Skip to main content
Log in

Analyst coverage, syndicate structure, and loan contracts

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Eurasian Economic Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the effect of information intermediaries, specifically financial analysts, on the non-price terms and syndicate structure of bank loans. We find that loans to firms with higher analyst coverage have significantly less intensive covenant restrictions, a lower likelihood of requiring collateral and a lower likelihood of having performance-pricing provisions. Furthermore, our results document a negative relation between analyst coverage and loan maturity, implying that banks become more information-sensitive when lending to firms with large analyst coverage. We also find evidence that lenders tend to form less concentrated syndicate when the number of analysts increases.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For example, in 2006, nonfinancial US firms obtained over $1.3 trillion in new loans, which was almost equivalent to the total sum of capital issued in the equity market (around $0.13 trillion) and the bond market (around $1.2 trillion). The data supporting these statistics comes from the Federal Reserve's flow of funds data. http://www.federalreserve.gov/econresdata/releases/corpsecure/current.htm.

  2. To mitigate the information problem, banks must invest in costly information production and due diligence to assess the creditworthiness of the borrower at the outset of a lending relationship, and then monitor the borrower after the loan is made.

  3. Although it is not the exact equivalent of Tobin’s q, it has become common practice in the finance literature to calculate the ratio by using the market value of firm’s equity scaled by its book value of equity (i.e., Market-to-Book).

  4. It is highly possible that a borrower that violated a covenant and failed the renegotiation has no immediate access to other capital.

  5. In Flannery’s model, if transaction costs are high enough, firms with high risk ratings are willing to pay high interest rates on long-maturity debt in order to avoid transactions costs and a high possibility of paying higher rates after rolling over short-term debt; firms with low risk ratings are willing to pay low interest rates on short-maturity debt and roll it over because they are less likely to pay higher interest rates in the next period.

  6. Interacting analyst coverage variable with the dummies of asset tercile is equivalent to running regressions for each of the size tercile.

  7. Because the value of collateral is sensitive to borrower’s action, banks have to closely monitor the borrower after requiring collateral.

  8. In the reported results, we treat the loans with missing collateral information in DealScan as unsecured. Our results are unaffected if we ran the regressions only based on the subset of sample with nonmissing collateral.

  9. Sufi (2007) defined private and unrated firms as opaque firms and firms with investment-grade ratings as transparent firms. In our sample, private firms are not included after combining I/B/E/S, Compustat, and DealScan. We also classified only the unrated firms as opaque; the results were even stronger.

References

  • Altman, E. I. (1968). Financial ratios, discriminant analysis and the prediction of corporate bankruptcy. Journal of Finance, 23, 589–609.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asquith, P., Beatty, A., & Weber, J. (2005). Performance pricing in bank debt contracts. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 40, 101–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barclay, M. J., & Smith, C. W, Jr. (1995). The maturity structure of corporate debt. Journal of Finance, 50, 609–631.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnea, A., Haugen, R., & Senbet, L. (1980). A rationale for debt maturity structure and call provisions in an agency theoretic framework. Journal of Finance, 35, 1223–1234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, A., & Udell, G. (1995). Relationship lending and lines of credit in small firm finance. Journal of Business, 68, 351–381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bharath, S., Dahiya, S., Saunders, A., & Srinivasan, A. (2009). Lending relationships and loan contract terms. Review of Financial Studies (forthcoming).

  • Bhushan, R. (1989). Firm characteristics and analyst following. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 121, 255–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowen, R., Chen, X., & Cheng, Q. (2004). Analyst coverage and the cost of raising equity capital: evidence from underpricing of seasoned equity offerings. Working Paper, University of British Columbia.

  • Bradley, D. J., Jordan, B. D., & Ritter, J. R. (2003). The quiet period goes out with a bang. Journal of Finance, 58, 1–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradley, M., & Roberts, M. R. (2003). The structure and pricing of corporate debt covenants. Working Paper, Duke University.

  • Campbell, T., & Kracaw, W. (1980). Information production, market signaling, and the theory of intermediation. Journal of Finance, 35, 863–882.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cavezzali, E., Crepaldi, J., & Rigoni, U. (2014). Proximity to hubs of expertise and financial analyst forecast accuracy. Eurasian Business Review, 4, 157–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, X., Dasgupta, S., & Hilary, G. (2006). Analyst coverage and financing decisions. Journal of Finance, 61, 3009–3048.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chung, K., & Jo, H. (1996). The impact of security analysts’ monitoring and marketing functions on the market value of firms. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 31, 493–512.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Datta, S., Iskandar-Datta, M., & Ramna, K. (2005). Managerial stock ownership and the maturity structure of corporate debt. Journal of Finance, 60, 2333–2350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Defond, M., & Jiambalvo, J. (1994). Debt covenant violation and manipulation of accruals. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 17, 145–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dennis, S. A., & Mullineaux, D. J. (2000). Syndicated loans. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 9, 404–426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, D. W. (1984). Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring. The Review of Economic Studies, 51, 393–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, D. W. (1991). Debt maturity structure and liquidity risk. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 709–737.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dichev, I., & Skinner, D. (2002). Large-sample evidence on the debt covenant hypothesis. Journal of Accounting Research, 40, 1091–1123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flannery, M. J. (1986). Asymmetric information and risky debt maturity choice. Journal of Finance, 41, 19–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garleanu, N., & Zwiebel, J. (2009). Design and renegotiation of debt covenants. Review of Financial Studies, 22, 749–781.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham, J. R., Li, S., & Qiu, J. (2008). Corporate misreporting and bank loan contracting. Journal of Financial Economics, 88, 44–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Healy, P., & Palepu, K. (2001). Information asymmetry, corporate disclosure, and the capital markets: a review of the empirical disclosure literature. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 31, 405–440.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B., & Tirole, J. (1997). Financial intermediation, loanable funds, and the real sector. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 663–691.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong, H., Lim, T., & Stein, J. C. (2000). Bad news travels slowly: size, analyst coverage, and the profitability of momentum strategies. Journal of Finance, 55, 265–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Irvine, P. (2003). The incremental impact of analyst initiation of coverage. Journal of Corporate Finance, 9, 431–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jimenez, G., Salas, V., & Saurina, J. (2006). Determinants of collateral. Journal of Financial Economics, 81, 255–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, J., William, L., & Nigro, P. (2005). Agent bank behavior in bank loan syndications. Journal of Financial Research, 28, 385–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, S. W., & Mullineaux, D. J. (2004). Monitoring, financial distress, and the structure of commercial lending syndicates. Financial Management, 33, 107–130.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moyer, R., Chatfield, R., & Sisneros, P. (1989). Security analyst monitoring activity: agency costs and information demands. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 24, 503–512.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myers, S. C. (1977). Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics, 5, 147–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qian, J., & Strahan, P. E. (2007). How law and institutions shape financial contracts: the case of bank loans. The Journal of Finance, 62, 2803–2834.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajan, R., & Winton, A. (1995). Covenants and collateral as incentives to monitor. Journal of Finance, 47, 1367–1400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramakrishnan, R., & Thakor, A. (1984). Information reliability and the theory of financial intermediation. Review of Economic Studies, 51, 415–432.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simons, K. (1993). Why do banks syndicate loans? New England Economic Review of the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 45–52.

  • Smith, C. W., & Warner, J. B. (1979). On financial contracting: an analysis of bond covenants. Journal of Financial Economics, 7, 117–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strahan, P. (1999). Borrower risk and the price and nonprice terms of bank loans. Staff Paper No: Federal Reserve Bank of New York. 90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stulz, R. (2000). Does financial structure matter for economic growth? A corporate finance perspective. Working Paper, Ohio State University.

  • Sufi, A. (2007). Information asymmetry and financing arrangements: evidence from syndicated loans. The Journal of Finance, 62, 629–668.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yu, F. (2008). Analyst coverage and earnings management. Journal of Financial Economics, 88, 245–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to LiuLing Liu.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Liu, L. Analyst coverage, syndicate structure, and loan contracts. Eurasian Econ Rev 5, 1–21 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40822-015-0015-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40822-015-0015-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation