Thomas, J. (2013). Credit shocks and aggregate fluctuations in an economy with production heterogeneity. Journal of Political Economy, 121(6), 1055–1107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  115. Kiyotaki, N., & Moore, J. (1997). Credit cycles. Journal of Political Economy, 105(2), 211–248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  116. Kocherlakota, N. (2009). Modern macroeconomic models as tools for economic policy. Minneapolis Federal Reserve Bank Annual Report.Google Scholar
  117. Korinek, A. (2017). Thoughts on DSGE macroeconomics: matching the moment, but missing the point? Beitrag zur Konferenz „A Just Society“ zu Ehren von Joseph Stiglitz.Google Scholar
  118. Krugman, P. (2011). Credibility and monetary policy in a liquidity trap (Wonkish). The Conscience of a Liberal Blog. 18. März 2011Google Scholar
  119. Krusell, P., & Smith, A. (1998). Income and wealth heterogeneity in the macroeconomy. Journal of Political Economy, 106(5), 867–896.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  120. Kurmann, A., & Sims, E. (2017). Revisions in utilization-adjusted TFP and robust identification of news shocks. Drechsel University: Mimeo.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  121. Lian, C., & Ma, Y. (2018). Anatomy of corporate borrowing constraints. MIT: Mimeo.Google Scholar
  122. Lorenzoni, G. (2009). A theory of aggregate demand shocks. American Economic Review, 99(5), 2050–2084.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  123. Mackowiak, B., & Wiederholt, M. (2009). Optimal sticky prices under rational inattention. American Economic Review, 99(3), 769–803.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  124. Mackowiak, B., & Wiederholt, M. (2015). Business cycle dynamics under rational inattention. Review of Economic Studies, 82(4), 1502–1532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  125. Mackowiak, B., Mönch, E., & Wiederholt, M. (2009). Sectoral price data and models of price setting. Journal of Monetary Economics, 56, S78–S91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  126. Malmendier, U., & Nagel, S. (2011). Depression babies: do macroeconomic experiences affect risk-taking? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(1), 373–416.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  127. Malmendier, U., & Nagel, S. (2016). Learning from inflation experiences. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 131(1), 53–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  128. Mankiw, N. (2006). The macroeconomist as scientist and engineer. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(4), 29–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  129. Mankiw, N., & Reis, R. (2002). Sticky information versus sticky prices: a proposal to replace the new Keynesian Phillips curve. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4),1295–1328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  130. Martin, A., & Ventura, J. (2012). Economic growth with bubbles. American Economic Review, 102(6), 3033–3058.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  131. Mian, A., & Sufi, A. (2016). Who bears the cost of recessions? The role of house prices and household debt. In J. Taylor & H. Uhlig (Hrsg.), Handbook of Macroeconomics (Bd. 2, S. 255–294). Amsterdam, Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  132. Michaillat, P., & Saez, E. (2015). Aggregate demand, idle time, and unemployment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 130, 507–569.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  133. Midrigan, V. (2011). Menu costs, multiproduct firms and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica, 79(4), 1139–1180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  134. Mongey, S. (2017). Market structure and monetary non-neutrality. University of Chicago: Mimeo.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  135. Moscarini, G., & Postel-Vinay, F. (2012). The contribution of large and small employers to job creation in times of high and low unemployment. American Economic Review, 102(6), 2509–2539.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  136. Moscarini, G., & Postel-Vinay, F. (2017). The job ladder: inflation vs. reallocation. Yale University: Mimeo.Google Scholar
  137. Nakamura, E., & Steinsson, J. (2008). Five facts about prices: a reevaluation of menu cost models. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(4), 1415–1464.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  138. Petrosky-Nadeau, N., & Wasmer, E. (2013). The cyclical volatility of labor markets under frictional financial markets. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 5(1), 193–221.Google Scholar
  139. Piazzesi, M., & Schneider, M. (2016). Housing and macroeconomics. In J. Taylor & H. Uhlig (Hrsg.), Handbook of macroeconomics (Bd. 2, S. 1547–1640). Amsterdam, Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  140. Picketty, T. (2014). Capital in the 21 st century. Harvard: University Press.Google Scholar
  141. Ramey, V. (2011). Identifying government spending shocks: it’s all in the timing. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126, 1–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  142. Ramey, V. (2016). Macroeconomic shocks and their propagation. In J. Taylor & H. Uhlig (Hrsg.), Handbook of macroeconomics (Bd. 2, S. 71–162). Amsterdam, Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  143. Ramey, V., & Zubairy, S. (2014). Government spending multipliers in good times and in bad: evidence from 20th century historical data. University of California at San Diego: Mimeo.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  144. Ravn, M., & Sterk, V. (2017). Job uncertainty and deep recessions. Journal of Monetary Economics, 90, 125–141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  145. Ravn, M., & Sterk, V. (2018). Macroeconomic fluctuations with HANK & SAM: an analytical approach. University College London: Mimeo.Google Scholar
  146. Reis, R. (2018). Is something really wrong with macroeconomics? Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 34(1–2), 132–155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  147. Rendahl, P. (2016). Fiscal policy in an unemployment crisis. Review of Economic Studies, 83, 1189–1224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  148. Rodrick, D. (2015). Economics Rules: The Rights and Wrongs of the Dismal Science. New York City: W.W. Norton and Company.Google Scholar
  149. Rogerson, R., Shimer, R., & Wright, R. (2005). Search-theoretic models of the labor market: a survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 43, 959–988.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  150. Romer, P. (2015). The Clinical-Bench Science Distinction in Macro. Paul Romer Blog. 31. August 2015Google Scholar
  151. Romer, C., & Romer, D. (2004). A new measure of monetary shocks: derivation and implications. American Economic Review, 94, 1055–1084.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  152. Romer, C., & Romer, D. (2010). The macroeconomic effects of tax changes: estimates based on a new measure of fiscal shocks. American Economic Review, 100, 763–801.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  153. Rotemberg, J. (1982). Sticky prices in the United States. Journal of Political Economy, 90(6), 1187–1211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  154. Schmieder, J., van Wachter, T., & Heining, J. (2018). The costs of job displacement over the business cycle and its sources: evidence from Germany. Boston University: Mimeo.Google Scholar
  155. Sims, C. (1980). Macroeconomics and reality. Econometrica, 48, 1–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  156. Smets, F., & Wouters, R. (2003). An estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the Euro area. Journal of the European Economic Association, 1(5), 1123–1175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  157. Smets, F., & Wouters, R. (2007). Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: a Bayesian DSGE approach. American Economic Review, 97(3), 586–606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  158. Smith, N. (2017). The “cackling cartoon villain” defense of DSGE. Noahopinion Blog, 15. November 2017Google Scholar
  159. Song, J., Price, D., Guvenen, F., Bloom, N., & von Wachter, T. (2016). Firming up inequality. University of Minnesota: Mimeo.Google Scholar
  160. Taylor, J., & Uhlig, H. (2016). Handbook of macroeconomics. Bd. 2. Amsterdam, Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  161. Uhlig, H. (2005). What are the effects of monetary policy on output? Results from an agnostic identification procedure. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52(2), 381–419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  162. Vavra, J. (2014). Inflation dynamics and time-varying volatility: new evidence and an ss interpretation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(1), 215–258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  163. Wieland, J. (2017). Are Negative Supply Shocks Expansionary at the Zero Lower Bound? Journal of Political Economy.  https://doi.org/10.1086/701421.Google Scholar
  164. Winberry, T. (2016). Lumpy investment, business cycles, and stimulus policy. University of Chicago: Mimeo.Google Scholar
  165. Wolff, E. (2017). Household wealth trends in the United States, 1962 to 2016: has middle class wealth recovered? NBER Working Paper 24085.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  166. Woodford, M. (2003). Imperfect common knowledge and the effects of monetary policy. In P. Aghion, R. Frydman, J. Stiglitz & M. Woodford (Hrsg.), Knowledge, information, and expectations in modern macroeconomics: in honor of Edmund S. Phelps. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  167. Wren-Lewis, S. (2018). Ending the microfoundations hegemony. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 34(1–2), 55–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  168. Wright, R. (2018). On the future of macroeconomics: a new monetarist perspective. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 34(1–2), 107–131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  169. Wu, C., & Xia, F. (2016). Measuring the macroeconomic impact of monetary policy at the zero lower bound. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 48(2–3), 253–291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  170. Wu, C., & Zhang, J. (2017). A shadow rate new Keynesian model. University of Notre Dame: Mimeo.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© List-Gesellschaft e.V. 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.3026 Jenkins Nanovic Hall, Department of Economics, University of Notre DameNotre DameUSA

Personalised recommendations