Skip to main content
Log in

Restrictions of Competition in Licensing Agreements: The Worldwide Convergence of Competition Laws and Policies in the Field of Intellectual Property

  • Article
  • Published:
European Business Organization Law Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Competition law aims at promoting the competitive process by preventing anti-competitive practices, while IP law provides exclusive rights to authors and inventors. Although there are tensions between the two fields of law, they share the common goal of improving incentives for innovation. It is a difficult task for competition policymakers to determine the relationship between competition and exclusivity. In practice, the most important challenge concerns restrictions on competition in licensing agreements. This article aims to examine the existing approaches at the intersection of competition law and IP from a comparative perspective, focusing on the situation in the US, the EU and Korea. While differences exist, for example, as regards the abuse of market dominance, considerable convergence can be seen in the competition law treatment of licensing agreements. This development is welcome, because harmonisation in this field is particularly conducive to the international transfer of technology.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In the United States, the term antitrust law is used to indicate the body of law prohibiting anti-competitive practices. In many jurisdictions outside of the United States competition law is used in a more general sense. In this article, we will continue to use competition law, except when referring to US law.

  2. Carrier (2009), at p. 19.

  3. Cf. Hovenkamp (2011), at p. 260.

  4. For the EU, see European Court of Justice, Joint Cases C-241/91 P and C-242/91 P, RTE and ITP v. Commission (‘Magill’) [1995] ECR, I-743, para. 46: ‘So far as a dominant position is concerned, it is to be remembered at the outset that mere ownership of an intellectual property right cannot confer such a position.’ For US law, see the US Supreme Court, Illinois Tool Works v. Independent Ink, 547 U.S. 28 (2006), reversing the presumption resulting from older case law that a patent confers market power. See also the US Licensing Guidelines, at 2.2.

  5. See the ground-breaking study of Bowman (1973); for a more recent analysis, see Landes and Posner (2003), at p. 374. However, there are some criticisms of this property view. See, e.g., Gilbert (2008), at p. 524 et seq.

  6. For an overview of the changing concepts in the relationship between IP and competition law, see Abbott (2014).

  7. Dynamic efficiency usually means the gains from innovation and the emergence of new technologies. See Crane (2015), at p. 10.

  8. Lowe and Peeperkorn (2005), at p. 266. For the optimal intensity of competition, see Aghion et al. (2005).

  9. Sidak and Teece (2011), at p. 93.

  10. Myers (2007), at p. 3.

  11. See, e.g., Goyder and Albors-Llorens (2009), at p. 261.

  12. Leslie (2011), at p. 44. Leslie argues that the evolution of economic theories on how to balance the concerns of competition law and IP law has helped courts to issue more nuanced opinions on this subject.

  13. Ibid, at p. 41.

  14. Ibid, at p. 42.

  15. See supra n. 4.

  16. See, e.g., US Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission (2007), at p. 2. The degree of competition and innovation is deeply related to market entry. See also Geroski (1999), at p. 19.

  17. Heinemann (2008), at p. 78 et seq. Heinemann argues that the contestable market theory can justify IP protection and the limits resulting from competition law enforcement, which balances the pros and cons of each law.

  18. Teece (2011), at p. 221.

  19. Sometimes, US antitrust law is given credit as the first competition law of the modern world. In fact, Canada adopted a competition law in 1889 (i.e., one year earlier than the Sherman Act in the US), although this law never achieved a status comparable to that of the Sherman Act, see Gerber (2010), at p. 259.

  20. Wilson (1970); Carrier (2009), at p. 77.

  21. See, e.g., ABA (2007), at p. 77; Gavil et al. (2008), at p. 1195. The Nine No-Nos were: (i) tying of unpatented to patented products; (ii) mandatory grantbacks; (iii) post-sale resale restrictions; (iv) tie-outs (restricting a licensee’s ability to deal in products outside the scope of the patent); (v) exclusive licensing; (vi) mandatory package licensing; (vii) compulsory payment of royalties not reasonably related to sales of the patented product; (viii) restrictions on sales of unpatented products made by a patented process; and (ix) utilising vertical price fixing involving the licensing of patented products.

  22. Myers (2007), at p. 79.

  23. Carrier (2009), at p. 77; Leslie (2011), at pp. 42-43; Sprigman (2012), at p. 351.

  24. Choi (2011), at p. 122.

  25. US Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property, available at https://www.justice.gov/sites/default/files/atr/legacy/2006/04/27/0558.pdf, accessed 15 July 2015.

  26. Leslie (2011), at p. 45.

  27. However, some argue that the self-assessment framework in the context of a safe harbour generates problems of legal uncertainty, because neither market definition nor the evaluation of efficiencies is an exact science. See Kuik (2007), at p. 170.

  28. This type of restraint includes hard-core restrictions, such as price fixing and output restriction.

  29. Sec. 3.2.2 of the US Guidelines, supra n. 25, explains that ‘[t]echnology markets consist of the intellectual property that is licensed … and its close substitutes − that is, the technologies or goods that are close enough substitutes significantly to constrain the exercise of market power with respect to the intellectual property that is licensed’.

  30. Sec. 3.2.3 of the US Guidelines, supra n. 25, clarifies that ‘[a]n innovation market consists of the research and development directed to particular new or improved goods or processes, and the close substitutes for that research and development’.

  31. Glader (2006), at p. 225.

  32. Sec. 5.1 of the US Guidelines, supra n. 25.

  33. For the ‘4-plus-test’, see Heinemann (2011b), at p. 203.

  34. See, e.g., ABA (2007), at p. 491.

  35. IP rights traditionally have been granted at Member State level, creating tensions between free trade and the competition rules of the EU. Not only the existence of national IP laws in each Member State but also the differences between them raise concerns because the diversity of laws can be detrimental to the objective of an EU internal market. See, e.g., Coates et al. (2014), at p. 1145; Jones and Sufrin (2014), at p. 847; Rose and Bailey (2013), at pp. 674–675; Whish and Bailey (2012), at p. 768. For further discussion about the problem of the internal market and IP in the EU, see Caggiano (2012), at p. 3 et seq.; Cornish et al. (2010), at p. 818 et seq.; Heinemann (2011a), at p. 303 et seq. See also the fundamental Cases 56 and 58/64 Consten and Grundig v. Commission [1966] ECR 299.

  36. Commission Regulation (EC) No 240/96 of 31 January 1996 on the application of Article 85(3) of the Treaty [now Article 101(3) TFEU] to certain categories of technology transfer agreements, OJ L 31/2.

  37. Commission Regulations (EEC) No 2349/84 of 23 July 1984 and 556/89 of 30 November 1989. In particular, the emergence of complex cases of patent licences in the 1970s seemed to bring about the thought of adopting regulations for technology transfer agreements. See, e.g., Greaves (1994), at p. 9; Korah (1996), at pp. 2–3; Ritter and Braun (2004), at pp. 791–792.

  38. Commission Regulation (EC) No 772/2004 of 27 April 2004 on the application of Article 81(3) of the Treaty to categories of technology transfer agreements, OJ L123/11.

  39. Anderman (2008), at p. 110. The legal framework of the TTBER demonstrates newly developed features: (i) a more economic focus of EU competition policy; (ii) the use of economic analysis; (iii) the offer of safe harbour-based legal certainty; and (iv) a procedural change in enforcement. See also Anderman and Schmidt (2011), at pp. 203–204.

  40. Commission Regulation (EU) No 316/2014 of 21 March 2014 on the application of Article 101(3) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union to categories of technology transfer agreements, OJ L93/17. For further detail about TTBER development, see also Goyder and Albors-Llorens (2009), at pp. 263–281; Anderman (2006), at pp. 76–89.

  41. For further details, see Korah (1996), at p. 158 et seq.

  42. See Drexl (2008), at p. 29; Fine (2006), at p. 50; Lowe and Peeperkorn (2005), at p. 278; Jones and Sufrin (2014), at p. 867.

  43. Armillotta (2010), at pp. 96–97.

  44. Guidelines on the application of Article 101 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union to technology transfer agreements, OJ C 2014 89/3 (hereinafter ‘TT Guidelines’).

  45. Art. 4 TTBER.

  46. See also Choi (2011), at p. 133.

  47. Arts. 6 and 7 TTBER.

  48. Armillotta (2010), at p. 103.

  49. KFTC Guidelines, Established Rule No. 205 (amended on 17 December 2014), available in English at http://eng.ftc.go.kr/bbs.do?command=getList&type_cd=62&pageId=0401, accessed 12 March 2015. For further detail, see also Choi (2011), at pp. 124–127.

  50. Law No. 13071, amended on 20 January 2015.

  51. For general information, see also Cheng (2012), at p. 504 et seq.; Choi (2011), at p. 125.

  52. See also Choi (2011), at p. 126.

  53. The Supreme Court of Korea held that the market share threshold in the Guidelines is not legally binding, and the KFTC can withdraw the relevant provision in individual cases. See Supreme Court of Korea, Judgment 2009Du9543, 25 November 2010.

  54. See, e.g., Ginsburg and Fraser (2011), at p. 49.

  55. Art. 4 MRFTA: the market share of a single undertaking is 50 % or more; alternatively, the combined market share of three or fewer undertakings is 75 % or more (with an exception for firms with a market share below 10 %).

  56. Art. V.1.Ga.(4) of the Guidelines for the Review of Unfair Trade Practices, amended on 12 August 2012, Established Rule No. 72 of the KFTC; Art. V.2.Ga.(2) of the Guidelines for Concerted Practice Review, amended on 20 August 2012, Established Rule No. 165 of the KFTC, the English version is available at http://eng.ftc.go.kr/bbs.do?command=getList&type_cd=62&pageId=0401, accessed 16 March 2015.

  57. In particular, IP law ensures higher prices for recoupment by avoiding competition by imitation; on the other hand, competition law aims to promote lower prices by preventing anti-competitive business practices. See Gilbert and Weinschel (2008), at p. 2009.

  58. Myers (2007), at p. 3.

  59. Cotter (2015), at p. 132.

  60. See, e.g., Sullivan and Grimes (2006), at p. 843.

  61. Jones and Sufrin (2014), at p. 851. Some argue that the conflict between the two laws is exaggerated because of the problem of uncertainty that involves the optimal amount and scope of IP protection. Hovenkamp (2005), at p. 225.

  62. In particular, the development of the EU’s block exemption regulations is one of the important features of the modernisation of competition rules, which is based on the more economic approach. See, e.g., Mendelsohn and Rose (2001), at pp. 39–41.

  63. Jorde and Teece (1992), at p. 56. However, Sidak and Teece (2011), at pp. 61–64, argue that the market share criterion itself is not a clear proxy for an overall appraisal.

  64. Niels et al. (2011), at p. 172.

  65. Most cases concern the abuse of market dominance, such as Microsoft, Intel and Qualcomm, but cases on restrictive agreements, such as, e.g., reverse payments, also appear in numerous jurisdictions, e.g., Supreme Court of Korea, Judgment 2012Du24498, 27 February 2014.

  66. See, e.g., Cass and Hylton (2013), at p. 187.

  67. Nevo (2015), at p. 10.

  68. Kaplow (2015), at p. 345. Multi-sided platforms best exemplify this problem, because it is often difficult to measure substitutability regarding the different market sides. See, e.g., Evans and Schmalensee (2015), at p. 422.

  69. Nevo (2015), at p. 87.

  70. Pleatsikas and Teece (2001), at p. 108.

  71. Ibid, at p. 111. However, it may be useful to transform the SSNIP into an SSNDQ (small but significant non-transitory decrease in quality) test for the purpose of ‘free’ internet markets: this new test allows a determination of substitutability when prices are not available or non-existent but variations in quality will be important for demand, see Gebicka and Heinemann (2014), at p. 156 et seq.

  72. Gavil et al. (2008), at p. 1173.

  73. The term ‘new economy’ refers to the newly developed industries, including computer software, internet-based business, and communication services. The new-economy industries can be characterised by falling average costs over outputs, high rates of innovation, easy entry and exit, and considerable economies of scale and scope. See Posner (2001), at p. 925; Landes and Posner (2003), at p. 390.

  74. Gavil et al. (2008), at pp. 1155–1156.

  75. See, e.g., Gotts (2013), at p. 162.

  76. Ibid, at p. 180.

  77. Anderman (2012), at p. 466; Lowe and Peeperkorn (2005), at p. 281.

  78. See also Jones and Sufrin (2014), at p. 881.

  79. See, e.g., Heinemann (2012), at p. 57.

  80. Jones and Sufrin (2014), at p. 867.

  81. Teece (2011), at p. 222.

  82. Anderman (2008), at pp. 117–118.

  83. See supra n. 33.

  84. All this is explained in more depth in the European TT Guidelines, supra n. 44, note 79 et seq.

  85. Bohannan and Hovenkamp (2012), at p. 1; Carrier (2009), at p. 1.

  86. Gavil et al. (2008), at p. 1153.

  87. See, e.g., Sullivan and Grimes (2006), at p. 841.

  88. Teece (2011), at p. 208.

  89. See, e.g., Czapracka (2009), at p. 1 et seq.

  90. Sec. 2.0 of the US Guidelines, supra n. 25; Carrier (2009), at p. 81.

  91. Carrier (2009), at p. 3.

  92. See, e.g., Sidak and Teece (2011), at p. 57.

  93. See, e.g., Bohannan and Hovenkamp (2012), at p. 9. The choice and balance between monopoly and competition is crucial for competition policymakers; IP guidelines determine the level of market power, and respectively, exclusivity which maximises the incentives to innovate.

  94. See, e.g., Kuik (2007), at p. 143.

  95. See, e.g., Jerez (2015), at p. 352 et seq.

  96. See, e.g., Ginsburg and Fraser (2011), at p. 42.

References

  • Abbott AF (2014) The evolving IP–antitrust interface in the USA—the recent gradual weakening of patent rights. J Antitrust Enforcement 2:363–388

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Bloom N, Blundell R, Griffith R, Howitt P (2005) Competition and innovation: an inverted-U relationship. Quart J Econ 120:701–728

    Google Scholar 

  • American Bar Association (ABA) (2007) Intellectual property and antitrust handbook. ABA Publishing, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderman S (2006) EC competition law and intellectual property rights: the regulation of innovation. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderman S (2008) The new EC competition law framework for technology transfer and IP licensing. In: Drexl J (ed) Research handbook on intellectual property and competition law. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, Northampton

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderman S (2012) Innovation, IPRs and EU competition law: cross currents in the EU/US debate. In: Ezrachi A (ed) Research handbook on international competition law. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, Northampton

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderman S, Schmidt H (2011) EU competition law and intellectual property rights: the regulation of innovation, 2nd edn. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Armillotta M (2010) Technology pooling licensing agreements: promoting patent access through collaborative IP mechanisms. Nomos, Baden-Baden

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bohannan C, Hovenkamp H (2012) Creation without restraint: promoting liberty and rivalry in innovation. Oxford University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bowman W (1973) Patent and antitrust law—a legal and economic appraisal. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Caggiano G (2012) Competition and regulation of intellectual property rights for the achievement and functioning of the internal market. In: Caggiano G, Muscolo G, Tavassi M (eds) Competition law and intellectual property: a European perspective. Wolters Kluwer, Alphen aan den Rijn

    Google Scholar 

  • Carrier MA (2009) Innovation for the 21st century. Oxford University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cass RA, Hylton KN (2013) Laws of creation: property rights in the world of ideas. Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheng TK (2012) The patent-competition interface in Asia: a regional approach? In: Ezrachi A (ed) Research handbook on international competition law. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, Northampton

    Google Scholar 

  • Choi YS (2011) A study of competition law and intellectual property in the EU: comparative perspectives in licensing agreements. Journal of Intellectual Property 6:109–145

    Google Scholar 

  • Coates K, Kjølbye L, Peeperkorn L (2014) Intellectual property. In: Faull J, Nikpay A (eds) The EU law of competition, 3rd edn. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornish W, Llewelyn D, Aplin T (2010) Intellectual property: patents, copyright, trademarks and allied rights, 7th edn. Sweet & Maxwell, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Cotter TF (2015) Innovation and antitrust policy. In: Blair RD, Sokol DD (eds) The Oxford handbook of international antitrust economics, vol 2. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Crane DA (2015) Rationales for antitrust: economics and other bases. In: Blair RD, Sokol DD (eds) The Oxford handbook of international antitrust economics, vol 1. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Czapracka K (2009) Intellectual property and the limits of antitrust: a comparative study of US and EU approaches. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Drexl J (2008) Is there a ‘more economic approach’ to intellectual property and competition law? In: Drexl J (ed) Research handbook on intellectual property and competition law. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, Northampton

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Evans DS, Schmalensee R (2015) The antitrust analysis of multisided platform businesses. In: Blair RD, Sokol DD (eds) The Oxford handbook of international antitrust economics, vol 1. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Fine FL (2006) The EC competition law on technology licensing. Sweet & Maxwell, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Gavil AI, Kovacic WE, Baker JB (2008) Antitrust law in perspective: cases, concepts and problems in competition policy, 2nd edn. Thomson/West, St Paul

    Google Scholar 

  • Gebicka A, Heinemann A (2014) Social media & competition law. World Competition 37:149–172

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerber DJ (2010) Global competition. Oxford University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Geroski PA (1999) Innovation as an engine of competition. In: Mueller DC, Haid A, Weigand J (eds) Competition, efficiency, and welfare. Kluwer Academic Publishers, The Hague

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert RJ (2008) Competition policy for intellectual property. In: Buccirossi P (ed) Handbook of antitrust economics. MIT Press, Cambridge MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert RJ, Weinschel AJ (2008) Competition policy for intellectual property: balancing competition and reward. In: ABA, Issues in competition law and policy. ABA Publishing, Chicago

  • Ginsburg DH, Fraser EM (2011) The role of economic analysis in competition law. In: McEwin RI (ed) Intellectual property, competition law, and economics in Asia. Hart Publishing, Oxford, Portland

    Google Scholar 

  • Glader M (2006) Innovation markets and competition analysis: EU competition law and US antitrust law. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gotts IK (2013) Market definition in the merger context: hard work pays off in the long-run. In: Hawk B (ed) International antitrust law and policy. Fordham Competition Law 2012. Juris Publishing, New York

  • Goyder J, Albors-Llorens A (2009) Goyder’s EC competition law, 5th edn. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Greaves R (1994) EC block exemption regulations. Chancery Law Publishing, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Heinemann A (2008) The contestability of IP-protected markets. In: Drexl J (ed) Research handbook on intellectual property and competition law. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, Northampton

    Google Scholar 

  • Heinemann A (2011a) Intellectual property rights and market integration. In: Anderman S, Ezrachi A (eds) Intellectual property and competition law: new frontiers. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Heinemann A (2011b) The impact of innovation—comments on Uwe Cantner and Wolfgang Kerber. In: Drexl J, Kerber W, Podszun R (eds) Competition policy and the economic approach: foundations and limitations. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, Northampton

    Google Scholar 

  • Heinemann A (2012) Intellectual property rights and merger control: how to secure incentives to innovate in the long run. In: Caggiano G, Muscolo G, Tavassi M (eds) Competition law and intellectual property: a European perspective. Wolters Kluwer, Alphen aan den Rijn

    Google Scholar 

  • Hovenkamp H (2005) United States antitrust policy in an age of IP expansion. In: Hawk B (ed) International antitrust law and policy. Fordham Competition Law 2004. Juris Publishing, New York

  • Hovenkamp H (2011) Federal antitrust policy: the law of competition and its practices, 2nd edn. Thomson/West, St Paul

    Google Scholar 

  • Jerez HV (2015) Competition law enforcement and compliance across the world: a comparative review. Wolters Kluwer, Alphen aan den Rijn

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones A, Sufrin B (2014) EU competition law: text, cases, and materials, 5th edn. Oxford University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Jorde TM, Teece DT (1992) Innovation, cooperation, and antitrust. In: Jorde TM, Teece DT (eds) Antitrust, innovation, and competitiveness. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplow L (2015) Market definition. In: Blair RD, Sokol DD (eds) The Oxford handbook of international antitrust economics, vol 1. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Korah V (1996) Technology transfer agreements and the EC competition rules. Clarendon Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuik K (2007) Treatment of horizontal agreements: the quest for legal certainty—the EC competition law approach to horizontal co-operation agreements. In: Amato G, Ehlermann CD (eds) EC competition law: a critical assessment. Hart Publishing, Oxford, Portland

    Google Scholar 

  • Landes WM, Posner RA (2003) The economic structure of intellectual property law. Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Leslie CR (2011) Antitrust law and intellectual property rights: cases and materials. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Lowe P, Peeperkorn L (2005) Singing in tune with competition and innovation: the new EU competition policy towards licensing. In: Hawk B (ed) International antitrust law and policy. Fordham Competition Law 2004. Juris Publishing, New York

  • Mendelsohn M, Rose S (2001) Guide to the EC block exemption for vertical agreements. Kluwer Law International, The Hague

    Google Scholar 

  • Myers G (2007) The intersection of antitrust and intellectual property: cases and materials. Thomson/West, St Paul

    Google Scholar 

  • Nevo H (2015) Definition of the relevant market: (lack of) harmony between industrial economics and competition law. Intersentia, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Niels G, Jenkins H, Kavanagh J (2011) Economics for competition lawyers. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Pleatsikas C, Teece D (2001) New indicia for antitrust analysis in markets experiencing rapid innovation. In: Ellig J (ed) Dynamic competition and public policy: technology, innovation, and antitrust issues. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner RA (2001) Antitrust in the new economy. Antitrust Law Journal 68:925–943

    Google Scholar 

  • Ritter L, Braun WD (2004) European competition law: a practitioner’s guide, 3rd edn. Kluwer Law International, The Hague

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose V, Bailey D (2013) Bellamy and Child European Union law of competition, 7th edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Sidak JG, Teece D (2011) Favouring dynamic competition over static competition in antitrust law. In: McEwin RI (ed) Intellectual property, competition law, and economics in Asia. Hart Publishing, Oxford, Portland

    Google Scholar 

  • Sprigman CJ (2012) The intersection of patent and antitrust law. In: Elhauge E (ed) Research handbook on the economics of antitrust law. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, Northampton

    Google Scholar 

  • Sullivan LA, Grimes WS (2006) The law of antitrust: an integrated handbook, 2nd edn. Thomson/West, St Paul

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece DJ (2011) Favoring dynamic over static competition: implications for antitrust analysis and policy. In: Manne GA, Wright JD (eds) Competition policy and patent law under uncertainty: regulating innovation. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission (2007) Antitrust enforcement and intellectual property rights: promoting innovation and competition. http://www.ftc.gov/reports/antitrust-enforcement-intellectual-property-rights-promoting-innovation-competition-report. Accessed 27 June 2015

  • Whish R, Bailey D (2012) Competition law, 7th edn. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson BB (1970) Patent and know-how license agreements: field of use, territorial, price and quantity restrictions. Address before the Fourth New England Antitrust Conference, 6 Nov 1970

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yo Sop Choi.

Additional information

Y. S. Choi: Assistant Professor of Law, Division of Language and Diplomacy.

A. Heinemann: Professor of Commercial, Economic and European Law, Vice-President of the Swiss Competition Commission. The views and opinions expressed in this article are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of the institutions to which he is affiliated.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Choi, Y.S., Heinemann, A. Restrictions of Competition in Licensing Agreements: The Worldwide Convergence of Competition Laws and Policies in the Field of Intellectual Property. Eur Bus Org Law Rev 17, 405–422 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40804-016-0046-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40804-016-0046-y

Keywords

Navigation