Skip to main content
Log in

An experiment in the role of identity in fostering coordination

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of the Economic Science Association Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Coordination problems arise in many economic, political, and social situations. Many times, authorities and institutions are created to solve these coordination problems. However, the success of these institutions depends on whether people are willing to follow their prescriptions. Using a behavioral experiment on Amazon Mechanical Turk we analyze whether an authority can aid in solving hawk-dove coordination games and whether its success depends on a shared identity by the players. The authority is represented in our experiment by a randomizing device that recommends actions to players to implement a socially efficient correlated equilibrium. In the game, players are better off following the recommendations if they believe others will do as well. We investigate whether people are more likely to follow recommendations when they have a shared identity. We find that the device’s success is not driven by group membership, but rather by the content of its recommendations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

The replication material for this study is available at https://doi.org/10.3886/E193903V2.

Notes

  1. The advent of the global games literature in both economics (e.g., Angeletos et al., 2007; Carlsson & Van Damme, 1993; Morris & Shin, 1998) and political science, (e.g., Aldama et al., 2019; Casper & Tyson, 2014; Malis & Smith, 2019) has been developed partially to come up with unique equilibrium predictions in coordination games.

  2. Importantly, however, some institutions could not only influence players’ beliefs about others’ actions but also their preferences over them.

  3. For a review of the experimental literature on cheap-talk communication see Crawford (1998).

  4. In contrast to our study, Chen and Chen (2011) focus on equilibrium selection, rather than on the implementation of a correlated equilibrium.

  5. It is important to note that in this case, neither payoff dominance nor risk dominance make a prediction of which equilibrium should be selected.

  6. For detailed discussions on correlated equilibria see Aumann (1974) and Fudenberg and Tirole (1991: pp. 53–59).

  7. The lowest possible symmetrical payoff, 20, is given by \(a=b=d=\tfrac{1}{3}\), \(c=0\).

  8. In fact, in equilibrium only probabilities that \(p=0\) or \(p=1\) can be sustained.

  9. This was done to ensure the quality of the responses as suggested in Kennedy et al. (2020).

  10. A full set of demographic characteristics divided by treatment condition is available in the Online Appendix.

  11. Screenshots of the instructions are included in the Online Appendix.

  12. For a discussion on how this helps ensure quality, see Hauser et al. (2019).

  13. Equal payoffs are presented in the off-diagonal in an effort to try to make them less immediately salient to participants and have them consider the full payoff table.

  14. Though this was not known by participants ex-ante, given our ex-post matching procedure, in the end, the actions of five participants had to be matched with a player for a second time, though they were only paid for the first match.

  15. In a pilot, we used Smartriqs (Molnar, 2019) to enable people to play at the same time but wait times on MTurk made the ex-post matching a more efficient mechanism.

  16. Of course, the more risk averse participants are, the more likely they would be to choose Dove, even when recommended Hawk, unless they are fairly certain that the other player will choose Dove.

  17. A notable exception being Chen and Chen (2011).

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1369–1401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agranov, M., & Schotter, A. (2013). Language and government coordination: An experimental study of communication in the announcement game. Journal of Public Economics, 104, 26–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G. A., & Kranton, R. E. (2000). Economics and identity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), 715–753.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aldama, A., Vásquez-Cortés, M., & Young, L. E. (2019). Fear and citizen coordination against dictatorship. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 31(1), 103–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Almendares, N., & Landa, D. (2007). Strategic coordination and the law. Law and Philosophy, 26(5), 501–529.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angeletos, G.-M., Hellwig, C., & Pavan, A. (2007). Dynamic global games of regime change: Learning, multiplicity, and the timing of attacks. Econometrica, 75(3), 711–756.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Arifovic, J., Boitnott, J. F., & Duffy, J. (2019). Learning correlated equilibria: An evolutionary approach. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 157, 171–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aumann, R. J. (1974). Subjectivity and correlation in randomized strategies. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 1(1), 67–96.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Balliet, D., Wu, J., & De Dreu, C. K. (2014). Ingroup favoritism in cooperation: A meta-analysis. Psychological Bulletin, 140(6), 1556–1581.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Bar-Tal, D. (2000). Shared beliefs in a society: Social psychological analysis. Sage Publications.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bernhard, H., Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2006). Group affiliation and altruistic norm enforcement. American Economic Review, 96(2), 217–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bicchieri, C. (2006). The grammar of society: The nature and dynamics of social norms. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Billig, M., & Tajfel, H. (1973). Social categorization and similarity in intergroup behaviour. European Journal of Social Psychology, 3(1), 27–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandts, J., Cooper, D. J., & Fatas, E. (2007). Leadership and overcoming coordination failure with asymmetric costs. Experimental Economics, 10(3), 269–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlsson, H., & Van Damme, E. (1993). Global games and equilibrium selection. Econometrica, 61(5), 989–1018.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Cartwright, E., & Wooders, M. (2014). Correlated equilibrium, conformity, and stereotyping in social groups. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 16(5), 743–766.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cason, T. N., & Sharma, T. (2007). Recommended play and correlated equilibria: An experimental study. Economic Theory, 33(1), 11–27.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Casper, B. A., & Tyson, S. A. (2014). Popular protest and elite coordination in a coup d’état. Journal of Politics, 76(2), 548–564.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charness, G. (2000). Self-serving cheap talk: A test of Aumann’s conjecture. Games and Economic Behavior, 33(2), 177–194.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, R., & Chen, Y. (2011). The potential of social identity for equilibrium selection. American Economic Review, 101(6), 2562–2589.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y., & Li, S. X. (2009). Group identity and social preferences. American Economic Review, 99(1), 431–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connor, P., Stancato, D., Yildirim, U., Lee, S., & Chen, S. (2020). Inequality in the minimal group paradigm: How relative wealth and its justification influence ingroup bias. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 88, 103967.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, R., DeJong, D. V., Forsythe, R., & Ross, T. W. (1989). Communication in the battle of the sexes game: Some experimental results. The RAND Journal of Economics, 20(4), 568–587.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, R., DeJong, D. V., Forsythe, R., & Ross, T. W. (1992). Communication in coordination games. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 739–771.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, R., DeJong, D. V., Forsythe, R., & Ross, T. W. (1993). Forward induction in the battle-of-the-sexes games. American Economic Review, 83(5), 1303–1316.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, R. W., DeJong, D. V., Forsythe, R., & Ross, T. W. (1990). Selection criteria in coordination games: Some experimental results. American Economic Review, 80(1), 218–233.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coppock, A., & McClellan, O. A. (2019). Validating the demographic, political, psychological, and experimental results obtained from a new source of online survey respondents. Research & Politics, 6(1), 2053168018822174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crawford, V. (1998). A survey of experiments on communication via cheap talk. Journal of Economic Theory, 78(2), 286–298.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • d’Adda, G., Dufwenberg, M., Passarelli, F., & Tabellini, G. (2020). Social norms with private values: Theory and experiments. Games and Economic Behavior, 124, 288–304.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Dickson, E. (2010). Leadership, followership, and beliefs about the world: An experiment. New York University Working Paper.

  • Dickson, E. S., Gordon, S. C., & Huber, G. A. (2015). Institutional sources of legitimate authority: An experimental investigation. American Journal of Political Science, 59(1), 109–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dickson, E. S., & Scheve, K. (2006). Social identity, political speech, and electoral competition. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 18(1), 5–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duell, D., & Valasek, J. (2019). Political polarization and selection in representative democracies. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 168, 132–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duffy, J., & Feltovich, N. (2010). Correlated equilibria, good and bad: An experimental study. International Economic Review, 51(3), 701–721.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg, D., & Tirole, J. (1991). Game theory. The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gintis, H. (2010). Social norms as choreography. Politics, Philosophy & Economics, 9(3), 251–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G., & Baldassarri, D. (2012). The impact of elections on cooperation: Evidence from a lab-in-the-field experiment in Uganda. American Journal of Political Science, 56(4), 964–985.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Habyarimana, J., Humphreys, M., Posner, D. N., & Weinstein, J. M. (2007). Why does ethnic diversity undermine public goods provision? American Political Science Review, 101(4), 709–725.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hadfield, G. K., & Weingast, B. R. (2012). What is law? A coordination model of the characteristics of legal order. Journal of Legal Analysis, 4(2), 471–514.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hara, K., Adams, A., Milland, K., Savage, S., Callison-Burch, C., & Bigham J. P. (2018). A data-driven analysis of workers’ earnings on amazon mechanical turk (pp. 1–14). New York, NY, USA: Association for Computing Machinery.

  • Hauser, D., Paolacci, G., & Chandler, J. J. (2019). Common concerns with MTurk as a participant pool: Evidence and solutions. In F. R. Kardes, P. M. Herr, & N. Schwarz (Eds.), Handbook of research methods in consumer psychology (pp. 319–337). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kennedy, R., Clifford, S., Burleigh, T., Waggoner, P. D., Jewell, R., & Winter, N. J. (2020). The shape of and solutions to the MTurk quality crisis. Political Science Research and Methods, 8(4), 614–629.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kranton, R. E., & Sanders, S. G. (2017). Groupy versus non-groupy social preferences: Personality, region, and political party. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 107(5), 65–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landa, D., & Duell, D. (2015). Social identity and electoral accountability. American Journal of Political Science, 59(3), 671–689.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malis, M., & Smith, A. (2019). A global game of diplomacy. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 31(4), 480–506.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McAdams, R. H., & Nadler, J. (2005). Testing the focal point theory of legal compliance: The effect of third-party expression in an experimental hawk/dove game. Journal of Empirical Legal Studies, 2(1), 87–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Molnar, A. (2019). Smartriqs: A simple method allowing real-time respondent interaction in qualtrics surveys. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance, 22, 161–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moreno, D., & Wooders, J. (1998). An experimental study of communication and coordination in noncooperative games. Games and Economic Behavior, 24(1), 47–76.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Morris, S., & Shin, H. S. (1998). Unique equilibrium in a model of self-fulfilling currency attacks. American Economic Review, 88(3), 587–597.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morsky, B., & Akçay, E. (2019). Evolution of social norms and correlated equilibria. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 116(18), 8834–8839.

    Article  ADS  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Morton, R. B., Ou, K., & Qin, X. (2020). Reducing the detrimental effect of identity voting: An experiment on intergroup coordination in china. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 174, 320–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. American Political Science Review, 87(3), 567–576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Postema, G. J. (1982). Coordination and convention at the foundations of law. Journal of Legal Studies, 11(1), 165–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. C. (1960). The strategy of conflict. Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shayo, M. (2009). A model of social identity with an application to political economy: Nation, class, and redistribution. American Political Science Review, 103(2), 147–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanis, M., & Postmes, T. (2005). A social identity approach to trust: Interpersonal perception, group membership and trusting behaviour. European Journal of Social Psychology, 35(3), 413–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, R. K., & Rhodes, C. M. (1997). Leadership and credibility in n-person coordination games. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 41(6), 767–791.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

For discussions and comments on previous iterations of this project we thank the editor, Dirk Engelmann, two anonymous reviewers, Joel Blaxland, Cristina Bicchieri, Eric Dickson, Eugen Dimant, Jana Freundt, Mateo Vásquez-Cortés and seminar participants at SPSA, NYU New York and NYU Abu Dhabi. We thank the University of Pennsylvania for providing funding.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Abraham Aldama.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file1 (PDF 1270 KB)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Aldama, A., Draganoff, D. & Pahwa, G. An experiment in the role of identity in fostering coordination. J Econ Sci Assoc (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40881-023-00158-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40881-023-00158-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation