Skip to main content
Log in

A model of search and matching with PES intermediation

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Eurasian Economic Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper is an extension of Morgan (A model of search, coordination and market segmentation. Department of Economics, SUNY-Buffalo Working paper, 1998). It shows that introducing a specialist matching intermediary, a public employment exchange, can improve the efficiency of the market under certain conditions. Coupled with search costs and incentive compatible lumpsum membership fees, agents participate in only one of the disjoint segments generated in such markets. A complete description is provided of the equilibrium matching of agents. In equilibrium, agents separate according to type into different segments viz., an informal economy, an economy operated by the intermediary, and an economy populated by relatively highly skilled agents only. Welfare properties of the equilibrium are provided.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See for example, Gehrig (1993), Loertscher & Niedermayer (2008a), Agrawal et al. (2004), Rubinstein & Wolinsky (1987), Rust & Hall (2003).

  2. The search cost is assumed independent of type. However, introducing a different search cost that increases with an agent’s own type or the value of match generated does not alter the main implications of the model; it will only manifest in its impact on the size of market segments.

  3. The fee \(k^{'}(\tilde{v},v_u)\) is designed to ensure incentive compatibility for the type \(\tilde{v}\) between the PES segment and the higher segment. Note that, when \(\tilde{v}=v_u\), \(k^{'}(\tilde{v},v_u)= R-c-\frac{\beta \int _{\hat{v}}^{v_u}\mu (v_u,z)f(z) dz}{F(v_u)-F(\hat{v})}\), which implies that \(EV(v_u;v_u,v_u)=0\). On the other hand, if \(\tilde{v}<v_u\), then \(EV(v_u;\tilde{v},v_u)>0\), as observed from (15) later. So, a type \(v_u\) rationally prefers a \(\tilde{v}\) lower than its own type.

  4. Incentive compatibility of all types is demonstrated in Sect. 3.4. See below.

  5. This can be shown by using (20) and the fact that the highest type a PES with positive assortative matching scheme is able to offer a type \(v_u\) is \(\tilde{v}\).

  6. Leibniz’s rule states that \(\frac{\partial }{\partial {p}}\int _{a(p)}^{(b(p)}f(x,p)dx=\int _{a(p)}^{(b(p)}\frac{\partial f}{\partial p}dx + f(b(p),p)\frac{\partial b}{\partial p}- f(a(p),p)\frac{\partial a}{\partial p}\), where x is the variable of integration.

  7. The weakest sufficiency condition is continuous differentiability of the expression in (9). In the proof of Proposition 1, we have shown that G(.) is continuously differentiable, and therefore so is \(h(\tilde{v};.)\).

References

  • Agrawal, M., Hariharan, G., Kishore, R., & Rao, H. R. (2004). Matching intermediaries for information goods in the presence of direct search: An examination of switching costs and obsolescence of information. Decision Support Systems, 41, 20–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atakan, A. E. (1999). Assortative matching with explicit search costs. Econometrica, 74(3), 667–680.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autor, D. H. (2009). Studies of Labor Market Intermediation (pp. 1–23). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  • Becker, G. (1973). Theory of marriage: Part I. Journal of Political Economy, 81, 813–846.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1974). Theory of marriage: Part II. Journal of Political Economy, 82, S11–S26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bester, H. (1988). Bargaining, search costs and equilibrium price distributions. Review of Economic Studies, 55, 201–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binmore, K. G., & Herrero, M. J. (1988). Matching and bargaining in dynamic markets. Review of Economic Studies, 55(1), 17–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloch, F., & Ryder, H. (1987). Matching, search and bargaining. Journal of Economic Theory, 42, 311–333.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloch, F., & Ryder, H. (2000). Two sided search, marriages and matchmakers. International Economic Review, 41(1), 93–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burani, N. (2008). Matching, search and intermediation with two-sided heterogeneity. Review of Economic Design, 12(2), 75–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burdett, K., & Coles, M. G. (1997). Marriage and class. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(1), 141–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carrillo, P. E. (2005). An empirical two-sided equilibrium search model of the real estate market, University of Virginia, Department of Economics.

  • Chade, H. (1995). Two sided search with heterogeneous agents. mimeo, Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign.

  • Chade, H. (2001). Two-sided search and perfect segregation with fixed search costs. Mathematical Social Sciences, 42, 31–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chatterjee, T. (2015). Public employment exchange in India: A report. mimeo, State University of New York at Buffalo.

  • Davis, D., & Holt, C. (1994). An experimental examination of the diamond paradox. Working paper, University of Virginia.

  • Davos-Klosters, S. (2014). Matching skills and labour market needs. World Economic Forum Global Agenda Council on Employment, 12.

  • Diamond, P. (1971). A model of price adjustment. Journal of Economic Theory, 3, 156–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P. A., & Maskin, E. (1981). An equilibrium analysis of search and breach of contract II. A non-steady state example. Journal of Economic Theory, 25(2), 165–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P. (1982). Wage determination and efficiency in search equilibrium. Review of Economic Studies, 49(2), 217–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fougère, D., Pradel, J., & Roger, M. (2005). Does job-search assistance affect search effort and outcomes? A microeconometric analysis of public versus private search methods. Institute for the Study of Labor, IZA DP No. 1825.

  • Gale, D., & Shapley, L. S. (1962). College admissions and the stability of marriage. The American Mathematical Monthly, 69(1), 9–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrig, T. (1993). Intermediation in search markets. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 2(1), 97–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Han, L., & Strange, W. C. (2015). The microstructure of housing markets: Search, bargaining, and brokerage. In G. Duranton, V. Henderson, & W. Strange (Eds.) Handbook of regional and urban economics (Vol. 5, pp. 813–886). http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/B9780444595317000132.

  • Kubler, D. (1999). Coexistence of public and private job agencies: Screening with heterogenous institutions. Public Choice, 101(1/2), 85–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Larsen, C. A., & Vesan, P. (2012). Why public employment services always fail. Public Administration, 90(2), 446–479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood, B. (1986). Transferable skills, job matching, and the efficiency of the ‘natural’ rate of unemployment. Economic Journal, 96, 961–974.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loertscher, S., & Niedermayer, A. (2008a). Fee setting intermediaries: On real estate agents, stock brokers, and auction houses. Discussion Papers, Northwestern University, Center for Mathematical Studies in Economics and Management Science.

  • Loertscher, S., & Niedermayer, A. (2008b). Fee setting intermediaries: On real estate agents, stock brokers, and auction houses. Discussion papers from Northwestern University, Center for Mathematical Studies in Economics and Management Science.

  • Lu, X., & McAfee, P. R. (1996). Matching and expectations in a market with heterogenous agents. In M. Bay (Ed.) Advances in Applied Micro-Economics (Vol. 6, pp. 121–156). London: JAI Press.

  • MacNamara, J., & Collins, E. (1990). The job search problem as an employer-candidate game. Journal of Applied Probability, 28, 815–827.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mckenna, C. (1987). Labour market participation in matching equilibrium. Economica, 54, 325–333.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McMillan, J., & Rothschild, M. (1994). Search theory. In R. J. Aumann, S. Hart (Eds.) Handbook of game theory with economic applications (Vol. 2). North Holland: Elsevier Science B.V.

  • Morgan, P. B. (1995). Two sided search and matching. mimeo, Department of Economics, State University of New York at Buffalo.

  • Morgan, P. B. (1998). A model of search, coordination and market segmentation. Department of Economics, SUNY-Buffalo Working paper.

  • Mortensen, D. (1982). The matching process as a noncooperative bargaining game. In J. J. McCall (Ed.), The economics of information and uncertainty. Chicago: Univeristy of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nungsari, M. (2014). Searching for yourself: A model of pricing on a two-sided matching platform with horizontally-differentiated agents (Vol. 12). The University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill.

  • OECD Employment Outlook (2005). Public employment services: Managing performance. ISBN 92-64-01045-9.

  • Pissarides, C. (1971). Equilibrium unemployment theory. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A., & Sotomayor, M. (1990). Two-sided matching: A study in game-theoretic modelling and analysis. Econometric society monograph no. 18. New York and Melbourne: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein, A. (1985a). Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model. Econometrica, 50, 97–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein, A. (1985b). Equilibrium in a market with sequential bargaining. Econometrica, 53, 1133–1150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein, A., & Wolinsky, A. (1987). Middlemen. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, 581–593.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rust, J., & Hall, G. (2003). Middlemen versus market makers: A theory of competitive exchange. Journal of Political Economy, 111(2), 353–403.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sattinger, M. (1993). Assignment models of the distribution of earnings. Journal of Economic Literature, 31, 831–880.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shimer, R., & Smith, L. (2000). Assortative matching and search. Econometrica, 68(2), 343–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, L. (1995). Cross-sectional dynamics in a two-sided matching model. MIT, Department of Economics mimeo 95-14.

  • Stigler, G. J. (1961). The economics of information. The Journal of Political Economy, 69(3), 213–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1962). Information in the labor market. The Journal of Political Economy, 70(5), 94–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vera, C. P. (2014). A quasi-experimental evaluation of the public employment service: Evidence from Perù. mimeo, Zirve University.

  • Wooders, J. (1994). Bargaining and matching in small markets. Working Paper 94-56.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Twisha Chatterjee.

Additional information

I am thankful to Professor Peter Morgan and Professor Neel Rao for their constant advice and support. I also thank my peers at the Department of Economics at UB for their helpful comments and suggestions. All errors are mine.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1. Consider (9) and write

$$\begin{aligned} G({\tilde{v}},{\hat{v}};v_l)\equiv \beta \Bigg [\frac{\int _{\hat{v}}^{\tilde{v}}\mu ({\hat{v}},z)f(z)dz}{F({\tilde{v}})-F({\hat{v}})}-\frac{\int _{v_l}^{\hat{v}}\mu ({\hat{v}},z)f(z)dz}{F({\hat{v}})}\Bigg ]-R+c=0 \end{aligned}$$

for \(v_{l}\le {\hat{v}} \le {\tilde{v}}\). \(\mu ({\hat{v}},z)\) is differentiable, so \(G(\tilde{v},\hat{v};v_l)\) is continuous and differentiable with respect to \(\hat{v}\). The value of G(.) at \(\hat{v}=v_{l}\) is

$$\begin{aligned} G(\tilde{v},v_l;v_l)=\beta \Bigg [\dfrac{\int _{v_l}^{\tilde{v}}\mu (v_l,z)f(z)dz}{F(\tilde{v})}- \dfrac{\int _{v_l}^{v_l}\mu (v_l,z)f(z)dz}{F(v_l)}\Bigg ]=\beta \Bigg [\frac{\int _{v_l}^{\tilde{v}}\mu (v_l,z)f(z)dz}{F(\tilde{v})}-\mu (v_{l},v_{l})\Bigg ]\, ; \end{aligned}$$

i.e., the benefit of the lowest type in \([v_l,\tilde{v}]\) in matching within the PES exceeds the match value generated by pairing with an identical agent of the same type. The value of G(.) at \(\hat{v}=\tilde{v}\) is

$$\begin{aligned} G(\tilde{v},\tilde{v};v_l)=\beta \Bigg [\dfrac{\int _{\tilde{v}}^{\tilde{v}}\mu (\tilde{v},z)f(z)dz}{F(\tilde{v})-F(\tilde{v})}- \dfrac{\int _{v_l}^{\tilde{v}}\mu (\tilde{v},z)f(z)dz}{F(\tilde{v})}\Bigg ]=\beta \Bigg [\mu (\tilde{v},\tilde{v})-\frac{\int _{v_l}^{\tilde{v}}\mu (\tilde{v},z)f(z)dz}{F(\tilde{v})}\Bigg ]\, ; \end{aligned}$$

i.e., the benefit of the highest type in \([v_l,\tilde{v}]\) in matching with an identical agent of its own type exceeds the match value generated from matching within \([v_l,\tilde{v}]\).

Therefore,the net benefit of PES membership for a type \(\hat{v}\) attains a maximum in \([v_l,\tilde{v}]\). If

$$\begin{aligned} \beta \Bigg [\frac{\int _{v_l}^{\tilde{v}}\mu (v_l,z)f(z)dz}{F(\tilde{v})}-\mu (v_{l},v_{l})\Bigg ]<R-c<\beta \Bigg [\mu (\tilde{v},\tilde{v})-\frac{\int _{v_l}^{\tilde{v}}\mu (\tilde{v},z)f(z)dz}{F(\tilde{v})}\Bigg ] \end{aligned}$$

then the Intermediate Value Theorem establishes the existence of at least one zero root; i.e., at least one solution \({\hat{v}}_1\) for (9), for given R and c. Then,

$$\begin{aligned} G(\tilde{v},{{\hat{v}}_1};v_l)\equiv \beta \Bigg [\frac{\int _{{\hat{v}}_1}^{\tilde{v}}\mu (\hat{v},z)f(z)dz}{F(\tilde{v})-F({{\hat{v}}_1})}-\frac{\int _{v_l}^{{\hat{v}}_1}\mu (\hat{v},z)f(z)dz}{F({{\hat{v}}_1})}\Bigg ]-R+c \equiv 0 . \end{aligned}$$

\({\hat{v}}_1\) is unique if G(.) is monotonic with respect to \(\hat{v}\) on \([v_l,\tilde{v}]\).

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial G(\tilde{v},\hat{v};v_l)}{\partial \hat{v}}&= \beta \frac{\partial }{\partial \hat{v}}\Bigg [\dfrac{\int _{\hat{v}}^{\tilde{v}}\mu (\hat{v},z)f(z)dz}{F(\tilde{v})-F(\hat{v})}- \dfrac{\int _{v_l}^{\hat{v}}\mu (\hat{v},z)f(z)dz}{F(\hat{v})}\Bigg ]\\&= \beta \Bigg [\frac{[F(\tilde{v})-F(\hat{v})]\frac{\partial }{\partial \hat{v}}\int _{\hat{v}}^{\tilde{v}}\mu (\hat{v},z)f(z)dz + f(\hat{v})\int _{\hat{v}}^{\tilde{v}}\mu (\hat{v},z)f(z)dz }{[F(\tilde{v})-F(\hat{v})]^{2}}\Bigg ]\\&\times \dfrac{[F(\hat{v})]\frac{\partial }{\partial \hat{v}}\int _{v_l}^{\hat{v}}\mu (\hat{v},z)f(z)dz + f(\hat{v})\int _{v_l}^{\hat{v}}\mu (\hat{v},z)f(z)dz }{F(\hat{v})^{2}}\Bigg ]. \end{aligned}$$

Keeping in mind that the function \(\mu\) is twice continuously differentiable and increasing in its domain for both its arguments, and then using Leibniz’s rule to differentiate under the integral.Footnote 6 Furthermore, the supermodularity of the \(\mu\) function ensures that \(\mu _{12}>0\), \(\forall\) \(v\in\) \([v_l,v_u]\). We can further write \(\frac{\partial G(\tilde{v},\hat{v};v_l)}{\partial \hat{v}}\) as

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial G(\tilde{v},\hat{v};v_l)}{\partial \hat{v}}= & {} \frac{\beta }{[F(\tilde{v})-F(\hat{v})]^{2}}\Bigg [[F(\tilde{v})-F(\hat{v})]\int _{\hat{v}}^{\tilde{v}} \frac{\partial \mu (\hat{v},z)}{\partial \hat{v}}f(z)dz-f(\hat{v})[F(\tilde{v})\\&-F(\hat{v})]\mu (\hat{v},\hat{v}) +f(\hat{v})\int _{\hat{v}}^{\tilde{v}}\mu (\hat{v},z)f(z)dz\Bigg ]\\&-\frac{\beta }{F(\hat{v})^{2}}\Bigg [F(\hat{v})\int _{v_l}^{\hat{v}} \frac{\partial \mu (\hat{v},z)}{\partial \hat{v}}f(z)dz+f(\hat{v})(F(\hat{v})\mu (\hat{v},\hat{v})\\&-f(\hat{v})\int _{v_l}^{\hat{v}}\mu (\hat{v},z)f(z)dz\Bigg ].\\ \frac{\partial G(\tilde{v},\hat{v};v_l)}{\partial \hat{v}}= & {} \beta \Bigg [\frac{\int _{\hat{v}}^{\tilde{v}}\mu _{1}(\hat{v},z)f(z)dz}{F(\tilde{v})-F(\hat{v})}-\frac{\int _{v_l}^{\hat{v}}\mu _{1}(\hat{v},z)f(z)dz}{F(\hat{v})}\Bigg ]\\&+ \frac{\beta f(\hat{v})}{F(\tilde{v})-F(\hat{v})}\Bigg [ \frac{\int _{\hat{v}}^{\tilde{v}}\mu (\hat{v},z)f(z)dz}{F(\tilde{v})-F(\hat{v})} - {\mu (\hat{v},\hat{v})}\Bigg ]\\&+\frac{\beta f(\hat{v})}{F(\hat{v})}\Bigg [\frac{\int _{v_l}^{\hat{v}}\mu (\hat{v},z)f(z)dz}{F(\hat{v})} - {\mu (\hat{v},\hat{v})}\Bigg ]\\&= \beta [A_1-A_2]+\beta f(\hat{v})[B_1-B_2]+ \beta f(\hat{v})[C_1-C_2]>0. \end{aligned}$$

\(A_1-A_2>0\) because \(\mu _1(.)\) is increasing in \([v_l,\tilde{v}]\). \(B_1\) represents a type \(\hat{v}\)’s average payoff of matching with any type in \([\hat{v},\tilde{v}]\). \(B_2\) is the match value generated by matching with itself in \([\hat{v},\tilde{v}]\). Since, any average type in \([\hat{v},\tilde{v}]\) is higher than \(\hat{v}\), \(B_1-B_2>0\). Similarly, \(C_1\) represents a type \(\hat{v}\)’s average payoff of matching with any type in \([v_l, \hat{v}]\). \(C_2\) is the match value generated by matching with itself in \([v_l, \hat{v}]\). Since, any average type in \([v_l, \hat{v}]\) is lower than \(\hat{v}\), \(C_1-C_2<0\). Further, \(B_1\) and \(C_1\) are the average normalized payoff of \(\hat{v}\) with z, for \(\hat{v}\le z \le \tilde{v}\) and \(v_l\le z \le \hat{v}\) respectively. The latter is smaller than the former because the strictly supermodular function \(\mu (\hat{v},z)\) possesses strictly increasing differences in \((\hat{v},z)\). This implies that \(\mid {B_1-B_2}\mid >\mid {C_1-C_2}\mid\). Therefore, \(G(\tilde{v},\hat{v};v_l)\) is a strictly increasing function of \(\hat{v} \in\) \([v_l,\tilde{v}]\). \(\square\)

Proof of Remark 1

Since \(v_u\) chooses \(\tilde{v}\) to optimize its net expected payoff from matching in the higher segment, the reservation type of \(v_u\) cannot be lower than \(\tilde{v}\). Suppose \(\rho (v_u;\tilde{v},v_u)>\tilde{v}\). Then the expected value of a match generated for \(v_u\) in \([\tilde{v},\rho (v_u;.)]\bigcup [\rho (v_u;.),v_u]\) (call it \(E_2\)) is

$$\begin{aligned} E_2=\Big (1-F(\rho (v_u;.))\Big ) \Bigg [\frac{-c+\beta \int _{\rho (v_u;.)}^{v_u}\mu (v_u,z)f(z)dz}{1-F(\rho (v_u;.))}\Bigg ]-c \Big (F(\rho (v_u;.))-F(\tilde{v}))\Big ). \end{aligned}$$

The first term in \(E_2\) is the expected payoff for \(v_u\) of matching with any type at least as high as its reservation type, multiplied by the probability that a type \(v_u\) actually encounters a v \(\in\) \([\rho (v_u;.),v_u]\). The second term in \(E_2\), is the expected search cost due to a type \(v_u\) rejecting any type v \(\in\) \([\tilde{v},\rho (v_u;.)]\).

However, if \(\rho (v_u;\tilde{v},v_u)=\tilde{v}\), then \(v_u\)’s expected value of matching in \([\tilde{v},v_u]\) is

$$\begin{aligned}&\Big (1-F(\rho (v_u;.))\Big ) \Bigg [\frac{-c+\beta \int _{\rho (v_u;.)}^{v_u}\mu (v_u,z)f(z)dz}{1-F(\rho (v_u;.))}\Bigg ]\nonumber \\&\quad -c \Big (F(\rho (v_u;.))-F(\tilde{v}))\Big )+c \Big (F(\rho (v_u;.))-F(\tilde{v}))\Big )>{E_2}. \end{aligned}$$

Therefore \(\rho (v_u;\tilde{v},v_u)=\tilde{v}\). \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 2

Consider (16) and write

$$\begin{aligned} G_1(\tilde{v},v_u;\hat{v})=\frac{\beta \int _{\tilde{v}}^{v_u}[\mu (v_u,z)-\mu (\tilde{v},z)]f(z) dz}{F(v_u)-F(\tilde{v})}-\frac{\beta \int _{{\hat{v}}_1=h(\tilde{v};.)}^{\tilde{v}}[\mu (v_u,z)-\mu (\tilde{v},z)]f(z) dz}{F(\tilde{v})-F({\hat{v}}_1=h(\tilde{v};.))}. \end{aligned}$$

Consider the compact interval \([\hat{v},v_u]\) on \(\mathbb {R}\). \(G_{1}(\tilde{v},v_u;\hat{v})\) Footnote 7 is defined on \([\hat{v},v_u]\). Evaluating \(G_{1}(.)\) at its end points of the domain yields

$$\begin{aligned} G_{1}(\hat{v},v_u;\hat{v})= \frac{\beta \int _{\hat{v}}^{v_u}[\mu (v_u,z)-\mu (\hat{v},z)]f(z)dz}{F(v_u)-F(\hat{v})}-\frac{\beta \int _{{\hat{v}}_1=h(\tilde{v};.)}^{\hat{v}}[\mu (v_u,z)-\mu (\hat{v},z)]f(z)dz}{{F(\hat{v}})-F({{\hat{v}}_1=h(\tilde{v};.)}})>0. \end{aligned}$$

The second term in the above expression in \(G_{1}(\hat{v},v_u;\hat{v})\) is smaller than the first term since \(v_u\) is the highest type in the matching set specified in the first term above.

Also,

$$\begin{aligned} G_{1}(v_u,v_u;\hat{v})= \frac{\beta \int _{v_u}^{v_u}[\mu (v_u,z)-\mu (v_u,z)]f(z)dz}{F(v_u)-F(v_u)}-\frac{\beta \int _{{{\hat{v}}_1=h(\tilde{v};.)}}^{v_u}[\mu (v_u,z)-\mu (v_u,z)]f(z)dz}{F(v_u)-F({{\hat{v}}_1=h(\tilde{v};.)})}=0. \end{aligned}$$

\(\mu (v_u,z)\) is continuous on \([v_l,v_u]\), so \(G_{1}(\tilde{v},v_u;\hat{v})\) is both continuous and bounded on \([\hat{v},v_u]\), since functions continuous on a closed interval are also bounded in that interval. By Weierstrass’s Theorem, \(G_{1}(.)\) must attain a maximum in \([\hat{v},v_u]\). That is, there exists an agent \({\tilde{v}^{*}}\) such that

$$\begin{aligned} G_{1}(\hat{v},v_u;\hat{v}) > G_{1}({\tilde{v}}^{*},v_u;\hat{v}) \ge G_{1}(v_{u},v_{u};\hat{v})\,\, \mathrm{for}\,\, {\tilde{v}}^{*} \in [\hat{v},v_u]. \end{aligned}$$

Additionally, \({\tilde{v}^{*}}\) is unique. Since the reservation value for any type in this matching model is unique for every type in \([v_l,v_u]\) by construction, \(\rho (v_u;{\tilde{v}^{*}},v_u)={\tilde{v}^{*}}\), is the only value of v \(\in\) \([\hat{v},v_u]\) that maximizes the function \(G_{1}(.)\). \(\square\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chatterjee, T. A model of search and matching with PES intermediation. Eurasian Econ Rev 8, 1–36 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40822-017-0084-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40822-017-0084-y

keywords

Navigation