1 Introduction

According to the International Energy Agency (IEA), the energy used for space heating accounts for 10% of the world energy consumption and consequently a significant share of CO2 emissions (International Energy Agency 2018). In Europe, heating and cooling are responsible for approximately 50% of total final energy consumption. District heating (DH) alone reduces more than 110 million tons of CO2 emission annually, representing 2.6% of the union’s annual CO2 emissions (DHC + Technology Platform 2020). Therefore, it is important to explore the potential of energy savings in this sector in order to mitigate climate change.

DH is characterized as high energy efficiency and low environmental pollution among different methods of heating, especially in the context of Nordic area, whereas, it is facing tougher competition in the market, since other technologies have achieved great improvement, and hence lower costs, while the price of DH keeps rising. Taking the Swedish DH market as an example, the price in 2017 was increased by almost 60% compared to the level in 2001, as shown in Fig. 1. By contrast, the costs for other heating options, such as heat pumps and wood pellet boilers, stay on a relatively low level. For instance, heat pumps normally have a coefficient of performance (COP) of 3–5. During the same period aforementioned, the price for electricity was 800–950 SEK/MWh including tax, which implies that for a heat pump system, the cost for producing 1 MWh heat is between 160 and 316 SEK.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Development of average DH price in Sweden 2001–2017 (Swedish Energy Agency)

A proper price model could give incentives to DH companies to upgrade the system and optimize the production in order to improve their competitiveness in the market (Li et al. 2015). In the meantime, an effective price model could also contribute to energy savings and CO2 emission reduction, as price is the most important factor affecting consumers’ behavior (Lin et al. 2017; Wang et al. 2018). Therefore, developing a proper price model is essential for encouraging heat demand response and enhancing sustainability of DH systems.

The objective of this work is to develop a new dynamic model based on the levelized cost of heat (LCOH) which can reflect the changes in production and fuel mix and eventually improve the competitiveness of DH. The contributions of this work to the research topic included:

  • Analyzing the challenges faced by both DH companies and consumers and identifying the drawbacks of the currently market-implemented price models;

  • Developing a novel dynamic price model based on LCOH;

  • Evaluating the impacts of the dynamic price model on consumers’ energy expense and their possible reaction.

The rest of the paper was organized as follows: Sect. 2 briefly reviewed the market-implemented price models of DH, highlighted the knowledge gap and discussed the requirements on new price models; in Sect. 3, a new dynamic price model was proposed based on LCOH and hourly heat demand and two market-implemented price models and three alternative heating solutions were also described, which were used to analyze the influences of different price models; the result of price model comparison and the analysis of different alternative solutions under different price models were presented in Sect. 4; and the conclusions were summarized in Sect. 5.

2 Issues regarding current price models of DH

2.1 Pricing mechanism of DH and price model structure

Pricing mechanism of DH has been reviewed in our previous work (Li et al. 2015). There are two general methods: the cost-plus pricing method, which is often used in regulated DH markets and the marginal-cost pricing method, which is commonly used in deregulated heating markets.

Cost-plus pricing calculates the price as the sum of costs to be recovered and reasonable profits for DH companies. It offers a number of advantages to sellers, buyers, and regulators, such as simplicity, flexibility, and ease of administration. However, a regulated market does not encourage DH companies to compete with other heating solutions (Johns et al. 1982; Lassource 2013). The marginal-cost method is widely used in the deregulated market. Marginal cost is the cost of one more unit of product, which, in this case, is the cost of generating one more unit of heat through DH (Rolfsman and Gustafsson 2002; Trygg et al. 2009). In principle, the marginal-cost method reflects the scarcity of resources and it is considered as the basic method for determining the price of DH. However, when a DH company sets the price according to its marginal costs, which in turn largely depend on variable costs, the company may gain less profit than intended. This may lead to a lower interest in investment and maintenance (Westin and Lagergren 2002; Hansson 2009; Ericsson 2009).

The cost of a DH system depends on different factors, such as (1) the investment cost when customer joins the network, (2) the cost of a distribution network, which is determined by the size of the DH network and thermal loads, and (3) the production cost of thermal energy (Song et al. 2015). Therefore, in reality, the heat price is normally divided into different components to cover these costs. A comprehensive survey has been carried out about the market-implemented price models in Sweden. 237 price models were investigated. Four typical components have been identified: (1) Fixed Connection Component (FCC) is the fee that a customer needs to pay each month for connecting to the network; (2) Flow Demand Component (FDC) is, in principle, charged on volume of hot water needed to deliver the heat that a customer consumes; (3) Load Demand Component (LDC) is charged to cover the investment and maintenance costs to maintain a certain level of heat capacity; and (4) Energy Demand Component (EDC) is charged to cover the fuel cost of heat production. In general, setting price based on marginal cost is only used to determine the component of EDC; and LDC and EDC account for more than 90% of the total expense of consumers. Among those four components, FCC and LDC can be considered as fixed costs while FDC and EDC can be considered as variable costs.

According to the survey, the investigated price models do not really reflect the production cost, which is largely dependent on the peak demand. In order to improve the competitiveness of DH, some large companies have been reforming their price models and LDC receives the most attention. The purpose of emphasizing the importance of LDC is to encourage consumers to change their behavior and reduce the peak demand (Song et al. 2017). As a result, DH companies can reduce investments in peak capacity and avoid using expensive fuels, which would, consequently, lead to a lower heat price.

2.2 Pricing dilemma

  1. (1)

    Fixed cost versus variable cost

One of the financial risks faced by DH companies is the high capital investment. A large share of operating costs is related to investment and maintenance cost on the DH system and does not vary according to the production; whereas, the heat production fluctuates largely over a year and between different years due to the variation of demand. Therefore, DH companies usually prefer a high share of fixed components in their price models to reduce such risks and streamline the cash flow. However, DH price model has moved toward a more consumer-oriented approach since the deregulation of DH market. Opposite to DH companies, consumers always prefer a high share of energy cost (variable cost), which facilitates energy conservation measures and increases price transparency. This means that the shares between fixed and variable costs in price models should be carefully determined to balance the need of producers and preference of consumers.

  1. (2)

    Historic consumption data versus current heat demand

The level of LDC is usually determined according to the historical consumption data. However, the climatic condition changes year by year, resulting in a dynamic change of heat demand. Even though a correction based on the normal year can be introduced, there could still be a big deviation between the predicted and actual heat demand, since the demand is not totally depending on the yearly degree-day.

  1. (3)

    Pricing transparency versus limited information accessibility

To ensure that the heat price on the wholesale market reflects the dynamics of supply and demand, market participants should be able to have access to the information on production and consumption. On the retail level, transparent information is important for consumers to choose the supplier as well as manage their energy consumption. Even though the legislative package in Europe plans various dispositions for consumer rights (Lassource 2013), and regulations have increasingly highlighted the importance of transparency for promoting trust and reducing complaints, there has been little work done to improve the transparency in DH system. DH companies keep claiming that they are using the marginal costs to determine heat prices, yet neither purchase price for fuels nor the production status in DH system is made available for consumers.

2.3 Criteria for new price model

Based on the discussion above, the DH price model should be able to:

  • Reflect the dynamic production cost.

  • Motivate consumers to reduce heat consumption, especially during the peak period of time.

  • Be predictable.

  • Be transparent and easy to understand.

To fulfill these criteria, a dynamic price model based on the prediction of system heat demand becomes more attractive, since it allows DH companies to predict the peak load more accurately and estimate the extra cost for covering the peak load. By charging a higher price for the peak, it even gives customers higher incentive to reduce the peak demand. Since heat production in Swedish DH systems is mainly from CHPs, a dynamic DH price model can also relate to the dynamic electricity price in a better way. Furthermore, a dynamic price model can improve the transparency, which has been proved to be an effective way to achieve higher energy savings in the domestic sector. By understanding the price model, customers can change their behaviors in order to reduce the heat consumption and save the cost.

3 Methodology

In this paper, a dynamic price model was proposed based on LCOH. To estimate the capital cost and operation and maintenance costs (O&M), a real DH company in Sweden was used as a case study. In order to consider the change in production methods, the heat demand was predicted by using neural networks. The proposed model was also compared two market-implemented price models (Song et al. 2015) to demonstrate its advantages. In addition, the impacts of price models on selecting  alternative heating solutions were investigated, including heat pumps and direct electric heating.

3.1 Proposed dynamic price model based on LCOH

The levelized cost of energy is a popular methodology for evaluating the economic competitiveness of electricity generation technology over the long term (International Energy Agency 2015). Different from the marginal cost model, in which a fixed cost is charged on a period basis, the levelized cost approach uses the average cost of energy production over the lifetime of energy plant, which must take all fixed (investment, operations and maintenance, and decommissioning) and variable (fuel) costs into consideration. In the LCOH-based price model, the fixed cost is already integrated with variable cost. There is no need to include other fixed components. The main advantage of the LCOH-based method lies in its flexibility and transparency, while the biggest challenge for calculating LCOH is how to estimate the total heat production during the lifetime. LCOH-based prices are usually calculated on an hourly basis:

$${\text{LCOH}} = {\text{LCOH}}_{\text{fuel}} + {\text{LCOH}}_{\text{TIC}} + {\text{LCOH}}_{{{\text{O}}\& {\text{M}}}}$$
(1)
$${\text{LCOH}}_{\text{TIC}} + {\text{LCOH}}_{{{\text{O}}\& {\text{M}}}} = \frac{{\mathop \sum \nolimits_{t} \left( {{\text{TIC}}_{t} + {\text{FOM}}_{t} + {\text{VOM}}_{t} } \right) \times \left( {1 + r} \right)^{t} }}{{\mathop \sum \nolimits_{t} {\text{HEAT}}_{t} }}$$
(2)

where LCOHfuel is the fuel cost to produce one unit of heat, TIC is the total investment cost, FOM and VOM are fixed operation and maintain cost and variable operation and maintain cost, respectively, r is the interest rate, t is the life span, and \(\mathop \sum \limits_{t} {\text{HEAT}}_{t}\) is the total heat production during the life time.

For different production methods (bio-oil boilers, oil boilers, heat pumps, etc.), LCOH varies. When more than one production methods are used, the overall LCOH at a specific moment includes all costs for all methods in use and could be calculated via combining LCOH for each method according to their heat productions:

$${\text{LCOH}} = \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{n} \left( {{\text{LCOH}}_{i} \frac{{{\text{Heat}}_{i} }}{{\sum {\text{Heat}}_{i} }}} \right)$$
(3)

where n is the total number of methods for heat production and i means the ith method.

Since the CHP plant produces heat and power simultaneously, the fuel consumption should be allocated between electricity and heat production.

$$F_{t}^{E} = \left( {1 - \alpha_{h} } \right) \times {\text{Fuel cost}}$$
(4)
$$F_{t}^{H} = \alpha_{h} \times {\text{Fuel cost}}$$
(5)

where \(F_{t}^{E} {\text{and }}F_{t}^{H}\) are the fuel costs for the electricity and heat productions, respectively, and αh is the cost allocation factor.

There are a number of principles used to allocate joint costs between heat and power for CHP plants (Sjödin and Henning 2004; Tereshchenko and Nord 2015). The following three methods have been tested in this work:

M-1: Allocating the costs in proportion to the amounts of generated heat and electricity. This method is widely used due to the simplicity and accessibility of measurements. Energy taxation in Sweden also uses this method as the ground on CHP plants. But it does not consider the energy quality difference between heat and electricity, in other words, it tends to allocate less fuel on electricity and more on heat. Since the efficiency of CHP plant to produce electricity and heat was assumed to be same in this study, the total fuel costs can be allocated between heat and electricity according to the electricity-to-heat ratio.

M-2: Allocating the costs in proportion to the exergy of the generated heat and electricity. This method is based on the second law of thermodynamics, which reflects the quality of electricity and heat. Since electricity is better than heat in quality, this method will normally allocate a higher share of costs on electricity generation. The exergy of electricity is equal to its energy, while the exergy of heat can be calculated as:

$${\text{Exergy}}_{H} = {\text{Energy}}_{H} \times \frac{{T_{H} - T_{\text{a}} }}{{T_{H} }}$$
(6)

where TH is the temperature of supply water (K) and Ta is the ambient temperature (K).

M-3: Allocating all costs on heat production with the deduction of the income of selling electricity. Since the deregulation of energy market, the electricity price depends totally on bidding in the market, while energy companies maintain autonomy on price of heat. In this method, electricity is considered as by-product. All fuel cost is allocated on heat, and after deducting the income from selling electricity from the total cost, the heat price can be determined.

As aforementioned, the fuel allocation should only be applied to the fuel used in cogeneration process of heat and electricity. In practice, CHP plants are not always operated in the cogeneration mode. As shown in Fig. 2, when heat demand reaches a high level, the turbine is bypassed to produce more heat. The fuel used in the bypass process should not be divided between heat and electricity, as it is used only for heat production (HO). In order to accurately allocate the cost between heat and electricity production, heat produced in the CHP system can be further divided into heat produced from the cogeneration mode (H_CHP) and heat produced from heat-only mode (H_HO). Meanwhile, some heat can be recovered from Flue Gas Condensation (H_FGC) at high heat demand. Such heat is usually released to the ambient and not included in the heat production of CHP. Therefore, the fuel cost of H_FGC was considered negligible in the calculation.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Energy flow in a CHP system

LCOH is tightly related to the level of heat demand, which determines the methods used for heat production. Once the heat demand is known, the involved heat production methods are known, and then LCOH could be calculated by Eq. 3.

The calculation of LCOH in this paper was based on a real DH system, which consists of a CHP plant, a biomass boiler, and a bio-oil boiler. Detailed input data and assumptions are listed in Table 1.

Table 1 Input data and assumptions

Figure 3 shows the total heat production and the breakdown for each specific method. CHP is the primary method, which is usually scheduled to shut down for maintenance for 1 month in summer, while biomass boiler is used as an alternative. Since the oil price is high, the oil boiler is only running during very cold days, when the production from other methods cannot cover the total heat demand.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Heat productions from different plants

3.2 Prediction of heat demand

An accurate prediction of heat demand is important in the calculation of LCOH. In our previous work (Ma et al. 2014; Xie et al. 2017), a model based on Elman neural networks (ENN) is developed to predict the heat demand. The model of Elman neural network is presented as follows:

$$x_{1} \left( k \right) = f\left[ {w^{1} u\left( {k - 1} \right) + w^{c1} x_{c1} \left( k \right)} \right]$$
(7)
$$x_{i} \left( k \right) = f\left[ {w^{i} x_{i - 1} \left( {k - 1} \right) + w^{ci} x_{ci} \left( k \right)} \right],\quad i = 2,3, \ldots ,s$$
(8)
$$x_{ci} \left( k \right) = x_{i} \left( {k - 1} \right),\quad i = 2,3, \ldots ,s$$
(9)
$$y\left( k \right) = g\left[ {w^{s + 1} x_{s} \left( k \right)} \right]$$
(10)

where s is number of hidden layers, \(u\left( k \right)\) is the input of the model, \(x_{ci} \left( k \right)\) and \(x_{i} \left( k \right)\) are the output of context layer i and hidden layer i, \(y\left( k \right)\) is the output of output layer, \(w^{1}\) is the connection weight matrix between the input layer and the hidden layer 1, \(w^{i}\) is the connection weight matrix between the hidden layer i and the hidden layer (i−1), \(w^{n + 1}\) is the connection weight matrix between the hidden layer n and the output layer, respectively, \(w^{ci}\) is the connection weight matrix between the hidden layer i and the context layer i. \(f\left( \cdot \right)\) and \(g\left( \cdot \right)\) are transfer functions, \(f\left( \cdot \right)\) is usually sigmoid, tangent sigmoid, or logarithm sigmoid transfer function and \(g\left( \cdot \right)\) is usually a linear transfer function. More detailed information about the developed model is given in (Ma et al. 2014; Xie et al. 2017). Comparing the predicted heat demand with the operation statistics obtained from the DH company, the overall mean absolute percentage error (MAPE) was 4.43%, which indicated that the prediction model worked well in this case.

$${\text{MAPE}} = \frac{1}{n}\mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{n} \frac{{\left| {y_{i} - y_{\text{pi}} } \right|}}{{y_{i} }} \times 100\%$$
(11)

where \(y_{i}\) is the actual heat demand value, \(y_{\text{pi}}\) is the corresponding heat demand prediction value, and \(n\) is the prediction step length.

3.3 Market-implemented price models

Different from the LCOH-based price model, DH companies use other models. In this work, two market-implemented models identified from the previous price model survey (Song et al. 2015) were included for comparison purpose.

3.3.1 Seasonal price model (Old-PM)

Seasonal Price model has been widely adopted. The LDC in this model is based on customers’ highest measured daily average demand in 1 year, and the EDC consisted of two levels of seasonal energy price (higher during winter and lower during summer) to differentiate consumptions in different periods.

Under this model, a customer’s DH cost is expressed as:

$$E = P_{{{\text{energy}} . {\text{w}}}} \times C_{\text{w}} + P_{{{\text{energy}} . {\text{s}}}} \times C_{\text{s}} + P_{\text{load}} \times L_{\text{peak}}$$
(12)

where Penergy.w is the energy price during winter season, Penergy.s is the energy price during summer season, Cw is customer’s winter DH consumption, Cs is customer’s summer DH consumption, Pload is the load demand price, and Lpeak is customer’s peak demand (daily).

3.3.2 Subscription price model (New-PM)

Subscription price model is a newly emerged price model. Similar to the seasonal price model, the LDC in this model is also based on the peak demand of customers, except it is on hourly basis instead of daily basis. The EDC is based on customers instant demand level. The DH company suggests a subscription level in proportion to the customer’s peak load demand, and customers pay a relatively lower price (so-called base price) for their heat consumption below the subscription level, but a relatively higher price for the part above the subscription level (so-called peak price).

A customer’s cost is calculated as:

$$E = P_{{{\text{energy}} . {\text{b}}}} \times C_{\text{b}} + P_{{{\text{energy}} . {\text{p}}}} \times C_{p} + P_{\text{load}} \times L_{\text{peak}} \times \alpha$$
(13)

where Penergy.b is base energy price, Penergy.p is peak energy price, Cb is the heat consumption below the subscription level, Cp is customer’s heat consumption above the subscription level, Pload is load demand price, Lpeak is customer’s peak demand (hourly), α is the subscription level, which equals to the share of base load plant’s capacity in comparison with the total capacity in the DH system.

Both Old-PM and New-PM consist of a LDC and an EDC; and the specific price levels for each model are listed in Table 2. Neither Old-PM nor New-PM is dynamic price model. To calculate the hourly price for the implemented models, 638 customers’ consumption data were collected from the local energy company. Each customer’s hourly costs on EDC were calculated according to the energy consumption and the energy price level during that hour. The annual cost on LDC was first calculated based on the customer’s peak demand and the load price level, and then evenly distributed into each hour of the year. The average hourly DH price then was calculated by adding up each customer’s hourly cost on both EDC and LDC and then divided by the total DH consumption during that hour.

Table 2 Price levels of price models in use

3.4 Different alternative heating solutions to DH

It is more likely for a customer to take action if the cost increases significantly. In order to assess the impacts of price models on the selection of alternative heating solutions, an industry customer facing significant cost increase in the price model restructuring process was selected according to our previous work (Song et al. 2017). The annual heating cost of the selected customer was calculated by applying different price models.

Three alternative solutions to lower the energy expense were considered in this study: using DH and direct electrical heating (DEH) to provide the base and peak heating demands; using ground source heat pump (HP) and DH to provide base and peak demands, and using HP and DEH to provide base and peak demands; Fig. 4 shows the selected customer’s consumption profile for different alternatives. The annual cost of each solution is the sum of DH cost, electricity cost, and annual investment cost for HP and DEH installation.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Consumption profile of different heating solutions

The capacity of HP was dimensioned to achieve the optimal annual cost. It was assumed that the capital investment of heat pump was 15,000 SEK/kW (Björk et al. 2013), the lifespan was 20 years, and the interest rate was 5% (Statistics Sweden & the Swedish Central Bank). The annual investment cost of HP could be calculated by Eq. 14; the annuity of investment was 1990 SEK/(kW year). The seasonal COP of heat pump was assumed to be 3.5 and the price of electricity was 840 SEK/MWh (Statistics Sweden & Swedish Energy Agency). The cost of implementing direct electrical heating equipment was negligible compared to life span of 20 years.

$$C_{\text{annual}} = \frac{{I_{\text{cap}} \times (1 + a)^{L} }}{L}$$
(14)

where \(C_{\text{annual}}\) is the annual investment cost per installed capacity of heat pump, \(I_{\text{cap}}\) is capital investment of heat pump, a is interest rate of capital, and L is life span of heat pumps.

4 Results

4.1 Comparison of proposed and implemented price models

Figure 5 shows the LCOH with different levels of heat demand. In general, there was a clear drop; no matter which method is used for allocating the fuel cost for CHP. The drop happened at the moment when FGC was involved in heat production. Since the fuel cost in FGC was negligible, when the total cost remained the same, while more heat were produced, it leaded to a lower cost per unit of heat production. For M-1 and M-2, LCOH went up when the turbine was bypassed, due to more fuel allocated for heat production as electricity production was lowered. For M-3, due to the high fraction of the capital cost in LCOH, H_CHP has a higher cost than H_HO. Therefore, when the turbine was bypassed, heat production in the heat-only cycle increased, whereas, the production in the CHP cycle decreased, resulting in decrease of LCOH.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Variation of LCOH with different levels of heat demand

Figure 6 shows the variation of heat demand and price from different price models through 1 year time. In general, LCOH-based models reflect the variation of heat demand in a better way and effectively cover the high cost at the peaks. It was also interesting to see that the prices at low heat demands, for example in summer, were still quite high for the proposed dynamic models; since CHP was shut down during summer and the biomass boiler was used instead, the high fuel price resulted in a high DH price.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Heat price from different price models at different heat demands

For the two market-implemented price models, the high price during summer time was majorly due to the fixed LDC, which was not allocated according to the energy consumption but based on time.

Table 3 compares the characters of different price models. In general, Old-PM is simple to understand. As the seasonal based EDC accounts for the major part of the heat price, it can also reflect the dynamic production cost. For New-PM, the average price depends largely on the peak demand of customers. Therefore, it can effectively motivate customers to reduce the peak load. Yet, such a model is difficult to understand and is less transparent. For the price models based on LCOH, the price varies with the production cost, which is further determined by the demand; hence, it can motivate customers to reduce the heat consumption, especially during the peak time. It is easier to understand, but the complexity of calculation results in uncertainties of the cost.

Table 3 Characters of different price models

4.2 Influences of price models on heat expenses

To demonstrate the influence of price models on the heat expense of customers, the expenses were calculated for all types of building (office & school, commercial buildings, hospital & social service buildings, and industry buildings) under different price models. Results show quite similar trend. Therefore, a user of multifamily house was chosen as an example. Figure 7 shows the heat demand and hourly heat expense. In general, the expense changed along with heat demand regardless of price model. Comparatively, the expense under the dynamic models varies in a more obvious way than under the two market-implemented price models (Old-PM and New-PM). The proposed dynamic price models resulted in a higher cost than the market-implemented price models when the demand was at a higher level, and the difference increased along with the peak demand. Nevertheless, in most of the time, the expenses under dynamic price models were lower than those under the market-implemented price models. It implies the proposed dynamic model could have a bigger potential in motivating the customers to reduce the peak load.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Heat demand and expenses of a multifamily house

4.3 Influences of price models on alternatives of DH

The costs of using DH only and other three alternatives were calculated based on the consumption data of the same customer (industry buildings). The annual costs of each solution under different price models were shown in Fig. 8. For the two market-implemented price models (Old-PM and New-PM), installing heat pump to supply base demand and using district heating to cover the peak demand was not an attractive solution, since it only marginally reduced the annual cost (by 4% and 1%, respectively), but exposed the consumer to a higher risk due to the extra investment cost. Reducing the peak demand of DH with direct electrical heating (DEH) can reduce the cost by 31% and 39%, respectively, under these two models, which makes it the second best solution under both implemented models. Installing a heat pump and using DEH to cover the peak demand was the best alternative, which can reduce the annual cost by 35% and 46%, respectively. For the dynamic model based on LCOH, since a much lower heat price could be obtained, the alternatives do not show as much saving as under the market-implemented price models. Using DEH to cover the peak demand of DH was instead the most economical alternative. Moreover, installing a heat pump and using direct electrical heating to cover the peak was not lucrative at all.

Fig. 8
figure 8

Cost comparison between Old-PM, New-PM, M-1, M-2 and M-3 for different alternative solutions (DH district heating cost, HP investment for heat pump, El electricity cost)

5 Conclusion

District heating (DH) companies are facing several challenges in the current heat market. In this paper, a novel dynamic price model based on the levelized cost of heat (LCOH) was proposed in order to improve the competence of district heating. The proposed model carefully considered the capital cost, operation and maintenance cost as well as other costs. The following conclusions can be drawn:

  • The prices based on LCOH can be lower than those from the market-implemented price models. The variation of LCOH followed the fluctuation of heat demand, and therefore, the proposed model can demonstrate the production cost more accurately, whereas, the complexity of the proposed model, for example to allocate the cost between heat and electricity in a CHP plant, might hinder its feasibility. Meanwhile, the dynamic operation hours of equipment and unpredictable maintenance cost could also introduce large deviations in the calculation of LCOH.

  • At peak demands, the dynamic model can result in an even higher hourly price than the market-implemented price models, which implies that the dynamic model may have a bigger potential to motivate consumers to reduce the peak load.

  • Price model reforming could lead to a significant change in the expense of consumers and affect the selection of alternatives to DH by investigating the influences of price models on the heat expenses of consumers; it was found that installing a heat pump and using direct electric heating (DHE) to cover the peak demand and using DEH to cover the peak demand of DH were the most economical alternatives under the market-implemented price models and the proposed dynamic price model, respectively.