Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

How do new entrepreneurs innovate?

  • Published:
Economia e Politica Industriale Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper builds upon Pellegrino et al. (Struct Chang Econ Dyn 23:329–340, 2012) further analysing the determinants of product innovation in Italian young innovative companies (YICs) by looking at in-house and external R&D and at the acquisition of external technology in its embodied and disembodied components. A Tobit approach is applied to study jointly the occurrence of product innovation and the intensity of such innovation. Results provide evidence that in-house R&D is linked to product innovation both in mature firms and YICs; however, YICs turn out to be less in-house R&D-based and, unlike their mature counterparts, more dependent on external sources of knowledge. While this outcome corroborates and further reinforce what found—using a different methodology—in Pellegrino et al. (Struct Chang Econ Dyn 23:329–340, 2012), in this study, other entrepreneurial attitudes such as the ability to cooperate with other firms in producing innovation or the capacity to develop significant organizational changes are also investigated. The results of the econometric estimations show that these attitudes turn out to be key innovative strategies in the incumbent firms but, in some specific cases (such as for the ability to cooperate), appear to be far less important in the YICs. These results are somehow worrying, since they show that Italian innovative entrepreneurs are mostly driven by routinized rather than creative strategies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For example, several EU member states have introduced new measures to support the creation and growth of YICs, especially by improving their access to funding (see BEPA 2008; Schneider and Veugelers 2010).

  2. For complementary interpretations of the transatlantic productivity gap, see Ortega-Argilés et al. (2011, 2014).

  3. Methodologically, this is well represented by the shift from the R&D-focused Frascati Manual (‘Guidelines for the collection of R&D data’, first published in 1963) to the Oslo Manual, published in the 1990 s (OECD 1997).

  4. The embodied nature of technological progress was originally discussed by Salter (1960) and Solow (1960); in particular, vintage capital models describe an endogenous process of innovation in which the replacement of old equipment is the main way through which firms update their own technologies (see also Jorgenson 1966; Hulten 1992; Greenwood et al. 1997; Hercowitz 1998).

  5. See Nelson and Winter (1982) and Dosi (1988) for an extended and more articulated view of the innovative process across firms.

  6. A related stream of literature instead focuses the attention on the so-called ‘New Technology Based Firms’ (NTBFs, see Storey and Tether 1998; Colombo and Grilli 2005), where only YICs in the high-tech sectors are analysed.

  7. In this case, in contrast with risk aversion, organizational change is positively correlated with the entrepreneurial ability.

  8. Given the aims and scope of this paper, attention has been limited to the manufacturing sectors.

  9. Firm selection was carried out through a ‘one step stratified sample design’. The sample in each stratum was selected with equal probability and without reimmission. The stratification of the sample was based on the following three variables: firm size, sector, regional location. Technically, in the generic stratum h, the random selection of n_{h} sample observations among the N_{h} belonging to the entire population was realized through the following procedure:

    - A random number in the 0–1 interval was attributed to each Nh population unit;

    - Nh population units were sorted by increasing values of the random number;

    - Units in the first nh positions in the order previously mentioned were selected.

    Estimates obtained from the selected sample are very close to the actual values in the national population. The weighting procedure follows Eurostat and Oslo Manual (OECD 1997) recommendations: weights indicate the inverse of the probability that the observation is sampled. Therefore, sampling weights ensure that each group of firms is properly represented and correct for sample selection. Moreover, sampling weights help to reduce heteroscedasticity commonly arising when the analysis focuses on survey data.

  10. In fact, mergers and acquisitions may break the link between innovative inputs and outputs (a link that must be studied within the context of the same economic entity over time).

  11. Given that our aim is to analyze the nature of the relationships within the innovative process (and not, for example, the effect of different inputs in determining the probability of innovating), this data limitation does not raise a problem of selection bias in our context. Since we are interested in the internal mechanisms of the innovative process, we have to focus on a randomly-selected sample of innovative firms (that is, randomness must hold within the innovative sub-sample, not in comparison with the non-innovative one where such mechanisms are obviously absent). For a study based on a comparison between innovative and non-innovative Italian firms, see Parisi et al. 2006. Moreover, as Mairesse and Mohnen (2010) pointed out, since CIS data provides little information about non-innovating firms, in the absence of additional information about these firms obtained by merging the innovation survey data with other firm data, not much room is left to distinguish between innovators and non-innovators and to correct appropriately for potential selectivity biases.

  12. As far as the age of the firms in the ‘young firms’ sub-sample is concerned, the threshold of 8 years was chosen to take into account the trade-off between a lower age and the representativeness of the sub-sample of YICs (here more than 10 % of the entire sample). However, the estimates discussed in Sect. 4 were replicated using a larger sample of young firms no more than 10 years old. The results, available from the authors upon request, do not change substantially.

  13. The estimates will include three groups: science-based, specialised supplier and scale intensive firms, where the default category will be the low-technology group of the supplier dominated firms.

  14. We are aware of the limits deriving by the use of this variable as a proxy of risk aversion. However, taking into account the information provided by the CIS questionnaire, this variable represents the most accurate proxy at our disposal of the degree of firm’s risk aversion.

  15. In the "Appendix", Table 7 reports the correlation matrix; as can be seen, all the correlation coefficients are less than 0.245, showing that data are not affected by serious collinearity problems. Finally, Table 8 reports the CIS questions on the basis of which the variables were constructed.

  16. As discussed at in Sect. 3, the CIS3 data adopted are collected from a representative sample of Italian manufacturing firms with more than 10 employees; this means that micro firms (which however are very rarely innovative) are excluded from the dataset, while SMEs are fully included.

  17. This also explains the negative and significant coefficient of MAC in the estimate referring to the incumbents (second column of Table 4).

  18. However, this may simply be due to possible inaccuracy in the adopted proxy, the only one available in our dataset.

References

  • Acs, Z. J., & Audretsch, D. B. (1988). Innovation in large and small firms: An empirical analysis. The American Economic Review, 78, 678–690.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acs, Z. J., & Audretsch, D. B. (1990). Innovation and small firms. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acs, Z. J., Audretsch, D. B., & Feldman, M. P. (1994). R&D spillovers and recipient firm size. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 76, 336–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrighetti, A., & Vivarelli, M. (1999). The role of innovation in the post-entry performance of new small firms: Evidence from Italy. Southern Economic Journal, 65, 927–939.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1962). The economic implications of learning by doing. Review of Economic Studies, 29, 155–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. (2007). The entrepreneurial society. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D., & Thurik, R. (2000). Capitalism and democracy in the 21st century: From the managed to the entrepreneurial economy. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 10, 17–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barlet, C., Duguet, E., Encaoua, D., & Pradel, J. (2000). The commercial success of innovations: An econometric analysis at the firm level in French manufacturing. In D. Encaoua, B. H. Hall, F. Laisney, & J. Mairesse (Eds.), The economics and econometrics of innovation (pp. 435–456). Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Bartelsman, E., Haltiwanger J., Scarpetta, S. (2004). Microeconometric evidence of creative destruction in industrial and developing countries. IZA Discussion Paper No. 1374.

  • BEPA. (2008). Innovation and growth in the EU: The role of SME policy. Brussels: European Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breschi, S., Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (2000). Technological regimes and schumpeterian patterns of innovation. The Economic Journal, 110, 388–410.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bresnahan, T. F., Brynjolfsson, E., & Hitt, L. M. (2002). Information technology, workplace organization and the demand for skilled labor: Firm-level evidence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 339–376.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cassiman, B., & Veugelers, R. (2002). R&D cooperation and spillovers: Some empirical evidence from Belgium. American Economic Review, 92, 1169–1184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cefis, E., & Marsili, O. (2005). A matter of life and death: Innovation and firm survival. Industrial and Corporate Change, 14, 1167–1192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cefis, E., Rosenkranz, S., & Weitzel, U. (2009). Effects of coordinated strategies on product and process R&D. Journal of Economics, 96, 193–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, W. M., & Klepper, S. (1996). A reprise of size and R&D. Economic Journal, 106, 925–951.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. (1989). Innovation and learning: The two faces of R&D. Economic Journal, 99, S569–S596.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: New perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35, 128–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colombo, M. G., & Grilli, L. (2005). Founders’ human capital and the growth of new technology-based firms: A competence-based view. Research Policy, 34, 795–816.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crépon, B., Duguet, E., & Mairesse, J. (1998). Research, innovation and productivity: An econometric analysis at the firm level. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 7, 115–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G. (1988). Sources, procedures, and microeconomic effects of innovation. Journal of Economic Literature, 26, 1120–1171.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, C. (1982). The economics of industrial innovation (2nd ed.). London: Pinter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, C., Clark, J., & Soete, L. (1982). Unemployment and technical innovation: A study of long waves in economic development. London: Pinter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, C., & Soete, L. (1987). Technical change and full employment. London: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fritsch, M., & Franke, G. (2004). Innovation, regional knowledge spillovers and R&D cooperation. Research Policy, 33, 245–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert, R., & Newbery, D. (1982). Preemptive patenting and the persistence of monopoly. The American Economic Review, 72, 514–526.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood, J., Hercowitz, Z., & Krusell, P. (1997). Long-run implications of investment-specific technological change. American Economic Review, 87, 342–362.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1979). Issues in assessing the contribution of research and development to productivity growth. The Bell Journal of Economics, 10, 92–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1990). Patent statistics as economic indicators: A survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 28, 1661–1707.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hercowitz, Z. (1998). The ‘embodiment’ controversy: A review essay. Journal of Monetary Economics, 41, 217–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hitt, L. M., & Brynjolfsson, E. (2002). Information technology, organizational transformation, and business performance. In N. Greenan, Y. L’Horty, & J. Mairesse (Eds.), Productivity, inequality, and the digital economy. A transatlantic perspective (pp. 55–91). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hulten, C. R. (1992). Growth accounting when technical change is embodied in capital. American Economic Review, 82, 964–980.

    Google Scholar 

  • ISTAT. (2004). Statistiche sull’Innovazione delle Imprese. Settore Industria. Anni 1998–2000, Rome: ISTAT.

  • Jorgenson, D. W. (1966). The embodiment hypothesis. Journal of Political Economy, 74, 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kan, K., & Tsai, W. D. (2006). Entrepreneurship and risk aversion. Small Business Economics, 26, 465–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kihlstrom, R. E., & Laffont, J. J. (1979). A general equilibrium entrepreneurial theory of firm formation based on risk aversion. Journal of Political Economy, 87, 719–748.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. (1997). Entrepreneurial discovery and the competitive market process: An Austrian approach. Journal of Economic Literature, 35, 60–85.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lööf, H., & Heshmati, A. (2002). Knowledge capital and performance heterogeneity: A firm-level innovation study. International Journal of Production Economics, 76, 61–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lööf, H., & Heshmati, A. (2001). On the relationship between innovation and performance: A sensitivity analysis, In ECISStockholm school of economics, working paper series in economics and finance No. 446.

  • Mairesse, J., & Mohnen, P. (2002). Accounting for innovation and measuring innovativeness: An illustrative framework and an application. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 92, 226–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mairesse, J., & Mohnen, P. (2010). Using innovations surveys for econometric analysis. NBER Working Paper 15857.

  • Malerba, F. (1992). Learning by firms and incremental technical change. Economic Journal, 102, 845–859.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F. (2005). Sectoral systems: How and why innovation differs across sectors. In J. Fagerberg, D. C. Mowery, & R. R. Nelson (Eds.), The oxford handbook of innovation (pp. 380–406). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (1996). Schumpeterian patterns of innovation. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19, 47–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Michelacci, C. (2003). Low returns in R&D due to the lack of entrepreneurial skills. The Economic Journal, 113, 207–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Harvard: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (1997). Oslo manual: The measurement of scientific and technological activities. Paris: OECD, Proposed Guideline for Collecting and Interpreting Technological Innovation Data.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ortega-Argilés, R., Potters, L., & Vivarelli, M. (2011). R&D and productivity: Testing sectoral peculiarities using micro data. Empirical Economics, 41, 817–839.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ortega-Argilés, R., Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2014). The transatlantic productivity gap: Is R&D the main culprit? Canadian Journal of Economics (forthcoming).

  • Palich, L. E., & Bagby, D. R. (1995). Using cognitive theory to explain entrepreneurial risk taking: Challenging conventional wisdom. Journal of Business Venturing, 10, 425–438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parisi, M. L., Schiantarelli, F., & Sembenelli, A. (2006). Productivity, innovation and R&D: Micro evidence for Italy. European Economic Review, 50, 2037–2061.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. C. (2004). The Economics of Self-employment and Entrepreneurship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. (2008). The economics of formal business networks. Journal of Business Venturing, 23, 627–640.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pavitt, K. (1984). Sectoral patterns of technical change: Towards a taxonomy and a theory. Research Policy, 13, 343–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pellegrino, G., Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2012). Young firms and innovation: A microeconometric analysis. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 23, 329–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piga, C. A., & Vivarelli, M. (2003). Sample selection in estimating the determinants of cooperative R&D. Applied Economics Letters, 10, 243–246.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piga, C. A., & Vivarelli, M. (2004). Internal and external R&D: A sample selection approach. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 66, 457–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piva, M., Santarelli, E., & Vivarelli, M. (2005). The skill bias effect of technological and organisational change: Evidence and policy implications. Research Policy, 34, 141–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salter, W. E. G. (1960). Productivity and technical change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Santarelli, E., & Vivarelli, M. (2007). Entrepreneurship and the process of firms’ entry, survival and growth. Industrial and Corporate Change, 16, 455–488.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, C., & Veugelers, R. (2010). On young highly innovative companies: Why they matter and how (not) to policy support them. Industrial and Corporate Change, 19, 969–1007.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The theory of economic development. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. New York: Harper and Brothers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1960). Investment and technical progress. In K. J. Arrow, S. Karlin, & P. Suppes (Eds.), Mathematical methods in the social sciences (pp. 89–104). Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Storey, D. J., & Tether, B. S. (1998). New technology-based firms in the European Union: An introduction. Research Policy, 26, 933–946.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J., Pisano, G., & Shuen, A. (1997). Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, 18, 509–533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vivarelli, M. (2013). Is entrepreneurship necessarily good? Microeconomic evidence from developed and developing countries. Industrial and Corporate Change, 22, 1453–1495.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Tunzelmann, N., & Wang, Q. (2003). An evolutionary view of dynamic capabilities. Economie Appliquée, 16(3), 33–64.

    Google Scholar 

  • Von Tunzelmann, N., & Wang, Q. (2007). Capabilities and production theory. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 18, 192–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winter, S. G. (1984). Schumpeterian competition in alternative technological regimes. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 5, 287–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank Andrea Conte, Giovanni Seri and the ADELE Laboratory at ISTAT in Rome for the provision of CIS 3 data. Comments by the discussant Simon Parker and the other participants at the ‘1st Joint DIW Berlin/IZA Workshop on Entrepreneurship Research’ (Bonn, February, 25–26, 2010) led to significant improvements to the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mariacristina Piva.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 7 and 8.

Table 7 Correlation matrix
Table 8 The questionnaire

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Pellegrino, G., Piva, M. & Vivarelli, M. How do new entrepreneurs innovate?. Econ Polit Ind 42, 323–341 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40812-015-0015-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40812-015-0015-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation