1 Introduction

A growing literature on fiscal federalism argues that political interests are crucial in the allocation of intergovernmental grants. There is a general concern that opportunistic incumbents at the central level tactically award grants to local governments in order to influence election outcomes. However, the empirical evidence is inconclusive as to which political type, partisan or opportunistic, is relevant and which group of voters, swing, with weak preferences (Lindbeck and Weibull 1987) or aligned (Cox and McCubbins 1986), is favored in designing transfer programs from national to subnational governments. There are conflicting explanations for this: according to Cox and McCubbins (1986), governments are risk averse and therefore favor their supporters, while according to Lindbeck and Weibull (1987), incumbents support “swing” voters because they respond much more quickly to any stimulus. In a later work, Bracco et al. (2015) find that an incumbent interested in electing his or her local colleagues has an incentive to shift the distribution to aligned jurisdictions with high electoral competition. Political alignment, i.e., whether the local politician belongs to the same party or coalition as the central government, is a central concept in this part of the literature. A drawback of these studies is the assumption that the central government acts as the sole decision maker, while de facto many stakeholders are involved.

Indeed, incumbents have different incentives to negotiate spending policies when their party has a majority than when they need the support of the other parties in the legislature to pass the budget (Roubini and Sachs 1989). The fragmentation of majority and opposition thus also plays a role in explaining the redistribution of resources. Then, we assume that the degree of opposition fragmentation is an important part of the political context that alters the intensity of votes against incumbent parties and makes a significant difference in the pattern of electoral competition.

Moreover, because the central government and subnational governments may be involved in a bargaining game in which the latter may prevent the central government from implementing desired policies or impede central initiatives, we expect that fragmentation at the regional level will also play a role and that politically fragmented regional governments will be favored.Footnote 1 In this case, the central government may have to engage in political bargaining and offer benefits to gain the support of defiant subnational units (Tsebelis et al. 2002; Samuels and Mainwaring 2004).

Yet despite the fact that various strands of the literature have provided evidence that either variable-fragmentation or alignment-seems to explain government transfers alone, however, as far as we know, the interaction between fragmentation and partisan alignment at different levels of government has never been studied. This paper brings the above issues together in a single framework by examining whether the effect of political alignment is affected by political fragmentation in a multi-level government. In examining the strategic interaction between the central government and regional governments, our approach extends the empirical evidence of redistributive policies from discretionary government spending to quasi-formula-based intergovernmental grants.Footnote 2 This approach, which emphasises the importance of institutional details, makes single-country analysis a valid alternative to cross-country samples. An important advantage of using subnational data is that budgeting institutions are usually the same for all units considered. These similar institutional structures avoid bias due to omitted variables at the country level and allow the study of larger samples. Italian multilevel governance is an excellent example because intergovernmental health grants on a quasi-formula basis play an important role in funding subnational governments.Footnote 3 Because both formula and total central government funding are predetermined, the distribution of national funds among regions should be automatic. In practice, a quasi-formula mechanism does not eliminate the arbitrariness that makes politically motivated grant-making possible.

Our work contributes to these strands of literature by showing that the central government allocates more resources to aligned regions, especially those that are more fragmented ( Alignment Fragmented Premium).

Using a dataset of Italian regions between 2001 and 2011 constructed from primary sources, this study provides an extension of previous analyses and overcomes (in part) the inherent problems of low variability of other fragmentation indices with fixed effects estimators by using an innovative measurement formulation based on Golosov (2010) that better “accounts for the relative sizes of parties” (Golosov 2010, p. 173). Fixed effects estimators and Panel Corrected Standard Errors (hereafter PCSE) developed by Beck and Katz (1995, 1996) are used to construct robust coefficient covariances for panel-corrected residuals.Footnote 4

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The following section reviews the literature on the political use of intergovernmental transfers and government fragmentation and derives the hypotheses to be tested using Italy as an example. Section 3 provides some background information on the Italian system, such as government and electoral institutions as key determinants of health financing. The data and empirical strategy are described in Sect. 4. Section 5 reports the regression results and discusses their implications. Section 6 provides several robustness checks and Sect. 7 concludes.

2 Literature Review and Theoretical Considerations

Government transfers are one of the most important instruments related to federal systems. According to the classic literature on public finance, transfers are important to finance public expenditures that generate positive externalities that, if financed by local governments alone, might be provided at suboptimal levels (see, for example, Musgrave 1959; Oates 1972; Rosen and Gayer 2014). Another justification is the collection of inefficient local taxes in the absence of a centralized mechanism of taxation and distribution. Finally, the equity argument states that imbalances among local units must be corrected by policies at higher levels of government. Regardless, this part of the literature on government transfers considers normative reasons as the main criterion for allocating these funds. In practice, factors other than normative ones may influence government transfers.

A growing strand of the political economy literature examines how incumbents use intergovernmental transfers for strategic purposes. The central idea of this approach is that political parties and candidates instrumentalize redistributive measures to maximize their electoral outcomes, independent of other normative or efficiency considerations. This compelling argument, made in Argentina by Porto and Sanguinetti (2001), has proven equally valid in other contexts, particularly during national electoral campaigns (Alesina et al. 1997).

Interestingly, while any grant can affect the electoral outcome of incumbents, timing matters, as voters seem to reward grants made just before an election more than those made earlier in the election cycle (Veiga and Veiga 2013). To appear more attractive to voters, national governments transfer more funds to districts in election years. These funds are highly productive because they raise awareness of policies (Baleiras and da Silva Costa 2004; Drazen and Eslava 2005). In central election years, however, the returns to purchasing political capital in this way would be offset by the direct political benefits of central spending, so grants should decline (Worthington and Dollery 1998). In this scenario, it is likely that the “strength” of the government (majority or minority, as measured by tenure) plays an important role in determining the budget outcomeFootnote 5 and bargaining power of regional governments.

Previous empirical research has shown that it takes time to build networks of relationships and loyalties within the administrative branches of central government responsible for distributing grants. Therefore, it is likely that regional governments that have been in office for a long time lobby more effectively and receive more transfers from the central government. Specific local considerations also play a role. In addition, a government’s policy decisions may also be influenced by the presence of multiple decision makers. Therefore, coalition governments representing multiple parties with different interests can be expected to have difficulty achieving the consensus needed to implement policies. As Perotti and Kontopoulos (2002) note, each member of a coalition has an incentive to increase spending on its constituents because it internalizes only a small portion of the costs. This problem is exacerbated as the number of parties in the coalition increases, so that the share of costs internalized by each group decreases as the number of groups increases ( “Law of 1/n”).

It follows that the smaller the number of parties and the greater the bargaining power of the coalition, the easier it is to reach a cooperative solution (Olson 1993). It follows that a coalition has less political power when it is more fragmented.Footnote 6 One can hypothesize that political fragmentation might affect the distribution of grants (Padovano 2012), as more fragmented government majorities would require more central government leniency toward regional governments to “buy” their support.Footnote 7

Indeed, when there is a large number of opposition parties, their interests may diverge and it may be difficult to coordinate to oppose the government’s proposals. As for a fragmented government, it would therefore be difficult for a fragmented opposition to achieve political consensus and political commitment, so government decision-making may not be monitored (Padovano and Venturi 2001; Ricciuti 2004). With a divided opposition, a government can implement a particular policy not only successfully but also without opposition. In short, fragmented opponents favor the central government by reducing the political costs of a policy, while a united opposition poses a greater threat to incumbents that can shorten their tenure.

Since the allocation of grants is the result of a bargaining process between competing interests, whether a national or subnational government is united or fragmented makes a difference to the outcome of the allocation. As plausible as this argument may be, the literature has so far almost completely neglected this side (the opposition) of the bargaining game in grant allocation. Our hypothesis is:

Hypothesis 1: The higher the fragmentation of the majority coalition (opposition), the higher (lower) the level of derived funding.

This hypothesis is tested on the distribution of health care resources among Italian regions, because only health care expenditures, which account for almost two-thirds of regional expenditures, are subject to an equalization mechanism implemented through the National Health Fund.Footnote 8 The Fund de facto allocates resources to the regions on the basis of a quasi-formula based on a negotiation process between the regional governments and their counterparts in the central government (the Ministries of Health and Finance), which takes place within the framework of the Conference of State Regions.

While the above literature shows that government fragmentation plays a role in explaining the redistribution of resources, it does not make clear the mechanism that drives strategic allocation. The literature offers two alternative arguments for how transfers are targeted based on the political characteristics of recipient groups. The first is based on the theoretical (Cox and McCubbins 1986) “core voter model”, i.e. supporters with strong party attachment. In this model, risk-averse political candidates favor their supporters “just as risk-averse investors tend to invest in low-risk securities” (Cox and McCubbins 1986, p. 385). The second argument relies on the “swing voter model” of Lindbeck and Weibull (1987) i.e. voters who are more likely to switch their vote because of certain advantages. Then two parties (or two blocs of parties) maximize their vote shares by tactically redistributing grants to constituencies with many swing voters who show no apparent loyalty to either party. Incumbent parties will continue to invest resources in districts until they reach the point where swing voters decide to vote for them. Therefore, the election outcome is assumed to depend on how much a constituency receives from the center.Footnote 9

Multi-level systems of government open up new dimensions in the study of how resources are misallocated to influence election outcomes. Politically aligned levels of government can improve the efficiency of distributive practices (Bracco et al. 2015). These mechanisms prompted empirical analyses with mixed findings. Ade and Freier (2013) find no local alignment effects in European and German parliamentary elections. According to Glaurdić and Vuković (2017), parties in power at the national level do not necessarily reward areas where they win, but only those where they gain vote share in each election. In Indonesia, Gonschorek et al. (2018) find that districts with low support for the president received significantly more grants than districts with core support, especially in the year of the national election. “These districts are politically promising investment opportunities. If reelection is no longer an option, this investment motive is absent” (Gonschorek et al. 2018, p. 252).

Instead, there is evidence of alignment effects in Spain (Solé-Ollé and Sorribas-Navarro 2008), Germany (Baskaran and Hessami 2017) and Portugal (Migueis 2013). Research providing evidence of alignment effects includes Banful (2011), who finds that Ghanaian districts receive higher allocations when the vote margin in the last presidential election is smaller; Bracco et al. (2015), who provide empirical evidence that aligned municipalities receive higher grants, especially before elections.Footnote 10 Brollo and Nannicini (2012) who show that in Brazil, in close elections, mayors aligned with the president receive more funds than unaligned mayors; Sakurai and Theodoro (2020) who report evidence of co-partisan assistance at the gubernatorial level; Curto-Grau et al. (2018) who find that a mayor belonging to the party of the regional president obtains twice the amount in grants received by an opposition’s mayor; Psycharis et al. (2020) who find as well that mayors politically aligned with the incumbent government receive higher shares of grants; Lara E. and Toro M. (2019), who discover tactical distribution to municipalities in Chile, and Azulai (2018), who shows that political connections between ministers—not the president—and mayors are important in explaining the size of grants transferred.

More recently, Baerlocher and Schneider (2021) provide strong evidence that in Brazil federal officials who are politically aligned with the executive branch transfer their discretionary grants more quickly than their politically unaligned counterparts; Ferreira et al. (2021) find that the alignment between municipal and federal chief executives is crucial to the allocation of grants; Ahmad (2021) find that in India relatively higher per capita transfers flow to states inhabited by large swing voters; Ha and Lee (2022) argues that in Korea, decentralised distribution is significantly affected by the partisan interests of central and local governments; and Jarocinska (2022) finds that regions with more loyal voters to the ruling party receive more grants per capita and that the partisan alignment of regional governments also plays a role. Thus, it emerges that, in Spain, the interaction between the central and subnational levels of government is a crucial variable and that party political alignment may play a central role in the allocation of intergovernmental transfers. We therefore formulate our second hypothesis:

Hypothesis 2: Central grants are higher for regions that are politically aligned with the central government.

An attempt to move a step further is offered by the political agency model elaborated by Arulampalam et al. (2009). They predict that upper-tier governments allocate more resources to lower-tier governments that are both aligned and relatively more swing (i.e., lower-tier governments in which the upper-tier ruling party faces greater political competition). Our results are consistent with the hypotheses, although not with the results of Arulampalam et al. (2009).

We argue that the alignment effect may be enhanced by the fragmentation of the subnational level of government. If this is the case, there may not be an “alignment premium” per se, but rather it varies with the fragmentation of regional government. National government leaders want to ensure that local leaders are loyal and motivated to achieve the party’s goals. Transferring funds to aligned local governments can increase the gratitude of local leaders and thus increase the incumbent’s chance of reelection. In a multiparty system where control of seats is fragmented, the distribution of specific benefits is an important means of attracting parties into the coalition and keeping them together (Baron and Ferejohn 1989). We then formulate the next hypothesis:

Hypothesis 3: Central government (and thus central grants) is biased in favor of regions that are simultaneously aligned and relatively more fragmented (Aligned fragmented premium).

We found that it is not the practice of partisan alignment itself but is the fragmentation of the aligned recipient government that affects the ultimate level of resources. We call this insight Aligned Fragmented Premium.

This literature on discretionary government spending, has mostly focused exclusively on the discretionary parts of the budget. However, Besley and Coate (2003, p. 2628) note that “even when spending is allocated formulaically, it is possible for legislators to manipulate such formulas to favor their own districts.” As Sorribas-Navarro (2011) note, in Spain, for example, regions receive additional grants because the formula that determines these funds can be renegotiated.

Further empirical evidence of politically motivated targeting in formula-based systems is provided by Litschig (2012) in Brazil, Banful (2011) and Fumey and Egwaikhide (2019) in Ghana, Abbott et al. (2017) in Mexico, and Foremny et al. (2017) in Spain. Moreover, the complexity of the formulas appears to increase the risk of political capture of the grant-awarding mechanisms (Banful 2011; Caldeira et al. 2012).

Despite the fact that all these factors may influence the strategic resource allocation of national incumbents, no efforts have been made to integrate the “alignment effect” with the political fragmentation approach in the same explanatory model in a quasi-formula-based grant allocation system. Italy provides an ideal case of study, as health grants allocated by the central government to the regions are rule-based but the allocation process involves a high degree of political bargaining.

3 Institutional Setup

The Italian National Health Service, INHS, is funded according to a typical sequential process. The central government determines the amount of funds allocated to the INHS, and the annual funding of each Regional Health Service is the result of a complex process and lengthy negotiations between the central government and the regional governments. The regions compete with each other, each pushing for the criteria that will benefit it the most in the allocation of available funds.Footnote 11

Although health care grants are officially described as rules-based, the way they are allocated seems to be rather quasi-discretionary, as much political bargaining is involved, both because the weighted capitation formula changes from year to year after negotiations between the regions and the center, and because the formula itself leaves some room for interpretation (Padovano 2014). To gain insight into the strategic relationship between the central government and the regions in the allocation of health care resources,Footnote 12 we summarize relevant background information on the Italian electoral system.

Italy is a unitary republic with a bicameral parliamentary system. Parliament consists of the Chamber of Deputies and the Senate. While the deputies are elected by universal and direct suffrage at the national level, the members of the Senate are elected by universal and direct suffrage at the regional level by voters who have reached the age of twenty-five. Elections are held every 5 years, unless Parliament is dissolved early.Footnote 13 The government of each region consists of three bodies—a council with legislative powers, an executive committee and its President.

The electoral system for regional elections follows a mixed-member logic. The regional council is elected at the same time as the president. Voters can express two votes on the ballot paper: they choose a candidate for the presidency in the majoritarian part, and a list that does not necessarily support that candidate and is running for seats in the legislative regional assembly in the proportional part. Separate voting is permitted. The majoritarian part of the electoral competition is the one that determines the main result of the elections, allocating the leadership of the executive and determining the majority in the legislative assemblies through a majority bonus. This premium ensures that the President can always count on a solid majority in the Council.Footnote 14

Each regional list is headed by a leading member who is the candidate of the coalition for the presidency of the regional council. He is elected directly by the voters. The President chairs the Regional Committee and appoints or dismisses its members, called Assessori, who may be elected from outside the Regional Council. When the directly elected president resigns, new elections are called. Regional elections were held in 2000 and 2005, in the years of interest (see Table 1).Footnote 15

Both the plurality system for the election of the President and the majority premium for the coalition supporting the winning presidential candidate have allowed a large number of parties to survive and have given a strong push to the bipolarization of the party system.

4 Empirical Strategy

The empirical analysis is based on a new and specifically assembled panel dataset consisting of annual observations of the Italian Ordinary Statute Regions, OSRs,Footnote 16 for the period 2001–2011. The variables and the data sources are presented in Table 2. The panel reflects data availability. Excluded from the empirical analysis are the five Regions with special Statute, RSSFootnote 17 because of their particular financing structure and spending autonomy, and because they have their own electoral laws.

Despite the differences among the 15 OSRs (in terms of size and number of political parties governing them, extension, density, age structure of the population, and GDP per capita, one advantage of restricting our empirical analysis to these regional governments is, that the budgetary institutions and the rules of government are the same for all the units considered, and therefore we avoid to some extent the problem of omitted unobserved variables explaining heterogeneity across different types of governments, and, as highlighted by Ashworth et al. 2005), this is an advantage of using subnational data. It is important to note that the database reflects not only data availability but also the fact that after 2011 it is not possible to capture the colour of the central government because we had only national coalition governments.Footnote 18

Table 1 Number of elections in Italian regions in the years of interest
Table 2 Variables’ description

4.1 Model Specification

In our framework, the same parties appear at both the state and the regional levels, and healthcare grants are seen as a strategic tool for central governments seeking reelection. This is true even in a formula-based system, as “it is possible for legislators to manipulate such formulas to favor their own districts” (Besley and Coate 2003, p. 2628). In Italy, for instance, the formula itself leaves some room for interpretation and the weighted capitation rate changes from year to year after negotiations between the regions and the center. Given this framework, our basic empirical model is:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \log ({\text {GRANTSPC}}_{it})&= \beta _{0} + \beta _{1} {\text {Regional }\text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Majority}}_{i (t-1)} + \beta _{2} {\text {Regional }\text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Opposition}}_{i(t-1)} \\&\quad +\beta _{3} \text {Aligned}_{i(t-1)} + \beta _{4}\text {Tenure}_{i(t-1)} + \beta _{5} \text {Regional Election}_{i(t-1)} \\&\quad + \beta _{6} \text {Control Variables}_{i(t-1)} + \beta _{7} \text {Time Trend}_{i(t-1)} + \alpha _{i} + \mu _{t} + \varepsilon _{it}\\ \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where the subscript i denotes regions and t is time in years. The dependent variable is the logarithmic transformation of fiscal transfers per region i and year t, in real per-capita terms, \(\log (\text {GRANTSPC})\). Total transfers include ex-post transfers distributed annually by the central government to cover regional healthcare deficits. The variable is forwarded one period to tackle the political delay in implementing the negotiated allocation of financial flows. This is consistent with the intuition that transfers to a region may adjust slowly and depend on the values of the previous year. This effect persists when different covariates are taken into account.

4.1.1 Effective Number of Parties: Index Construction

Given the prominent critiques of the Effective Number of Parties as formulated by Laakso and Taagepera , (Golosov 2010; Dunleavy and Boucek 2003; Kline 2009), we introduce a new and improved index based on Golosov (2010), \(ENP_{Gol}\). This index better “account(s) the relative sizes of parties” (Golosov 2010, p. 172) and better reflects the dominance of parties that win overall majorities. It is calculatedFootnote 19 on the seats each party has within a coalition, using the following formula:

$$\begin{aligned} ENP_{Gol} = \sum _{1}^{x}\dfrac{s_{i}}{s_{i} + (s_{1}^2) - s_i^2} \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where \(s_{i}\) is each party’s share of seats (or votes) and \(s_{1}^2\) is the square of the largest party’s share of seats (or votes). It considers the largest party as 1 and weights all other parties proportionally. Figure 1 illustrates how \(ENP_{Gol}\) provides a clearer distinction between more fragmented and concentrated political arenas when confronted with the Laakso and Taagepera index \(ENP_{ LT }\). Large values of \(ENP_{Gol}\) represent a diffuse political system in which multiple political parties share control of the government and electoral contests are fought by multiple parties; small values characterize a political system with few electoral competitors and a government controlled and run by few political parties. More pronounced polarization increases the variability of this index, clearly distinguishing between concentrated and highly fragmented coalitions and (partially) overcoming the inherent problems of low variability of fragmentation indices and fixed effects estimators. This property is particularly useful for our analysis because \(ENP_{Gol}\) takes into account the effective number of parties in the regional majority coalition, i.e. the degree of fragmentation of a government, Regional \(\text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Majority}\). The same methodology is also used to construct Regional \(\text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Opposition}\), which distinguishes between a united and a divided opposition.Footnote 20

Fig. 1
figure 1

Frequency distribution of the “Effective Number of Parties” in the regional majorities: Golosov (2010) vs Laakso and Taagepera (1979). Note: the Effective Number of Parties, calculated as in Golosov (2010), is confronted with the Laakso and Taagepera ’s index. The Golosov index offers a clearer distinction between more fragmented and concentrated political arenas

Our hypothesis is that the more fragmented the majority (opposition) coalition, the higher (lower) the derived health care funding. As expected, the sign of the variable is positive for Regional \(\text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Majority}\) and negative for Regional \(\text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Opposition}\). As pointed out by Mukherjee (2003), as the number of political parties represented increases, so does the number of special interests and voter groups represented. In this case, individual parties have stronger incentives to support spending on subsidies and transfers, as this provides more “pork” to meet the demands of their constituencies (Harrinvirta and Mattila 2001; Perotti and Kontopoulos 2002; Ricciuti 2004).Footnote 21

In our framework, the role of a united opposition holding the government accountable cannot be neglected. Like a fragmented government, a fragmented opposition would have difficulty achieving political consensus and commitment, and would therefore be unable to monitor government decision making (Padovano and Venturi 2001; Ricciuti 2004). Therefore, a government with a divided opposition may not only be able to pursue successful, short-term fiscal policy, but also remain unopposed.

4.1.2 Political and Control Variables

We include a number of political variables. The variable Aligned captures the “alignment effect”. A region is said to be aligned with a higher-level government if the party controlling the government at both levels is the same. In our framework, alignment status is captured by a dummy variable that equals 1 if the region’s president is supported by one of the parties in the coalition government (i.e., the central government). Otherwise, the variable equals zero. Another compelling line of research tests the argument that the ability to negotiate more resources and the intrusion of interest groups into government decisions is an increasing function of time. The variable Tenure—the number of years in office of a regional president—is a measure of lobbying processes and personal skills. The longer a (regional) government has been in office, the more effectively it can lobby the central government for higher grants. If a government has been in office for only a short time, it is not held accountable for the results of its policies, so the central government has less incentive to redistribute funds because it is not politically worthwhile. On the other hand, Tenure defines personal ability to negotiate more resources. This ability increases with tenure. The corresponding coefficient of this variable is also expected to be positive for Aligned.

Most empirical studies have provided evidence that “periodic fluctuations in a government’s fiscal policy are induced by the electoral cycle.” (Alt and Rose 2007).The political budget cycle is expressed by the variable Regional Election. It is predicted that incumbent politicians exploit information asymmetries to signal their competence to voters, e.g. by demonstrating their ability to produce public goods without raising taxes.

Transfers are then expected to be higher in election years as national politicians distribute grants to “buy” regional political capital with the aim of maximizing the probability of re-election. This effect is captured by the dummy variable Regional Election, which takes the value 1 if a region has elections in the second half of year t or in the first half of year \(t+1\) (zero otherwise).

Another set of control variables considers the impact of public finance, economic, and demographic determinants. The logarithmic transformation of regional GDP per-capita Regional GDP per-capita (log)—captures macroeconomic performance and conveys an “income effect.” We assume that transfers are negatively correlated with this variable, consistent with the equity-efficiency hypothesis of redistribution of public resources.

Demand effect is expressed by Population 75+ (%) , the proportion of people in a region who are 75 years and older. Health transfers are expected to be positively correlated with Population 75+ (%) and the unemployment rate (Regional Unemployment 15+ (\(\%\))). The logarithm of the regional real level of public health spending per-capita in the previous year, Regional Health Exp (log), tests for any effect of the previous years’ allocation on the current transfer level. It captures the so-called “spesa storica”, an incremental rule á la Wildavski, which is explicitly enshrined in Italian legislation.Footnote 22 The logarithm of the regional population, Regional Population (log), accounts for the presence of economies of scale. In addition, this variable accounts for the correlation between the size of the council and the fragmentation of the council itself. Council size correlates with population size, but also affects fragmentation (a 5% party would hardly elect anyone in a sparsely populated region with a small council size, but would certainly elect some representatives in heavily populated areas. In the case of Italy, it is particularly true that fragmentation has an institutional explanation (Chiaramonte 2007). First, electoral thresholds are generally low. More precisely, thresholds are high for parties that run in elections on their own, but less restrictive when small parties are part of large coalitions. The second reason is somewhat more subtle. As we have seen, voters in all regions can cast two votes, one for a presidential candidate (the majoritarian vote), the other for a party (the proportional vote). But they can also choose a single preference for a candidate or a party. If they choose the latter, the vote for the party is automatically transferred to the candidate supported by that party. This explains why coalitions have a strong incentive to field as many lists as possible, especially in close races. As it is particularly evident in populous regions, even small parties that have no hope of representation can muster the few votes that can be decisive for victory or defeat in a majority election.

A linear trend is also considered to model technological changes over time. We create region-specific trends (Time Trend), that imply that technological progress occurs at a steady pace specific to each region and correlates with regional GDP deflator growth.

Finally, the structurally adjusted deficit, Structural deficit, proxies the fiscal limits of the European Union. It traces any external constraint on the dynamics of the “common pool” in healthcare financing. For a qualitative description of each variable, see Table 2.

4.2 Methodology

To test whether the data have any problem, heteroskedasticity, serial autocorrelation and cross-sectional dependence are tested. Unfortunately, for panel data of this length,the tests developed by Wooldridge (2002), Pesaran (2004b), and Breusch and Pagan (1980) cannot be considered reliable for panel data of this length.Footnote 23

Cross-sectional dependence may occur due to omitted common effects or spatial dependence in regional data, typically observed in regional panel data (Pesaran 2015). It may be the result of local spill-over effects between countries or regions (Eberhardt and Teal 2011). Ignoring cross-sectional dependence can lead to misleading conclusions and inconsistencies (Pesaran 2015). From a purely economic perspective, however, it would be difficult to argue that there is no cross-sectional dependence and autocorrelation of the error when it is a bargained allocation of public funds. In particular, Italy is constrained by (international) financial boundaries at the EU level, and the central government is responsible for ensuring the general objectives and basic principles of the INHS, as well as for allocating national resources to the regions. It follows that each region receives an amount of resources that is influenced by the amount of funds received elsewhere, i.e. from all other regions. There is thus a (negative) cross-sectional dependency. For all these reasons, we apply to the estimated model the CD test, developed in Pesaran (2004a) and Pesaran (2015), as well as those Frees (1995) and Frees et al. (2004), which are tests for cross-sectional independence When N is large, this test, which takes into account the extent of dependence, may be more appropriate than the Breusch–Pagan LM test, which tests the extreme null hypothesis of independence. Moreover, the CD test proves to be powerful for both static and dynamic panels. The test rejects the null hypothesis of cross-sectional independence in favor of cross-sectional dependence, as can be seen in Table 5.Footnote 24

For all these reasons, we opt for the Panel Corrected Standard Errors, PCSE (Beck and Katz 1995), which are robust to the general form of heteroskedasticity, cross-sectional dependence, and autoregressive structure of the error.Footnote 25 Specifically, Monte-Carlo simulations show that this estimator performs well for small panel data (Beck and Katz 1995, p. 642).

Moreover, when it comes to constructing accurate confidence intervals with balanced panel data, that are characterized by Parks-style heteroskedasticity, serial correlation,Footnote 26 and cross-sectional dependence, Reed and Ye (2011) suggested either the Beck and Katz ’s Panel Corrected Standard Errors, PCSE estimator, or Pooled-OLS (with heteroskedasticity and cross-sectional dependence robust standard error).

Table 3 Fixed-effect regressions with XTPCSE standard errors

5 Estimation Results

5.1 Fixed Effect Estimates

The results of the preliminary fixed effects regressions can be found in Table 3. In this specification, we first analyse the effects of overall council fragmentation. To account for possible endogeneity bias due to omitted variables, we test whether regional-level fragmentation (which is not fully invariant in the time domain) is robust to a fixed effects specification, given the importance of controlling for unobserved region-specific effects that could simultaneously affect public resource redistribution and government fragmentation (Baskaran 2013, p. 357). In column (1) and column (2), we estimate a model without a control variable. \(\text {Regional ENP}_{Gol}^{Council}\) is relevant in magnitude and highly significant, as is the Tenure variable, and, to some extent, the effect of the political cycle captured by the Regional Election. No significant effect of the alignment effect is found. Adding year dummies (and assuming that the error term is not autocorrelated) as in column (2) does not seem to have a negative impact on the parameters, either in terms of magnitude or statistical significance. Because of possible collinearity with time-dependent dummies, the variable Regional Election is not included in column (2). Control variables are introduced in columns (3) and (4) and the same results are confirmed. As expected, the introduction of region-specific intercepts leads to a slight loss of statistical significance for the most serially correlated variables, such as \(\text {Regional ENP}_{Gol}^{Council}\). However, the magnitude of the coefficients does not appear to be noticeably affected. As for the coefficients of the control variables, only Regional GDP per-capita and Regional Unemployment 15+ (%) show a positive and statistically significant impact on the dependent variable.

Table 4 Fixed-effects regressions with XTPCSE standard errors
Table 5 Cross-sectional dependence of residuals test results
Table 6 Fixed-effect regressions with interaction terms
Table 7 Marginal effects on the derived per-capita financing on changes in the Effective number of parties conditioned on the “alignment effect”
Table 8 Robusteness checks

Table 4 shows the estimation results of several model specifications with time and region effects that break down council fragmentation into both \(\text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Majority}\) and \(\text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Opposition}\). If no time dummies are included, a common autoregressive structure of the error is assumed.Footnote 27 A region-specific trend is added to avoid collinearity and to proxy steady increase in per-capita financing due to technological change.Footnote 28 PCSE are chosen to handle cross-sectional dependence, heteroschedasticity, and autocorrelation in the error term. As expected, the introduction of region-specific intercepts results in a loss of statistical significance for the most serially correlated variables, such as those capturing fragmentation (Regional \(\text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Majority}\)) and the “alignment effect” (Aligned), and to a lesser extent the healthcare and economic variables.Footnote 29

In column (1) and column (2), we again estimate a model without control variables, allowing for fixed time effects only in the first column. While other parameters do not appear to be affected, the fragmentation effect of the Majority, which is driven by the variable—Regional \(\text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Majority}\)—has a positive and statistically significant effect on transfer flows. Moreover, the effect is larger than when considering total council fragmentation. The Model in column (2) shows a weak negative effect on transfer flows of the Opposition’s ENP Regional \(\text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Opposition}\). The effect is marginally significant and corresponds to a slight decrease in the statistical significance of the coefficient of the ENP of the majority.

As with the other political controls, the effect of the political cycle—via the dummy variable Regional Election—explains the 2.8% of the redistribution of health care grants. This result accounts for the possibility that strategic resource allocation could occur when electoral concerns are stronger (e.g., in the years leading up to elections). This result is consistent with the literature on political business cycles (Baleiras and da Silva Costa 2004; Drazen and Eslava 2005)

In the columns from (3) to (6) in Table 4, structural controls are added. As in model (3) and (4) in Table 3, the introduction of region-specific intercepts results in a slight loss of statistical significance for the highly serially correlated variables. As expected, the variable Structural deficit—which is time-variant but cross-sectionally invariant—is always negative and statistically significant.Footnote 30 This is evidence of the strong effect of the external budget constraint in containing the redistributive dynamics of the “common pool” consistent with Bordignon and Turati (2009). Conversely, the effective number of opposition parties- Regional \(\text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Opposition}\)Regional \(\text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Opposition}\)-does not perform very well except in Model 6 (Table 4), which includes fixed effects, time dummies, and control variables. We expect the final level of grants to be affected by the bargaining power of the opposition. It appears that the central government can impose its preferences when the opposition is fragmented (i.e., weaker). Our results only partially confirm our hypothesis.

When control variables such as the unemployment rate and GDP per-capita are added, some additional distortionary effects in the distribution of transfers become apparent. The positive coefficient on the unemployment rate—Regional Unemployment 15+ (\(\%\)) , a general proxy for the state of the economy—suggests the consequence of a countercyclical use of regional redistribution.Footnote 31 Contrary to expectations, the coefficient on GDP per-capita in Model 4 and Model 6 in Table 4 is positive and significant, suggesting that as regional GDP per-capita increases, grants to a region also increase. However, the reported results are consistent with the assumption that political influence is positively correlated with GDP per capita. These results reflect the greater influence that regions with high GDP exerted on the design of the grant distribution formula.

The alternative statistical significance of ENP in the majority and in opposition, particularly evident in column (6), is due to the interaction of two variables with low intertemporal variability and fixed time effect. The empirical analysis shows that majority fragmentation has a leading effect on the dependent variable that is larger in magnitude than the ENP at the council level. All in all, the results confirm that transfers to maximize returns in the form of votes are not targeted to areas where political support is concentrated (Cox and McCubbins 1986), but to areas where majorities tend to be fragmented. This finding adds a new and interesting result to the empirical literature. A previously neglected variable, the effective number of parties in the regional majority, is likely to be an important factor in explaining grant flows.

5.2 The Combined Effect of Alignment and Fragmentation

To further test whether the central government is biased in favor of the aligned regions and, among them, in favor of the relatively more fragmented regions, we used an interaction model to estimate what we call “the alignment fragmented premium” in Tables 6 and 7.

We consider the marginal effect of the continuous variable Regional \(\text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Majority}\) conditioned on the binary variable Aligned. The marginal effect, ME, of the ENP is calculated as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{\text {ME}}_{\text {Regional ENP}_{Gol}^{Majority}}= & {} \dfrac{\partial {\log (\text {F})} }{\partial \text {Regional ENP}_{Gol}^{Majority}}\nonumber \\= & {} {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \widehat{\beta }_{ \text {Regional ENP}_{Gol}^{Majority}} &{} \text {for Aligned} = 0 \\ \widehat{\beta }_{ \text {Regional ENP}_{Gol}^{Majority}} + \widehat{\beta }_{\text {Interaction}} &{} \text {for Aligned} =1\\ \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(3)

The standard errors of the MEs, calculated as in Brambor et al. (2006), are corrected for the presence of cross-sectional dependence.

The structure of Table 6 is the same as that of Table 4, with structural control variables included in each model specification and two different interaction effects added. The conditioned MEs of Regional \(\text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Majority}\) are given in Table 7 to account for the magnitude of the confidence interval, which is shown in Fig. 3 from column (1) to (4). The ME is positive and statistically different from zero only when the regional government is aligned with the central government. In particular, an additional party increases the level of per- capita funding on average from \(+ 1\%\) to \(+2\%\), ceteris paribus. Moreover, the presence of a political cycle confirms an additional financial premium of 2.8%. The positive effect of an additional year in office is confirmed, although it is still small in magnitude. The ME of the interaction in Model 1 (Table 6) is shown in Fig. 2. When the government are aligned, the estimated ME of an additional ENP (the punctual estimate is 1.4%) is very close to the results of the Pooled-OLS specification (1.5%) in the robustness checks in Sect. 6 (Table 8). It follows that central government (and hence central grants) is biased in favor of regions that are simultaneously aligned and relatively more fragmented. We call this Aligned Fragmented Premium (AFP). It turns out that despite the quasi-formula, the central incumbent changes the distribution of grants in favor of aligned regional arenas with unstable coalitions, given the uncertainty of a coalition. The additional funding is pure patronage politics as the central government seeks the loyalty and motivation of regional parties. These variations within regions reflect the multiple options available to politicians to change grant levels to extend the life of government, even in a formula-based framework. Table 6 provides the estimation results for the interaction.

Conversely, to examine the marginal effect of the variable Aligned on the level of funding, the ME is conditioned by Regional \(\text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Majority}\). Thus, the marginal effect of the variable Aligned is:

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{\text {ME}}_{\text {Aligned}} = \dfrac{\partial {\log (\text {F})} }{\partial \text {Aligned}}= \widehat{\beta }_{\text {Aligned}} + \widehat{\beta }_{\text {Interaction}} \times \text {Regional } \text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Majority} \end{aligned}$$
(4)
Fig. 2
figure 2

Impact of the effective number of parties on changes in health care grants conditioned on the alignment of regional government. Note: The axis on the left indicates the magnitude of the marginal effect (the interaction in Model 1, Table  6)

Fig. 3
figure 3

Impact of the alignment premium on changes in health care grants conditioned on the effective number of parties at the regional level. Note: The axis on the right indicates the magnitude of the marginal effect (the interaction in Model 1, Table 6). The vertical axis on the left is for the histogram, which depicts the absolute frequencies of the effective number of parties depicted on the horizontal axis

In this case, the conditional variable is continuous. MEs and meaningful standard errors are calculated for each value of the conditional variable. Figure 3 shows the ME of Aligned conditioned by \({\textbf {Regional ENP}}_{Gol}^{Majority}\) calculated from Model 1 in Table 6. The solid line in Fig. 3 illustrates the entire ME from Equation 4, while the dashed lines trace the 95% confidence interval. The distribution of the conditional variable is represented by the gray shaded histogram.

The central government is willing to allocate financial resources to the regions if their president belongs to the same party (or coalition). The “alignment premium” increases if the political arena is populated by more than 3.5 parties (otherwise the effect is not statistically different from zero). In this case, the AFP ranges on average from 3 to 6%.Footnote 32 There is no “alignment premium” per se, but it varies with regional government fragmentation. In short, regions that are aligned with the central government are likely to receive higher transfers the more fragmented the regional governments are. Transferring funds to aligned local governments can increase the gratitude of local leaders, which increases the incumbent’s chances of reelection. Success in local elections can also contribute to success in national elections. In addition, a national government may want to increase the likelihood of reelection of aligned local leaders if winning local elections gives the party a boost in national elections. In a multiparty system where seat control is fragmented, the distribution of particularistic benefits is an important means of attracting parties into the coalition and keeping them together (Baron and Ferejohn 1989).

Despite the key role that government fragmentation and alignment play in much of the theoretical literature, it seems that fragmentation or alignment alone cannot capture the full complexity of intergovernmental relations. To our knowledge, only Arulampalam et al. (2009) considered another variable, swing, in addition to alignment in their analysis of discretionary transfers. They found that a state that is both aligned and swing in the last election is estimated to receive higher transfers than a state that is neither aligned nor swing. Thus, it appears that previous research has never considered the interaction between partisan alignment of levels of government and fragmentation to determine whether this scenario may lead to a different magnitude of intergovernmental transfers. In a context with multiple levels of government, AFP then reveals a new mechanism affecting intergovernmental grant policy and offers an original contribution to the existing literature on tactical redistribution of resources to subnational governments as well as to the literature on fragmentation.

5.3 Does Fragmentation at the Central Level Affect Grants’ Flows?

To determine whether political fragmentation at the central level strengthens the AFP at the central level, we test a new formulation with two multiplicative terms and \({\textbf {National ENP}}^{Council}_{Gol}\), i.e., the effective number of parties supporting the central government.Footnote 33 This variable measures the fragmentation of the government and captures the strength of decision makers at the central level. It takes into account the effective number of parties in the upper house of the bicameral Parliament, the Senate, and is thus representative of the political balances that directly influence the government.Footnote 34 We expect politically motivated targeting to increase with fragmentation.

Again, \({\textbf {National ENP}}^{Council}_{Gol} \), computed as in Golosov (2010) is the new conditioning variable.Footnote 35 The new ME of an additional effective party is redefined as:

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{\text {ME}}_{\text {Reg ENP}_{Gol}^{Maj}}&= \dfrac{\partial {\log (\text {F})} }{\partial \text {Regional ENP}_{Gol}^{Maj}} \nonumber \\&={\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \widehat{\beta }_{ \text {Reg ENP}_{Gol}^{Maj}} + \widehat{\beta }_{\text {Nat ENP}^{Council}_{Gol} \times \text {Reg ENP}_{Gol}^{Maj}} \times \text {Nat ENP}^{Council}_{Gol} &{} \text {for Aligned} = 0 \\ \widehat{\beta }_{ \text {Reg ENP}_{Gol}^{Maj}} + \Big (\widehat{\beta }_{\text {Nat ENP}^{Council}_{Gol} \times \text {Reg ENP}_{Gol}^{Maj}} + \widehat{\beta }_{\text {Interaction}}\Big )\\ \qquad \times \text {Nat ENP}^{Council}_{Gol}&{} \text {for Aligned} =1\\ \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(5)
Fig. 4
figure 4

Impact of the effective number of parties in office on changes in health care grants conditional on the central government fragmentation and the alignment effect. Note: Aligned = 1, when regional and national governments are supported by the same coalition (and zero otherwise). The solid line illustrates the overall conditional marginal effect (the interaction in Model 5, Table  6), whereas the dashed lines trace out the 95% confidence interval. Axes on the left are for the histogram, which depicts the relative frequencies of the effective number of parties depicted on the horizontal axis

Table 9 Robustness checks
Table 10 Robustness check: fixed-effect regressions with XTPCSE standard errors

The ME of Regional \(\text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Majority}\) at the regional level, conditioned by the \({\textbf {National ENP}}^{Council}_{Gol}\) and by the alignment between the two levels of government, Aligned, are derived from Column (5) of Table 6 and presented in Fig. 4.

The results show that the more fragmented the central government, the higher the AFP (the fragmentation premium at the regional level) when the two coalitions are aligned. In this case, the premium averages between 1.5 and 2.5%, depending on how many parties support the central government. On the other hand, if the regional government is not aligned with the central government, the AFP premium (if statistically different from zero) decreases as fragmentation increases. This last result is evidence that there is no “alignment premium” per se.

6 Robustness Checks

6.1 Different Specifications and Other Intervening Factors

In this section, we investigate the sensitivity of our estimates by performing robustness checks, reporting the estimates reported in Tables 8 and 9. We find that our results are robust to substitution of a state-specific trend for the region-specific trends and to exclusion of time fixed effects.

Moreover, we investigate the sensitivity of our results by excluding some regions, starting with Campania, followed by Molise and Abruzzo. Campania was selected due to its highest fragmentation (on average) in the observed period. Due to a political scandal that led to earlier elections in Molise, we treated this region as an outlier and excluded it from the sample. Abruzzo held it regional election in 2008 due to the early resignation of the President following his indictment for alleged corruption (see Table 1). All results seem to be confirmed in terms of both magnitude and statistical significance. As an additional check, we consider the “repayment plans” (known as “Piani di Rientro”). These plans are a tool used by the central government to monitor and penalise regions with health care deficits. The plans are enforced through contractual agreements between the national and regional governments and are imposed whenever the regional health care deficit reaches or exceeds 7% of the previous year’s deficit (Ministero della Salute 2006). In this case, a region must submit to the central government a credible plan to restructure its health care system, including a list of measures and the corresponding regional taxes to cover these costs. In return, the central government allows them to access additional funds to improve health care. It is noteworthy that despite the fact that they were introduced by the National Budget Law of 2006 (Law 266/2005), it is only since 2013 that additional funds have been provided to support regional developmentFootnote 36 and the quota is equivalent to only 0.25 percent of the ordinary funds of the NHS.Footnote 37 When the variable “repayment plans” is included in the regression (see Table 10), the other coefficients are not affected.

Table 11 Descriptive statistics

To further check the robustness of our results, we included a swing measure in the regression. Swing is a time-invariant dummy variable that tracks financing dynamics consistent with the “swing voters” model (Dixit and Londregan 1996). Thus, we tested the idea of tactical investments focused on “swing” regions (Lindbeck and Weibull 1987) that are more likely to switch votes because of particularistic benefits, (rather than the hypothesis that politicians reward preexisting supporters (Cox and McCubbins 1986)). Swing takes the value 1 if there has been at least one change in the political color of the regional government in the last 15 years (and zero otherwise). Slightly more than half of the regions—homogeneously distributed over a north-south geographic span—are “swing” by this definition (Table 11).

Since this is a time-invariant variable, we ran Pooled-OLS regressions with PCSE. The results are presented in Table 8. To mitigate the potential endogeneity bias due to omitted variables that vary over time but are constant across regions, we use geographic dummies instead of regional fixed effects. We grouped the 15 Italian regions into three geographic macro-areas—North, Center and South—that are homogeneous in terms of economic characteristics. In some specifications, we also included time dummies. The effect seems to be remarkable as the estimated marginal response is about 10%. Swing alone doesn’t does not fully explain the tactical redistribution dynamics and does not change the magnitude or significance level of Regional \(\text {ENP}_{Gol}^{Majority}\).

6.2 Endogeneity and Interpretation Issues

A potential concern with the preceding analysis is that the Effective Number of Parties could be endogenous, since the “causality” could run from grants to fragmentation, rather than the other way around. If this is the case, the dissatisfied local politicians could change party affiliation or form a new regional party. As a result, fragmentation could be influenced by grantmaking, rather than the other way around. One way to rule out reverse causality would be to use a regression discontinuity design. However, this approach is not applicable given the small sample sizes of our within-country analyses. The most widely used approach is the instrumental variable, but this would be challenging in our study due to the lack of time-varying exogenous instruments. As a first feasible solution, the response variable is forwarded 1 year to better capture the lag in the grant-making mechanism and the time gap between policy decision and policy implementation. In addition, we do not capture party switching during a legislative session (which could be caused, for example, by unsatisfactory tactical allocation). Fragmentation indices are calculated using data from election results.Footnote 38 Therefore, the effective number of parties is stable on average over a 3/4 year period. These indices reflect the preferences of voters—expressed during elections—who are largely unaware of the actual redistribution of healthcare grants. This rules out the possibility of reverse causality between grants and policy choices. Although this erases a remarkable amount of variability, changes in the distribution of grants are directly linked to changes in voter preferences

An additional argument could be that aligned and fragmented regions are targeted for a higher distribution pattern due to purely economic considerations. However, concerns about the results are somewhat mitigated by the panel nature of the data and the control for regional GDP and unemployment. The FE coefficients estimate the impact of within-region variation on the outcome as political characteristics change, while controlling for fixed, unmeasured regional characteristics even if they are correlated with the political variables of interest. In addition, the FE model specification controls for time-invariant omitted variables that differ by region (i.e., political variables) and accounts for unobserved and correlated time-invariant country heterogeneity by explicitly estimating country fixed effects.

Finally, one could argue that unmeasured regional characteristics are not fixed and could be correlated with changes in voter preferences. However, it is unlikely that unmeasured regional characteristics changed significantly during the 10-year period studied.

7 Conclusions

This paper empirically investigates whether political motives determine the allocation of (quasi-discretionary) health grants to 15 Italian regions over the period 2001–2011. The main estimates use a geographic fixed effects and time fixed effects approach augmented by the use of panel-corrected standard errors to deal with autocorrelation.

The empirical analysis considers the strategic interaction between the center and regional governments and provides evidence of the influence of political factors in the allocation of intergovernmental grants in the Italian regional framework, where healthcare is the area where fiscal federalism rules are in force. Moreover, healthcare financing is an important issue in Italian electoral campaigns and key decisions on the regional allocation of resources take place in a political economy context where national legislators are elected from regional constituencies and political negotiations within the legislature determine the outcomes. As far as we know, subnational-level studies have mostly been conducted with data from relatively low levels of government, which casts doubt on the generalizability of the results. In contrast to cross-national studies, this paper uses variations from the relatively homogeneous Italian regions of ordinary status (OSR). In contrast to studies of subnational governments, this work is concerned with the middle level of Italian government, the regions, a politically powerful and fiscally relevant level.

Using interaction terms to capture the political environment in which the grant allocation takes place, we find that party alignment between the central government coalition and the coalition of regional governments matters for central government grantmaking only when fragmentation (i.e., the effective number of parties in the government and opposition coalitions after Golosov 2010) is taken into account. We call this finding aligned fragmented premium. The novelty of the present analysis is that it combines two aspects of government behavior that seem to belong together but have not previously been considered in the same model. It also shows that the introduction of allocation formulas as such does not help to curb political influence on grant allocation.