Skip to main content
Log in

An econometric identification of abnormally low bids in the procurement market: discriminant analysis

  • Published:
Journal of Industrial and Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In the public construction procurement market, ‘abnormally low bids (ALB)’ are prevalent and they cause many social and economic problems. Also, when the procurement bids are colluded, ALB make the competitive price systematically underestimated. As many countries regulate ALB, their criteria to identify ALB are not homogenous. Most of the criteria are based on construction cost, which is usually inaccurate, vulnerable to accounting manipulation, and limited to the supply side information of the market. We propose an econometric identification process of ALB using a discriminant analysis. It is based on a general mixture model and easily estimable by MLE. We apply our method to Korean public construction bidding data from 2007 to 2016. The estimation results identify the determinants of the bid prices, along with the determinants of ALB, and presents a more accurate assessment of the collusion damage.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

The data used in this paper are available from the authors upon request.

Notes

  1. Carpineti et al. (2006). Although the U.S. Federal Acquisition Regulation does not define ALB explicitly, it emphasizes that all prices during the procurement procedure should be fair and reasonable. The footnote 27 in Carpineti et al. (2006) explains what ‘fair and reasonable prices’ are.

  2. See Harrower (1999) for a detailed explanation.

  3. OECD(2016), Ibrahimi(2017)

  4. We agree with an anonymous referee that there exist collusions other than bid manipulation, and such a collusion does not necessarily raise the bid price. As De Leverano (2019) shows, non-price collusions such as market sharing agreements may not increase the bid price. It would not be successful at all to ‘detect’ collusion using bid price in such cases. As the referee points out, there have been developed a number of alternative collusion detection methods, even machine learing techniques as in Palshikar and Apte (2008) or Allahbakhsh et al. (2013). However, what we focus here is not collusion detection but damage assessment. Even in non-price collusion cases, ALB can mislead the damage assessment. As ALB lowers the estimated competitive price, the collusion effect based on the lowered competitive price would be ‘relatively’ overestimated, even though the collusion did not actually increase the bid price.

  5. For example, McAfee and McMillan (1987).

  6. As Ellison (1994) deals with time-series data, he uses a Markov structure for the logit function. We employ a contemporary logit structure, as we apply our method to cross-section data.

  7. Sometimes, the participating firms in an auction may offer ALB as a strategic ‘collusive’ behavior, to manipulate the tendering in favor of other bidders. This interesting behavior is important to analyze the relations between ALB and collusion. Ideally, if the data for all the participating bids are available, \(Z_{t}\) may include some variables on the collusive behaviors of the participating firms to investigate toward this end. Unfortunately, however, we only have the winner’s bids in our data set. Thus, in our model, \(\lambda_{t}\) is the probability of a ‘winning’ bid being an ALB, and cannot include the variables affecting ‘losing’ bids. We are grateful to an anonymous referee for drawing our attention to this important issue.

  8. We use GAUSS and R for the numerical maximization.

  9. Lee and Porter(1984), pp 400–401.

  10. For the structure and regulations in Korean public construction procurement market, see Jeong and Lee (2018).

  11. We use only the bids in which the number of bidders are less than 21. The reasons are: first, any bid with more than 20 bidders is regulated by a different Pre-Qualification standard, second, those bids with more than 20 bidders are usually very small construction project.

  12. There exists lots disaggregation in our collected data. Although lots disaggregation can make difference in the relations between the number of bidders and collusion, we could not control for lots disaggregation due to lack of information.

  13. Thus, there exists a possibility of under-detection for the collusion dummy.

  14. We are grateful to an anonymous referee for pointing this out.

  15. The maximum bid rate is 1 as the bid was exactly the same as the preliminary estimate in a contract (Juam Dam water conveyance tunnel stabilization project).

  16. Based on the discussion of the reasons motivating ALB in Sect. 2, it is natural to include some company level characteristics such as financial problems, legal liability limit, or liquidity status of the company in the regression model. We discovered, unfortunately, that such information is highly confidential in reality. Instead, we have tried an alternative model with the winner company heterogeneity as additional explanatory variables. We have included dummies for the 11 frequent bid winners (which won more than 20 bids in our data) in the model, to incorporate the company characteristics. The estimation results are almost identical to the one we present in Tables 3 and 4, and the winner heterogeneity turns out statistically insignificant all but one exception. The results are available from the authors upon request.

  17. ‘p.p.’ stands for ‘percentage point.’.

  18. As an anonymous referee points out, the collusion dummy variable could be endogenous. In our mixture regression model, however, a simultaneous equation system is not easy to implement. We note this limitation, and leave the collusion endogeneity analysis as a future work.

  19. We are grateful to an anonymous referee for pointing this out. Of course, though, as we do not have all bidding data except the winner’s, we should be cautious in making any assertive conclusion.

  20. As an anonymous referee suggests, it would be ideal if we could follow-up these 82 ALB contracts to see what happens after the construction is complete. Our inability to do so due to our limited resources is noted.

  21. This is somewhat counter-intuitive, considering a lowest price auction would naturally attract more price-ALB. We conjecture the reasons are as follows. First, in Korean procurement market, the weight on construction plan score is quite lower than price score. Choi and Lee (2012) explains that Korean government prefers low weight on construction plan score because such a subjective evaluation may attract a dispute on fairness. Second, ALB could occur to make up the bidder’s low construction plan score in a turn-key type bidding. As we only detect price-ALB, such a drastic reduction of price in turn-key type bidding is identified as ALB, regardless of the quality score. As we mentioned in Introduction, this is a limitation of our approach.

References

  • Albano, G.L., Bianchi, M. and Spagnolo, G. (2006). Bid average methods in procurement. Rivista di Politica Economica 2006 (1–2), 41–62 reprinted in Economics of Public Procurement, Palgrave-MacMillan.

  • Albano, G.L., Dini, F., Zampino, R. (2009). Bidding for complex projects: Evidence from Italian Government’s Acquisitions of IT Services. In Proceedings of the 8th International Conference on Electronic Government (eds) by M.A. Wimmer, H.J. Scholl, M. Janssen and R. Traunmuller, Springer-Verlag, 353–363.

  • Albano, G.L. (2017). Competition in public procurement markets. Working Party No. 2 on Competition and Regulation, Directorate for Financial and Enterprise Affairs Competition Committee, OECD.

  • Alexandersson, G., & Hultén, S. (2006). Predatory bidding in competitive tenders: A Swedish case study. European Journal of Law and Economics, 22(1), 73–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allahbakhsh, M., Ignjatović, A., Benatallah, B., Beheshti, S., Bertino, E., and Foo, N. (2013). Collusion detection in Online Rating Systems. APWeb 2013 : Web Technologies and Applications, 196–207.

  • Ballesteros-Pérez, P., González-Cruz, M. C., & Cañavate-Grimal, A. (2013). On competitive bidding: Scoring and position probability graphs. International Journal of Project Management, 31, 434–448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ballesteros-Pérez, P., Skitmore, M., Pellicer, E., & González-Cruz, M. C. (2015). Scoring rules and abnormally low bids criteria in construction tenders: A taxonomic review. Construction Management and Economics, 33(4), 259–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bedford, T. (2009). Analysis of the low-bid award system in public sector construction procurement. Doctoral dissertation.

  • Burguet, R., Ganuza, J. J., & Hauk, E. (2012). Limited liability and mechanism design in procurement. Games and Economic Behavior, 76(1), 15–25.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Calveras, A., Ganuza, J. J., & Hauk, E. (2004). Wild bids. Gambling for resurrection in procurement contracts. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 26, 41–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpineti, L., Piga, G., & Zanza, M. (2006). The variety of procurement practice: Evidence from public procurement. In N. Dimitri, G. Piga, & G. Spagnolo (Eds.), Handbook of procurement. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chapela, J. G. (2019). Weight values, scoring rules and abnormally low tenders criteria in multidimensional procurement: Effects on price. Review of Public Economics, 228, 55–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chillemi, O., & Mezzetti, C. (2014). Optimal procurement mechanisms: Bidding on price and damages for breach. Economic Theory, 55(2), 335–355.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, M.S. (2010). Reform of lowest price bidding and low bid evaluation system. Construction Issue Focus, CERIK, May 2010 (in Korean).

  • Choi, M.S. and Y.S. Lee (2012). Reform of turn-key type bidding system in procurement procedure. Construction Issue Focus, CERIK, August 2012 (in Korean).

  • Choi, M. S. (2011). Reform of the low bid evaluation system in lowest price bidding. CERIK. Korean.

    Google Scholar 

  • Conley, T. G., & Decarolis, F. (2016). Detecting bidders groups in collusive auctions. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 8(2), 1–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Connor, J. (2007). Price-fixing overcharges: Legal and economic evidence. Research in Law and Economics: A Journal of Policy, Volume 22, (ed) b R.O. Zerbe and J.B. Kirkwood.

  • Conti, P. L., & Naldi, M. (2008). Detection of anomalous bids in procurement auctions. Decision Support Systems, 46(1), 420–428.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Leverano, A. (2019). Collusion through market sharing agreements: Evidence from Quebec’s Road Paving Market. In ZEW-Centre for European Economic Research Discussion Paper No.19–053.

  • Decarolis, F. (2018). Comparing public procurement auctions. International Economic Review, 59(2), 391–419.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Downing, S. (2004). Post-bid analysis for public works projects. AACE International Transactions, ES111.

  • Ellison, G. (1994). Theories of cartel stability and the joint executive committee. RAND Journal of Economics, 25, 37–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engle, A. R., Ganuza, J. J., Hauk, E., & Wambach, A. (2006). Managing risky bids. In N. Dimitri, G. Piga, & G. Spagnolo (Eds.), Handbook of procurement. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, R. A. (1936). The use of multiple measurements in taxonomic problems. Annals of Eugenics, 7, 179–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fuentes-Bargues, J. L., González-Cruz, M. C., & González-Gaya, C. (2016). Abnormally low tenders in non-pricing criteria: The need for control. Universal Journal of Management, 4(12), 659–669.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giuffrida, L. M., & Rovigatti, G. (2022). Supplier selection and contract enforcement: Evidence from performance bonding. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy. https://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldfeld, S. M., & Quandt, R. E. (1972). Nonlinear methods in econometrics. North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gunduz, M., and Karacan, V. (2008). Abnormally low tender problem in public works. In Proceedings of 2008 International Conference on Management Science and Engineering, 1748–1753.

  • Harrower, J. R. (1999). Prevention, detection and elimination of abnormally low tenders in the European construction industry. DG III Working Group on Abnormally Low Tenders, European Technical Contractors Committee for the Construction Industry.

  • Ibrahimi, O. (2017). Elements of abnormally low tenders: A comparative analysis of EU procurement directive and case law. European Journal of Economics, Law and Social Sciences, 1, 91–97.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jeong, J., & Lee, J. (2018). An economic analysis of abnormally low bids in public construction procurement market. The Korean Journal of Industrial Organization, 26, 23–70. in Korean.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karacan, H.V. (2008). Abnormally lowest bids in public construction works. M.S. thesis, Civil Engineering Department, Middle East Technical University.

  • Kiefer, N. M. (1980). A note on switching regressions and logistic discrimination. Econometrica, 48, 1065–1069.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, J., Kim, J. J., & Jeong, J. (2022). An empirical assessment of collusion in the negotiable certificates of deposit market in Korea: A discriminant analysis. Asian Economic Journal, 36, 203–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, L., & Porter, R. H. (1984). Switching regression models with imperfect sample separation information-with an application on cartel stability. Econometrica, 52, 391–418.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • McAfee, R. P., & McMillan, J. (1987). Auctions and bidding. Journal of Economic Literature, 25, 699–738.

    Google Scholar 

  • Megremis, A. (2013). Abnormally low tenders: Objectifying detection. Working towards economically sustainable procurement through a framework for the contracting authority to objectify the detection of abnormally low bids, TUDelft.

  • OECD. (2016). Abnormally low tenders. SIGMA Brief 35: Public Procurement, September 2016.

  • Palshikar, G., & Apte, M. M. (2008). Collusion set detection using graph clustering. Data Mining and Knowledge Discovery, 16, 135–164.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Porter, R. H. (1983). A study of cartel stability: The joint executive committee, 1880–1886. Bell Journal of Economics, 14, 301–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quandt, R. E., & Ramsey, J. (1978). Estimating mixtures of normal distributions and switching regressions. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 73, 730–738.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt, P. (1982). An improved version of the quandt-ramsey MGF estimator for mixture of normal distributions and switching regressions. Econometrica, 50, 501–516.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Skitmore, R. M. (2002). The probability of tendering the lowest bid in sealed auctions: An empirical analysis of construction data. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 53(1), 47–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skitmore, R. M. (2004). Predicting the probability of winning sealed bid auctions: The effects of outliers on bidding models. Construction Management and Economics, 22(1), 101–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spiller, P. T., & Huang, C. J. (1986). On the extent of the market: Wholesale Gasoline in the Northeastern United States. Journal of Industrial Economics, 35, 131–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • UN. (2005). Possible revisions to the UNCITRAL Model Law on Procurement of Goods, Construction and Services— drafting materials for the use of electronic reverse auctions in public procurement,” Working Group I (Procurement), United Nations Commission on International Trade Law, Eighth session Vienna, 7–11 November 2005, A/CN.9/WG.I/WP.40/Add.1.

  • Waehrer, K. (1995). A model of auction contracts with liquidated damages. Journal of Economic Theory, 67(2), 531–555.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wambach, A., & Engel, A. R. (2011). Surety bonds with fair and unfair pricing. The Geneva Risk and Insurance Review, 36(1), 36–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2016). Abnormally low bids and proposals. Procurement Guidance, July 2016.

  • Zheng, C. Z. (2001). High bids and broke winners. Journal of Economic Theory, 100(1), 129–171.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Jin S. Cho, Yun J. Choi, Jiyoung Lee, the participants of Yonsei School of Economics Wednesday Seminar, and two anonymous referees for their helpful advice and comments. We also thank Construction Association of Korea (CAK) for the valuable data. This study was partially funded by the National Research Foundation of Korea (Grant Number NRF-2016S1A3A2923769). The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Funding

This study was partially funded by the National Research Foundation of Korea (Grant Number NRF-2016S1A3A2923769).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jinook Jeong.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors do not have any conflict of interest.

Ethical approval

This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the authors.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 6 and 7.

Table 6 Comparison of competitive bids and colluded bids
Table 7 Comparison by estimated posterior probability of ALB

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Jeong, J., Lee, H. & Kim, J.J. An econometric identification of abnormally low bids in the procurement market: discriminant analysis. J. Ind. Bus. Econ. 51, 211–234 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40812-023-00257-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40812-023-00257-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation