Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Market power, social welfare, and efficiency in the Peruvian microfinance

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Economia Politica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study quantifies the social welfare loss caused by market power in Peru’s regulated microfinance industry and analyzes its effect on microfinance institutions’ (MFIs) efficiency from 2003 to 2019. We estimate the efficiency-adjusted Lerner index as a measure of market power and obtain efficiency scores via cost and profit stochastic frontiers estimation using data from a wide panel of MFIs. Additionally, to analyze the effect of market power on the MFI’s efficiency, we estimate a fixed effects model with instrumental variables to correct the endogeneity problem. The results show that the welfare loss due to market power in Peru’s regulated microfinance industry has increased from 0.12% of GDP in 2003 to 0.27% in 2019. It is also found that market power positively affects Peruvian MFIs’ efficiency. Therefore, reducing market power leads to a welfare gain by lowering the social welfare loss (Harberger’s triangle) and a welfare loss due to decreased efficiency in MFIs. However, we find that reducing market power leads to a positive net effect on social welfare due to greater welfare gain than loss.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Source: SBS. Own elaboration

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

The datasets generated during and/or analyzed during the current study are available upon reasonable request to the corresponding author.

Notes

  1. Non-Governmental Organizations (NGOs) with microcredit programs and cooperatives specialized in microfinance are also part of the Peruvian microfinance system. The most important of these entities voluntarily report their financial information to the MIX Market database. According to this information, these institutions were responsible for 6% of the total microloans placed by the Peruvian microfinance system in 2019. Given their reduced participation in the national microcredit supply, our analysis only considers regulated MFIs.

  2. See the Appendix for this demonstration.

  3. For a presentation of this literature, see the paper by Fall et al. (2018).

  4. Resolution SBS 1276–2002, which approved the regulations for the entry of MFIs into the Lima market.

  5. Superintendencia de Bancos, Seguros y Administradoras de Fondos de Pensiones (SBS) (2003).

  6. Legislative Decree 1028/2008, which amends Article 290 of Law 28677, General Law on the Financial System and the Insurance System and Organic Law on the Superintendency of Banking, Insurance, and Private Pension Funds Administrators.

  7. It should be noted that we estimate an alternative profit frontier that, unlike the standard one, takes into account that financial intermediation institutions (in this case, MFIs) do not act in a perfectly competitive market, and therefore, the price of their product it is not given; if not, they can establish it by fixing their output. Consequently, we include output and input prices as exogenous variables in the profit frontier (Berger & Mester, 1997; Humphrey & Pulley, 1997). Under this assumption, we use profits as an endogenous variable and the same explanatory variables as in the cost frontier case.

  8. For a detailed presentation on stochastic frontiers, see Kumbhakar and Lovell (2003).

  9. We follow the intermediation approach of Benston et al. (1982), which defines financial intermediaries as firms that produce loans from the combination of the following inputs: loanable funds, labor, and physical infrastructure. This approach defines the cost concept broadly because it includes financial and operating costs within the total cost. In addition, in the particular case of MFIs, given that they finance volatile economic activities, their loan portfolios are exposed to greater credit risk, which implies the constitution of high provisions for expected losses for the entity. Although provisions are not an outflow of resources, they reduce the entities’ capital in accounting terms, constituting a cost for them, so the credit risk cost must be considered part of the total cost. Finally, we measure production as the monetary value of total loans.

  10. The definition of the variables used in the cost and profit frontiers are detailed in Table 6. Likewise, Table 7 shows the descriptive statistics of these variables. Finally, the estimates of the cost and profit frontiers are described in Tables 8 and 9, respectively.

  11. In the case of negative profits, we use the following estimation: \({TP}_{AD}=(profits) (PROFIT\_EFFI)\).

  12. See Sect. 2 for details.

  13. Our results are robust with different specification of lags. We use clustered standard errors.

  14. See Table 10: First stage of IV with fixed effects estimation.

  15. The exclusion restriction is difficult to test. The direct influence of these instruments (LIAD,t−7, LIAD,t−8, LIAD,t−9, LIAD,t−10, LIAD,t−11, LIAD,t−12) on contemporary efficiency (EFFIt) is unlike because market power from 7 months ago or even further back cannot influence EFFIt or its influence would be negligible. In any case, the influence of these instruments would be indirect through contemporary market power (LIAD,t).

  16. At the outset, we had data for 44 MFIs: thirteen CMACs, two banks specializing in microfinance, thirteen CRACs, and fourteen EDPYMEs. However, it was decided to exclude those entities that were taken over at an early stage, as they provided only a small number of observations and represented less than 3% of total loans in the Peruvian microfinance market. This left a panel of 37 MFIs.

  17. For the Mexican banking sector, Solís and Maudos (2008) detected a social welfare loss representing, on average, 0.34% of GDP from 1993–2005. In the study by Maudos and Fernández de Guevara (2007) on 15 EU banks from 1993–2002, the average welfare loss was 0.49% of GDP for this group of countries. Although these values are not comparable with those we estimate for the Peruvian microfinance industry, they are referential for our analysis.

  18. There are no prior estimations of welfare losses caused by cost and profit inefficiency for the microfinance industry. However, Solís and Maudos (2008) presented such estimates for the Mexican banking industry. They reported welfare losses associated with cost and profit inefficiency, as a percentage of GDP, of 0.02% and 0.07%, respectively. Maudos and Fernández de Guevara (2007) found that, for 15 EU countries, the welfare loss associated with cost inefficiency totaled 0.35% of the GDP of this group of European countries.

  19. We use the xtivreg2 command in Stata to estimate the fixed effects model with instrumental variables. See Schaffer (2005) for more details on the command.

  20. See Baum et al. (2007) for more details on these diagnostic tests for the fixed effects model with instrumental variables.

  21. The estimates of this new alternative profit frontier are described in Table 11.

  22. The main regression table is available on request.

References

  • Aguilar, G., & Portilla, J. (2020). Determinants of market power in the Peruvian regulated microfinance sector. Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade, 20(4), 657–688. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-019-00318-z

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ariss, R. T. (2010). On the implications of market power in banking: Evidence from developing countries. Journal of Banking & Finance, 34(4), 765–775. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2009.09.004

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Assefa, E., Hermes, N., & Meesters, A. (2013). Competition and the performance of microfinance institutions. Applied Financial Economics, 23(9), 767–782. https://doi.org/10.1080/09603107.2012.754541

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baquero, G., Hamadi, M., & Heinen, A. (2018). Competition, loan rates, and information dispersion in nonprofit and for-profit microcredit markets. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 50(5), 893–937.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bassem, B. S. (2012). Social and financial performance of microfinance institutions: Is there a trade-off? Journal of Economics and International Finance, 4(4), 92–100. https://doi.org/10.5897/JEIF11.129

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baum, C., Schaffer, M., & Stillman, S. (2007). Enhanced routines for instrumental variables/generalized method of moments estimation and testing. Stata Journal, 7(4), 465–506.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benston, G., Hanweck, G., & Humphrey, D. (1982). Scale economies in banking: A restructuring and reassessment. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 14(4), 435–456. https://doi.org/10.2307/1991654

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, A. N., & Hannan, T. H. (1998). The efficiency cost of market power in the banking industry: A test of the “quiet life” and related hypotheses. Review of Economics and Statistics, 80(3), 454–465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, A., & Mester, L. (1997). Inside the black box: What explains differences in the efficiencies of financial institutions? Journal of Banking & Finance, 21(7), 895–947. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0378-4266(97)00010-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cuéllar-Fernández, B., Fuertes-Callén, Y., Serrano-Cinca, C., & Gutiérrez-Nieto, B. (2016). Determinants of margin in microfinance institutions. Applied Economics, 48(4), 300–311.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Quidt, J., Fetzer, T., & Ghatak, M. (2018). Market structure and borrower welfare in microfinance. The Economic Journal, 128(610), 1019–1046. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecoj.12591

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Klapper, L., Singer, D., & Ansar, S. (2022). The Global Findex Database 2021: Financial inclusion, digital payments, and resilience in the age of COVID-19. World Bank Publications. https://doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-1897-4

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1973). Industry structure, market rivalry, and public policy. The Journal of Law and Economics, 16(1), 1–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fall, F., Akim, A., & Wassongma, H. (2018). DEA and SFA research on the efficiency of microfinance institutions: A meta-analysis. World Development, 107, 176–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernández de Guevara, J., & Maudos, J. (2004). Measuring welfare loss of market power: An application to European banks. Applied Economic Letters, 11, 833–836.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fu, X., Lin, Y., & Molyneux, P. (2014). Bank competition and financial stability in Asia Pacific. Journal of Banking & Finance, 38, 64–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fuentes-Dávila, H. (2016). Determinantes del margen financiero en el sector microfinanciero: El caso peruano. Revista Estudios Económicos, 32, 71–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W. (2005). Fixed and random effects in stochastic frontier models. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 23(1), 7–32. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-004-8545-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gregoire, J. R., & Tuya, O. R. (2006). Cost efficiency of microfinance institutions in Peru: A stochastic frontier approach. Latin American Business Review, 7(2), 41–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guha, B., & Chowdhury, P. R. (2013). Micro-finance competition: Motivated micro-lenders, double-dipping and default. Journal of Development Economics, 105, 86–102. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2013.07.006

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haghnejad, A., Samadi, S., Nasrollahi, K., Azarbayjani, K., & Kazemi, I. (2020). Market power and efficiency in the Iranian banking industry. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 56(13), 3217–3234. https://doi.org/10.1080/1540496X.2019.1643716

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halouani, N., & Boujelbène, Y. (2015). External Governance and Dual Mission in the African MFIs. Strategic Change, 24(3), 243–265. https://doi.org/10.1002/jsc.2007

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haq, M., Skully, M., & Pathan, S. (2010). Efficiency of microfinance institutions: A data envelopment analysis. Asia-Pacific Financial Markets, 17(1), 63–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harberger, A. (1954). Monopoly and resource allocation. The American Economic Review, 44(2), 77–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hermes, N., & Hudon, A. (2018). Determinants of the performance of microfinance institutions: A systematic review. Journal of Economic Surveys, 32(5), 1483–1513. https://doi.org/10.1111/joes.12290

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hermes, N., Lensink, R., & Meesters, A. (2011). Outreach and efficiency of microfinance institutions. World Development, 39(6), 938–948. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2009.10.018

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hermes, N., Lensink, R., & Meesters, A. (2018). Financial development and the efficiency of microfinance institutions. Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. R. (1935). Annual survey of economic theory: The theory of monopoly. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 3, 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hossain, S., Galbreath, J., Hasan, M. M., & Randøy, T. (2020). Does competition enhance the double-bottom-line performance of microfinance institutions? Journal of Banking & Finance, 113, 105765. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2020.105765

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Humphrey, D., & Pulley, L. (1997). Banks’ responses to deregulation: Profits, technology, and efficiency. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 29(1), 73–93. https://doi.org/10.2307/2953687

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Instituto Nacional de Estadística e Informática [INEI]. (2022a). Evolución de la Pobreza Monetaria 2010–2021. Informe Técnico.

    Google Scholar 

  • Instituto Nacional de Estadística e Informática [INEI]. (2022b). Producción y Empleo Informal en el Perú - Cuenta Satélite de la Economía Informal 2007–2021.

  • Koetter, M., Kolari, J. W., & Spierdijk, L. (2012). Enjoying the quiet life under deregulation? Evidence from adjusted Lerner indices for US banks. Review of Economics and Statistics, 94(2), 462–480. https://doi.org/10.1162/REST_a_00155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar, S., & Lovell, C. (2003). Stochastic frontier analysis. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • León, J. V. (2009). An empirical analysis of Peruvian municipal banks using cost-efficiency frontier approaches. Canadian Journal of Development Studies, 29(1–2), 161–182.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lerner, A. (1934). The concept of monopoly and the measurement of monopoly power. Review of Economic Studies, 1(3), 157–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marconi, R., & Mosley, P. (2006). Bolivia during the global crisis 1998–2004: Towards a macroeconomics of microfinance. Journal of International Development, 18(2), 237–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marquez, R. (2002). Competition, adverse selection, and information dispersion in the banking industry. The Review of Financial Studies, 15(3), 901–926. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/15.3.901

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maudos, J., & Fernández de Guevara, J. (2007). The cost of market power in banking: Social welfare loss vs. cost inefficiency. Journal of Banking & Finance, 31, 2103–2125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayorca, E., & Aguilar, G. (2016). Competencia y calidad de cartera en el mercado microfinanciero peruano, 2003–2015. Economía, 39(78), 67–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McIntosh, C., De Janvry, A., & Sadoulet, E. (2005). How rising competition among microfinance institutions affects incumbent lenders. The Economic Journal, 115(506), 987–1004. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0297.2005.01028.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McIntosh, C., & Wydick, B. (2005). Competition and microfinance. Journal of Development Economics, 78(2), 271–298. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2004.11.008

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mia, M. A. (2022). Social Purpose, Commercialization, and Innovations in Microfinance. Springer Books. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-19-0217-8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Motta, M. (2004). Competition policy: Theory and practice. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nguyen, T., Nghiem, H., Roca, E., & Sharma, P. (2016). Efficiency, innovation and competition: Evidence from Vietnam. China and India. Empirical Economics, 51(3), 1235–1259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oroz, M., & Salas, V. (2003). Competencia y eficiencia en la intermediación financiera en España, 1977–2000. Moneda y Crédito, 217, 73–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quayes, S., & Khalily, M. B. (2013). Efficiency of microfinance institutions in Bangladesh. Institute of Microfinance.

    Google Scholar 

  • Restrepo-Tobón, D., & Kumbhakar, S. (2014). Enjoying the quiet life under deregulation? Not quite. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 29(2), 333–343. https://doi.org/10.1002/jae.2374

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riaz, M., & Gopal, P. (2015). In competency aspects of microfinance industry: Via SFA approach. Journal of Economics and Behavioral Studies, 7(1(J)), 1–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schaffer, M. (2005). XTIVREG2: Stata module to perform extended IV/2SLS, GMM and AC/HAC, LIML and k-class regression for panel data models. Statistical Software Components S456501. Boston College Department of Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solis, L., & Maudos, J. (2008). The social costs of bank market power: Evidence from Mexico. Journal of Comparative Economics, 36, 467–488.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock, J., & Yogo, M. (2005). Asymptotic distributions of instrumental variables statistics with many instruments. Identification and Inference for Econometric Models: Essays in Honor of Thomas Rothenberg, 6, 109–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Superintendencia Bancos de Seguros y Administradoras de Fondos de Pensiones (SBS). (2003). Memoria anual 2002. Superintendencia de Bancos. Seguros y Administradoras de Fondos de Pensiones.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tadesse, G., Borzaga, C., & Getnet, K. (2014). Cost-efficiency and outreach of microfinance institutions: Trade-offs and the role of ownership. Journal of International Development, 26(6), 923–932.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vogelgesang, U. (2003). Microfinance in times of crisis: The effects of competition, rising indebtedness, and economic crisis on repayment behavior. World Development, 31(12), 2085–2114. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2003.09.004

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watkins, T. (2018). Introduction to Microfinance. World Scientific Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to acknowledge the financial support provided by the Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú to carry out this research.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

All authors contributed to the conception and design of the study. Material preparation and data collection were performed by JP and analysis by GA and JP. The first draft of the manuscript was written by both authors. Also, both authors read and approved the final version of the manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Giovanna Aguilar.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors have no competing interests to declare that are relevant to the content of this article.

Ethical approval

This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the authors.

Consent for publication

We have consented for the publication of this research in this journal.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

  1. 1.

    Harberger’s triangle

An MFI with market power in the microcredit market maximizes its profit by choosing the price or interest rate (P) that it will charge for its loans (L). The problem to be solved is therefore:

$$Max \pi \left(L\right)=P\left(L\right)L-TC\left(L\right)$$
(12)

The first-order condition to solve this problem is:

$$\frac{\partial \pi }{\partial L}=\frac{\partial P\left(L\right)}{\partial L}L+P\left(L\right)-\frac{\partial TC}{\partial L}=0$$
$$P\left(L\right)-\frac{\partial TC}{\partial L}=-\frac{\partial P\left(L\right)}{\partial L}L$$
$$P\left(L\right)-\frac{\partial TC}{\partial L}=-\frac{\partial P\left(L\right)}{\partial L}L\frac{P}{P}$$
$$\frac{P\left(L\right)-\frac{\partial TC}{\partial L}}{P}=-\frac{1}{\frac{\partial L}{\partial P}\frac{P}{L}}=-\frac{1}{\varepsilon }$$
(13)

Since \(\frac{\partial TC }{\partial L}\) is the marginal cost (MC), the term on the left of Eq. (13) is the Lerner index (LI) and \(\frac{\partial L}{\partial P}\frac{P}{L}\) is the price elasticity of loans demand (ɛ). Therefore, we obtain from profit maximization:

$$LI=-\frac{1}{\varepsilon }$$
(14)

The net loss of social welfare in Fig. 1 is equivalent to the area of triangle ABC:

$$\Delta ABC=\frac{\left({P}^{*}-MC\right)\left({L}_{PC}-{L}^{*}\right)}{2} =\frac{1}{2}\frac{\left(MC-{P}^{*}\right)\left({L}_{PC}-{L}^{*}\right)}{\left(MC-{P}^{*}\right)}\frac{\left({P}^{*}-MC\right){P}^{*}{L}^{*}}{{P}^{*}{L}^{*}}$$
$$\Delta ABC=-\frac{1}{2}\frac{\left({L}_{PC}-{L}^{*}\right)}{\left(MC-{P}^{*}\right)}\frac{{P}^{*}}{{L}^{*}}\frac{{\left({P}^{*}-MC\right)}^{2}{L}^{*}}{{P}^{*}}=-\frac{1}{2}\varepsilon \frac{{\left({P}^{*}-MC\right)}^{2}{L}^{*}}{{P}^{*}}$$

Replacing ɛ from Eq. (14), we have:

$$\Delta ABC=-\frac{1}{2}\left[-\frac{1}{LI}\right]\frac{{\left({P}^{*}-MC\right)}^{2}{L}^{*}}{{P}^{*}}$$

Replacing LI by \(\frac{{P}^{*}\left(L\right)-MC}{{P}^{*}}\), we have:

$$\Delta ABC=\frac{1}{2}\left[\frac{({P}^{*}-MC)}{{P}^{*}}\right]{P}^{*}{L}^{*}=\frac{1}{2}LI({P}^{*}{L}^{*})$$

See Table 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11 and 12.

Table 6 Definitions of variables and indicators
Table 7 Descriptive statistics
Table 8 Stochastic cost frontier results
Table 9 Stochastic alternative profit frontier results
Table 10 First stage of IV with fixed effects estimation
Table 11 Robustness analysis: stochastic alternative profit frontier results
Table 12 Robustness analysis: social welfare loss, weighted averages cost and profit efficiencies, and social costs associated with cost and profit inefficiency. In addition, variation in welfare loss associated with reduced cost efficiency and profit efficiency from a 10% reduction in market power (% GDP)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Aguilar, G., Portilla, J. Market power, social welfare, and efficiency in the Peruvian microfinance. Econ Polit 41, 123–152 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40888-023-00321-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40888-023-00321-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation